This chapter presents an empirical examination of the macroeconomic effects of remittances on remittance-receiving economies. Much of the early work on remittances’ macroeconomic impacts was carried out within the broader context of the economic development impact of migration. Taylor and others (1996a, 1996b) provide extensive surveys of this research, which includes discussion of the impacts of remittances.
The chapter is organized into four sections, each considering how remittances affect a particular macroeconomic variable of interest to policymakers: GDP growth, GDP volatility, the real exchange rate, and debt sustainability. The main findings from this exercise are as follows:
-
It is difficult to obtain a consistently robust positive effect of workers’ remittances on economic growth across a variety of econometric specifications.
-
A positive and significant coefficient on the effect of workers’ remittances on economic growth appears only when the estimation excludes investment and in the absence of country fixed effects.
-
The econometric evidence suggests that remittances may decrease economic growth in some countries through a reduction in total factor productivity.
-
Remittances diminish macroeconomic volatility over long horizons, likely through reductions in aggregate consumption volatility.
-
Higher remittance receipts tend to appreciate the equilibrium real exchange rate, implying that the beneficial effects of remittances in generating higher and more stable levels of consumption may come at the expense of long-run growth.
-
The presence of remittances can support higher future debt levels in countries that receive such flows in sufficient quantities, though enhanced sustainability depends on the persistence and elasticity of these flows with respect to income differentials, interest rate differentials, and changes in exchange rates.
The chapter proceeds as follows. The next section details the empirical relationship between workers’ remittances and GDP growth, which is followed by an examination of remittances’ effects on economic volatility and the real exchange rate. The chapter concludes with a discussion concerning assessments of debt sustainability in remittance-dependent countries. Descriptions of the data used in the chapter are provided in the chapter appendix.
Remittances and GDP Growth
Economists have recently turned their attention to estimating the impact of remittances on longer-term economic growth using modern growth theory.1 Previous chapters introduced several possible mechanisms through which remittances may affect economic growth. The following discussion summarizes these mechanisms to motivate the empirical work that has examined the relationship between remittances and growth. The discussion groups the mechanisms into those through which remittances potentially have positive effects on growth and those through which they may have negative effects.
On the positive side, remittances may increase or enhance investment in physical capital. To the extent that there are frictions in domestic financial intermediation, imperfect capital mobility is present and remittances are not simply “disguised” capital flows. The receipt of temporary remittances in an economy may lead to an increase in the domestic investment rate, thus increasing economic growth. If financial constraints are significant—for example, a large group of households are rationed out of credit markets because of the lack of domestic financial development—then remittances may help to ease the constraints. This results in an increase in investment, provided that the rationed households also have access to productive investment opportunities and use the remittances to expand investment rather than consumption.2 Alternatively, if remittances are primarily disguised capital flows—the recipients are investing on behalf of the remitter—then efficiency in investment is enhanced to the extent that the family member receiving the remittance flows possesses some informational advantage or expertise with respect to formal financial intermediaries.
Another channel through which remittances may have a positive impact on growth is via the facilitation of human capital formation. Even though, as discussed in Chapter 4, the majority of remitted funds are devoted to consumption and residential investment, significant productivity spillovers may result from the recipients’ improved nutrition and shelter, assuming that they participate in the labor market. In addition, the literature offers several examples in which a significant fraction of remittances are spent on education, assuming that those who receive the education do not in turn emigrate. As such, remittances may increase total factor productivity. These two channels through which remittances may have a positive impact on growth, the accumulation of physical capital and total factor productivity, are not mutually exclusive, but it may be possible to distinguish between them empirically.
In addition to enhancing investment and total factor productivity, remittances may also have a positive impact on growth through their effect on the recipient economy’s financial system. By increasing the recipient country’s demand for money, remittances are likely to expand the supply of funds to the banking system. This in turn may lead to enhanced financial development through a reduction in the external finance premium and thus to higher economic growth through one of two channels: (1) economies of scale, or (2) a political economy effect, whereby a larger constituency (depositors) is able to pressure the government into undertaking beneficial financial reform.
It is far from assured that remittances will have a positive impact on economic growth in any particular country, however. Each mechanism described in the foregoing discussion relies on a particular set of circumstances that may not be present in a given country; alternative conditions that reduce or eliminate the positive impact of remittances may be found there instead. In general, the greater the degree of capital mobility in a country, the less remittances will affect the domestic investment rate. Also, if remittances are perceived to be permanent, they will tend to be consumed in their entirety and therefore will not affect aggregate investment. A similar argument applies to credit-constrained households: even if the constraints are relaxed, additional funds from remittances may simply be consumed. Finally, the family member who receives a migrant’s remittances may actually be less skilled in investing than are financial intermediaries, which has important implications in this context if remittances are disguised capital flows.
Prevailing circumstances in a particular economy may likewise reduce the human capital and financial sector impacts of remittances. The consumption impact of remittances on labor productivity depends on recipient families’ standard of living. If a family’s standard of living is sufficiently high before the receipt of remittances that its basic needs are adequately met, then the labor productivity effect of remittances vanishes for that family. Also, any human capital accumulation impacts depend on the recipients’ participation in the labor force after accumulation of capital. In some remittance-receiving societies, education funded by remittances is intended to enable the recipients themselves to migrate. Finally, in terms of financial sector impacts, an increase in the size of the domestic banking system via an increase in the supply of funds does not necessarily reduce the external finance premium. The political economy mechanism arising from a larger banking system may have an adverse effect on financial development: depositors lobby the government for reforms favoring safety over intermediation, for example, causing banks to increase their holdings of safe assets rather than lending.
The question of whether remittances increase an economy’s growth is not simply a matter of whether conditions in the economy are favorable to the operation of the channels described previously. Remittances can also decrease economic growth through two means that operate differently than the positive channels. One that is increasingly mentioned in the literature is a Dutch disease effect, which requires that the traded goods sector of a remittance-receiving economy be the source of significant positive externalities that enhance other sectors’ productive capacity. If this condition is satisfied, a Dutch disease effect may arise from remittances to the extent that they cause the economy’s real exchange rate to appreciate. The third section of this chapter presents a separate discussion of the effect of remittances on the real exchange rate.
Acosta, Lartey, and Mandelman (2007) offer some empirical evidence on Dutch disease effects of remittances. These authors first develop a two-sector real business cycle model with remittances that produces Dutch disease effects in the remittance-receiving economy. The model is calibrated and simulated for El Salvador, and then impulse response functions from the model are compared to those calculated from a Bayesian vector autoregression (B-VAR) estimated on data for El Salvador from 1991–2006. The B-VAR response functions agree qualitatively with the model predictions, revealing evidence of Dutch disease effects of remittances (during this period, remittances increased 500 percent, and the country’s real exchange rate appreciated 30 percent).
A second means by which remittances may harm economic growth is through the moral hazard problem, an idea that was first formalized by Chami, Fullenkamp, and Jahjah (2003). Given that remittances are non-market income transfers that occur under asymmetric information and that monitoring and enforcement are extremely difficult because of the distance separating remitter and recipient, they may be plagued by severe moral hazard. The evidence discussed in Chapter 4 that remittances are compensatory transfers motivated by altruism supports such a view. The moral hazard problem manifests itself in two ways: recipients reduce their labor market effort and they make riskier investments. Anecdotal evidence of the labor effort effect is abundant, and academic studies have detected such an effect as well.3 The formal model developed in Chapter 6, which is designed to focus on households’ labor supply decisions, yields a similar conclusion. Reduced labor effort and increased investment risk lead to reduced economic growth.
Recent Empirical Findings
As noted in Chapters 2 and 3, the data on remittances recently improved to the point that cross-country studies of the macroeconomic effects of remittances became feasible. Thus, a relatively recent and growing literature attempts to measure empirically remittances’ impact on economic growth. The first of these studies was the Chami, Fullenkamp, and Jahjah (2003) crosscountry study of workers’ remittances. The study used a sample of 83 countries during the 1970–1998 period and conducted panel regressions of growth in real GDP per capita on both the workers’ remittances–to–GDP ratio and the change in that ratio, conditioned on the investment rate, the rate of inflation, regional dummies, and the ratio of net private capital flows to GDP. Overall, it found that whereas domestic investment and private capital flows were positively related to growth, the workers’ remittances–to–GDP ratio either was not significant or was negatively related to growth, with the same holding true when a squared term of the ratio was included in the analysis as well. Annual changes in the workers’ remittances–to–GDP ratio were found to be negative and significant on growth. To account for possible endogeneity of remittances to the macroeconomic controls, the study also conducted an instrumental variables estimation, whereby a first-stage regression estimated the workers’ remittances–to–GDP ratio as a function of each country’s income gap and real interest rate gap relative to the United States.4 With the predicted value for the workers’ remittances–to–GDP ratio as a regressor, the second stage continued to find that changes in remittances are negatively related to growth.
The IMF (2005) performed cross-country growth regressions with specifications similar to those in Chami, Fullenkamp, and Jahjah (2003) on a set of 101 countries measured over the 1970–2003 period. However, in contrast to Chami, Fullenkamp, and Jahjah (2003), the IMF (2005) used an aggregate remittance variable, or the sum of workers’ remittances, employee compensation, and migrant transfers, which was shown in Chapter 2 to capture behavior not associated with workers’ remittances. We refer to this aggregate measure as total remittances when discussing this and other studies that use a similar aggregation method. The IMF study also used two instruments for remittances: distance between the migrants’ home and main destination country, and a dummy measuring whether the home and main destination country shared a common language. Because the instruments did not vary over time, panel estimation techniques could not be used. The IMF (2005) found no statistically significant effect of total remittances on economic growth.
Faini (2006) estimated cross-sectional growth regressions on a set of 68 countries5 in which the dependent variable is the average annual per capita GDP growth rate from 1980 to 2004. These growth regressions do not include an investment variable; the reason given is that investment could be driven in part by remittances, and hence its coefficient could be capturing some of the effect of remittances. Faini (2006), like the IMF (2005), used an aggregate measure of remittances obtained by summing workers’ remittances, employee compensation, and migrant transfers. The estimated coefficient on the total remittances–to–GDP ratio in Faini’s ordinary least-squares (OLS) regression was positive and significant, both when average and when initial remittances were used in the total remittances–to–GDP variable. Faini also conducted an instrumental variables estimation, using distance from the migrants’ main destination countries as the instrument for remittances. In this estimation, the coefficient on total remittances remained positive but lost its significance.
Giuliano and Ruiz-Arranz (2005) gathered a sample of 73 countries during the 1975–2002 period, then calculated five-year averages for all variables used in their study to smooth out cyclical variations. Again, remittances were defined as the sum of workers’ remittances, employee compensation, and migrant transfers. This study conducted OLS as well as fixed-effects panel estimates, and through a system generalized method of moments (SGMM) procedure used internal instruments to account for possible endogeneity. The study’s basic specification regressed per capita GDP growth on the total remittances–to–GDP ratio, conditioning on the initial level of GDP per capita, the investment rate, population growth, the fiscal balance as a percentage of GDP, years of education, a measure of openness, and inflation. This specification did not find total remittances to be significantly related to growth. However, the authors also explored possible interactions between the total remittances–to–GDP ratio and financial deepening,6 as a way of testing whether remittances might enhance growth by relaxing credit constraints. Indeed, the authors found significant negative interaction terms and interpreted these results as indicative of the credit constraint hypothesis; total remittances appeared to have positive effects on growth only in countries with small financial sectors where presumably credit constraints would be more pervasive.
Another study, by Catrinescu and others (2006), incorporated institutional variables into the analysis, which covered 114 countries during the 1991–2003 period. Catrinescu and colleagues conducted OLS cross-sectional and various static and dynamic panel regressions of per capita GDP growth on the (log of) total remittances–to–GDP, controlling for initial GDP per capita, ratios of gross capital formation and net private capital inflows to GDP, and such institutional variables as the United Nations Human Development Index, six governance indicators as in Kaufmann, Kraay, and Mastruzzi (2003), and risk ratings from the International Country Risk Guide (ICRG). Overall, their study found a robust positive relationship between growth and gross capital formation, as well as between growth and some of the institutional variables. The study also found some evidence of a positive relationship between growth and total remittances, although this relationship was not very robust and, as the authors acknowledge, relatively mild.
Finally, the World Bank (2006) conducted crosscountry growth regressions on a data set of 67 countries measured over 1991–2005. The control variables included (logs of) initial GDP per capita, the secondary school enrollment ratio, the ratio of private domestic credit to GDP, the ICRG political risk index, the ratio of real imports and exports to GDP, the inflation rate, real exchange rate overvaluation, government consumption, and time period dummies. An SGMM estimation was performed, in which the instrument for remittances was a set of “migration” instruments formed by computing the product of the share of a country’s migrants going to each of its top five OECD country destinations (as of 2000) and a measure of the respective OECD country’s economic performance, such as GDP per capita, the GDP growth rate, or the unemployment rate. These instruments reflect the idea that income in the host country appears to be a key driver of remittances. The inverse of the distance between the migrants’ destination country and the remittance-receiving country was also used in place of migration shares in the migration instruments described above to form “distance” instruments. The growth regressions found a consistently positive relationship between the total remittances–to–GDP ratio and GDP growth, both when investment was included and when it was excluded from the estimations. When investment was excluded, however, the coefficients lost their significance. The authors also calculated the contribution of total remittances to growth rates and found that it was small.
A later exercise in the same World Bank study included interaction terms for remittances and education, remittances and financial depth, and remittances and institutional quality indicators in three separate growth equations that had the same specification as the growth equations examined previously, with the argument that remittances augment growth in the presence of complementary policies that enhance education, financial market depth, or institutional quality. The World Bank study found a negative and significant coefficient on the total remittances–to–GDP ratio, but positive and significant coefficients on each of the interaction terms. The study argued that this implies a net positive impact of total remittances on GDP, when the complementarities are included. In addition, the study included an estimate of total remittances’ impact on investment, finding a similar pattern of coefficients.
Estimating the Remittances-Growth Relationship
Overall, the results of the aforementioned studies are inconclusive. To the extent that a “best practice” for estimating the remittances-growth relationship exists, it is identified and incorporated into the empirical exercises that follow this discussion.
The disparity of results in the studies discussed previously has several sources. The first of these is the underlying data used to construct the time series for remittances. Given the conclusion reached in Chapter 2 that the categories employee compensation and migrant transfers in the balance of payments are conceptually different from and behave differently than the category workers’ remittances, the preferred measure for use in econometric analysis is the ratio of workers’ remittances to GDP. Of the papers referenced previously, only Chami, Fullenkamp, and Jahjah (2003) used this more precise definition of workers’ remittances. The estimations that follow incorporate the workers’ remittances–to–GDP ratio in three different ways: alone, together with its squared term to account for possible nonlinearities, and interacted with a financial deepening variable, the M2-to-GDP ratio,7 to examine possible credit constraint effects as in Giuliano and Ruiz-Arranz (2005).
A second source of disparity in the results of previous studies may arise from the differing time periods and sets of countries included, which vary greatly among the papers previously cited. The estimations in the following sections cover the 1970–2004 period, the longest period for which remittances data are available. To keep the reporting simple, two different sets of countries are analyzed: all countries, and emerging economies only (defined as in Chapters 2 and 3).
A third source of disparity in the studies discussed previously is the control variables included in the growth regressions. In particular, the presence of investment as a control variable seems to make a difference in the magnitude and significance of the remittances variable. Including a measure of domestic investment (the investment ratio or gross capital formation) as a regressor implies that any estimated growth effects of remittances will be through total factor productivity (TFP) rather than the quantity of investment. Since the preceding theoretical discussion also included possible effects of remittances on the volume of domestic investment, some of the regressions in the current study exclude this variable as a regressor to account for this possibility. More generally, different conditioning sets of variables are used, in order to incorporate the principal control variables employed in previous studies. Furthermore, to smooth out cyclical fluctuations, five-year averages of the macroeconomic variables are calculated and used in the regressions in place of single-year values.
An Instrument for Remittances
The set of variables used as an instrument for remittances in regressions is also an important potential source of the differences among estimation results in the studies discussed earlier in the chapter. Finding an appropriate instrument or set of instruments that corrects for the endogeneity of remittances has been a challenge for researchers. Two key features govern the selection of an instrument for remittances: the instrument must be correlated with remittances, and its effect on individual country growth must operate solely through its effect on remittances. Although two likely choices come to mind—GDP per capita, and growth in the developed countries where migrants from the remittance-receiving countries reside—both are also expected to have a direct impact on growth. Chapter 3 showed the first of these, GDP per capita, to be negatively correlated with remittance receipts, but it also affects economic growth directly through convergence. The second variable, GDP growth in developed countries where remitters reside, is likely to be correlated with trade flows,8 which in turn are expected to exert an independent impact on growth as well.
In general, the challenge in finding an appropriate instrument is that most variables that might explain remittances—domestic and foreign macroeconomic variables in particular—also tend to affect growth. For this reason, internal instruments (lagged right-hand-side variables) have been criticized (see especially World Bank, 2006), and migration and distance instruments have been suggested. These instruments may not be as great an improvement over internal instruments as they initially seem, however. Distance between migrants’ destination country and the remittance-receiving country is exogenous but time invariant, so it must be multiplied by host country GDP to obtain a time-varying instrument. Thus, distance instruments may be too strongly correlated with the growth rate in remittance-receiving countries. A similar argument can be made for migration instruments (migration shares are reported only periodically, so the migration shares are fixed and must be multiplied, again by host country GDP, to make the instrument time varying).
Thus, other determinants of remittances, such as their transaction costs, are likely candidates as instruments. In the absence of a direct observation of this cost variable, another (observable) variable might capture general trends in remittances throughout the world, including changes in transaction costs: the ratio of remittances to GDP of all other recipient countries (wrrowi). Admittedly, this instrument does not eliminate all endogeneity, but it represents a significant improvement over internal, lag-driven instruments and over previous attempts at obtaining an external instrument. By excluding the remittances-to-GDP ratio of the country in question, wrrowi is free of a direct causal link with other domestic macroeconomic variables. Furthermore, although one also expects wrrowi to capture income growth in the developed world, the correlation with trade effects is diluted to the extent that, for a given country i, wrrowi also incorporates the income movements in countries that have little trade with i. In other words, the diversification effect reduces any correlation between the instrument and the growth rate in the remittance-receiving country.
Using this variable as an instrument, the first-stage regression is given by
where writ denotes the ratio of workers’ remittances to GDP in country i and year t, and wrrowit denotes the ratio of workers’ remittances to GDP in the rest of the world—that is, in all countries except i—in year t. Thus, the first-stage regression includes the general world trend in remittances as an explanatory variable, along with a country-specific fixed effect to determine the average level of remittances for each given country. The second stage includes the fitted values from the first stage as a regressor.
Empirical Findings
Tables 7.1–7.4 present the main results of the growth regressions. For simplicity, the tables show only the coefficients for variables related to workers’ remittances, although three distinct combinations of a wide set of conditioning variables were included in the estimations. The basic conditioning set included initial per capita GDP; the ratios of trade and M2 to GDP, both in log terms; and the inflation rate. Through the addition of the ratio of domestic investment to GDP in the second conditioning set, a distinction could be made regarding whether remittances might have an impact on growth through higher investment or through higher TFP Finally, the full conditioning set included the following additional variables: foreign direct investment and the fiscal balance, both in relation to GDP; the rate of population growth; and the composite ICRG political risk indicator, as in Catrinescu and others (2006). Thus, each table includes results under each conditioning set, and both OLS and fixed-effects estimations are shown. Tables 7.1 and 7.2 report the results using wr as the remittance regressor, whereas Tables 7.3 and 7.4 report those using the second-stage fitted wr from the first-stage regression. In addition, results for the full country sample are reported in Tables 7.1 and 7.3, and those for the emerging economy subsample in Tables 7.2 and 7.4. Finally, each table shows the three alternative ways of including workers’ remittances identified in the previous subsection.
OLS and Fixed-Effects Regressions Explaining Per Capita GDP Growth as a Function of Workers’ Remittances and Different Conditioning Sets, All Countries
*significant at 10 percent; ** significant at 5 percent; ***significant at 1 percent.
OLS and Fixed-Effects Regressions Explaining Per Capita GDP Growth as a Function of Workers’ Remittances and Different Conditioning Sets, All Countries
Conditioning Sets of Variables | ||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Basic Conditioning Set: Excludes Domestic Investment |
Basic Conditioning Set Plus Domestic Investment |
Full Conditioning Set, Including Institutional Variable |
||||||
OLS | Fixed Effects | OLS | Fixed Effects | OLS | Fixed Effects | |||
Sample: All Countries | ||||||||
Specification: | ||||||||
1. wr only | ||||||||
wr | 0.200 | 0.172 | 0.171 | 0.202 | 0.056 | −0.099 | ||
(2.50)** | (0.90) | (2.21)** | (1.09) | (0.61) | (0.48) | |||
R 2 | 0.049 | 0.169 | 0.139 | 0.218 | 0.354 | 0.373 | ||
Observations | 383 | 383 | 374 | 374 | 189 | 189 | ||
Countries | 108 | 108 | 105 | 105 | 66 | 66 | ||
2. wr and wr-squared | ||||||||
wr | 0.125 | −0.030 | 0.105 | −0.017 | −0.005 | 0.012 | ||
(1.26) | (0.13) | (1.07) | (0.08) | (0.04) | (0.04) | |||
wr-squared | −0.033 | −0.073 | −0.028 | −0.077 | −0.028 | 0.032 | ||
(1.27) | (1.48) | (1.09) | (1.62) | (0.74) | (0.59) | |||
R 2 | 0.051 | 0.175 | 0.139 | 0.226 | 0.352 | 0.375 | ||
Observations | 383 | 383 | 374 | 374 | 189 | 189 | ||
Countries | 108 | 108 | 105 | 105 | 66 | 66 | ||
3. wr and interaction with M2-GDP | ||||||||
wr | 0.798 | 0.550 | 0.570 | 0.423 | 0.039 | −1.033 | ||
(1.95)* | (0.83) | (1.45) | (0.65) | (0.08) | (1.18) | |||
wr × M2-GDP | −0.176 | −0.111 | −0.118 | −0.065 | 0.005 | 0.296 | ||
(1.49) | (0.60) | (1.03) | (0.35) | (0.03) | (1.09) | |||
R 2 | 0.052 | 0.170 | 0.176 | 0.218 | 0.350 | 0.379 | ||
Observations | 383 | 383 | 374 | 374 | 189 | 189 | ||
Countries | 108 | 108 | 105 | 105 | 66 | 66 |
*significant at 10 percent; ** significant at 5 percent; ***significant at 1 percent.
OLS and Fixed-Effects Regressions Explaining Per Capita GDP Growth as a Function of Workers’ Remittances and Different Conditioning Sets, All Countries
Conditioning Sets of Variables | ||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Basic Conditioning Set: Excludes Domestic Investment |
Basic Conditioning Set Plus Domestic Investment |
Full Conditioning Set, Including Institutional Variable |
||||||
OLS | Fixed Effects | OLS | Fixed Effects | OLS | Fixed Effects | |||
Sample: All Countries | ||||||||
Specification: | ||||||||
1. wr only | ||||||||
wr | 0.200 | 0.172 | 0.171 | 0.202 | 0.056 | −0.099 | ||
(2.50)** | (0.90) | (2.21)** | (1.09) | (0.61) | (0.48) | |||
R 2 | 0.049 | 0.169 | 0.139 | 0.218 | 0.354 | 0.373 | ||
Observations | 383 | 383 | 374 | 374 | 189 | 189 | ||
Countries | 108 | 108 | 105 | 105 | 66 | 66 | ||
2. wr and wr-squared | ||||||||
wr | 0.125 | −0.030 | 0.105 | −0.017 | −0.005 | 0.012 | ||
(1.26) | (0.13) | (1.07) | (0.08) | (0.04) | (0.04) | |||
wr-squared | −0.033 | −0.073 | −0.028 | −0.077 | −0.028 | 0.032 | ||
(1.27) | (1.48) | (1.09) | (1.62) | (0.74) | (0.59) | |||
R 2 | 0.051 | 0.175 | 0.139 | 0.226 | 0.352 | 0.375 | ||
Observations | 383 | 383 | 374 | 374 | 189 | 189 | ||
Countries | 108 | 108 | 105 | 105 | 66 | 66 | ||
3. wr and interaction with M2-GDP | ||||||||
wr | 0.798 | 0.550 | 0.570 | 0.423 | 0.039 | −1.033 | ||
(1.95)* | (0.83) | (1.45) | (0.65) | (0.08) | (1.18) | |||
wr × M2-GDP | −0.176 | −0.111 | −0.118 | −0.065 | 0.005 | 0.296 | ||
(1.49) | (0.60) | (1.03) | (0.35) | (0.03) | (1.09) | |||
R 2 | 0.052 | 0.170 | 0.176 | 0.218 | 0.350 | 0.379 | ||
Observations | 383 | 383 | 374 | 374 | 189 | 189 | ||
Countries | 108 | 108 | 105 | 105 | 66 | 66 |
*significant at 10 percent; ** significant at 5 percent; ***significant at 1 percent.
OLS and Fixed-Effects Regressions Explaining Per Capita GDP Growth as a Function of Workers’ Remittances and Different Conditioning Sets, Emerging Economies
OLS and Fixed-Effects Regressions Explaining Per Capita GDP Growth as a Function of Workers’ Remittances and Different Conditioning Sets, Emerging Economies
Conditioning Sets of Variables | ||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Basic Conditioning Set: Excludes Domestic Investment |
Basic Conditioning Set Plus Domestic Investment |
Full Conditioning Set, Including Institutional Variable |
||||||
OLS | Fixed Effects |
OLS | Fixed Effects |
OLS | Fixed Effects |
|||
Sample: Emerging Economies | ||||||||
Specification: | ||||||||
1. wronly | ||||||||
wr | 0.207 | 0.192 | 0.182 | 0.223 | 0.053 | −0.095 | ||
(2.50)** | (0.97) | (2.28)** | (1.16) | (0.57) | (0.46) | |||
R 2 | 0.051 | 0.724 | 0.140 | 0.221 | 0.353 | 0.375 | ||
Observations | 365 | 365 | 356 | 356 | 184 | 184 | ||
Countries | 104 | 104 | 101 | 101 | 64 | 64 | ||
2. wr and wr-squared | ||||||||
wr | 0.119 | −0.012 | 0.109 | 0.008 | −0.005 | 0.008 | ||
(1.16) | (0.05) | (1.08) | (0.03) | (0.04) | (0.03) | |||
wr-squared | −0.039 | −0.073 | −0.031 | −0.076 | −0.027 | 0.030 | ||
(1.46) | (1.46) | (1.20) | (1.55) | (0.70) | (0.55) | |||
R 2 | 0.054 | 0.179 | 0.141 | 0.228 | 0.352 | 0.376 | ||
Observations | 365 | 365 | 356 | 356 | 184 | 184 | ||
Countries | 104 | 104 | 101 | 101 | 64 | 64 | ||
3. wr and interaction with M2-GDP | ||||||||
wr | 0.933 | 0.564 | 0.617 | 0.429 | 0.076 | −1.068 | ||
(2.14)** | (0.84) | (1.46) | (0.64) | (0.14) | (1.20) | |||
wr X M2-GDP | −0.216 | −0.110 | −0.129 | −0.061 | −0.007 | 0.308 | ||
(1.69)* | (0.58) | (1.05) | (0.32) | (0.04) | (1.12) | |||
R 2 | 0.056 | 0.173 | 0.140 | 0.221 | 0.389 | 0.382 | ||
Observations | 365 | 365 | 356 | 356 | 184 | 184 | ||
Countries | 104 | 104 | 101 | 101 | 64 | 64 |
OLS and Fixed-Effects Regressions Explaining Per Capita GDP Growth as a Function of Workers’ Remittances and Different Conditioning Sets, Emerging Economies
Conditioning Sets of Variables | ||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Basic Conditioning Set: Excludes Domestic Investment |
Basic Conditioning Set Plus Domestic Investment |
Full Conditioning Set, Including Institutional Variable |
||||||
OLS | Fixed Effects |
OLS | Fixed Effects |
OLS | Fixed Effects |
|||
Sample: Emerging Economies | ||||||||
Specification: | ||||||||
1. wronly | ||||||||
wr | 0.207 | 0.192 | 0.182 | 0.223 | 0.053 | −0.095 | ||
(2.50)** | (0.97) | (2.28)** | (1.16) | (0.57) | (0.46) | |||
R 2 | 0.051 | 0.724 | 0.140 | 0.221 | 0.353 | 0.375 | ||
Observations | 365 | 365 | 356 | 356 | 184 | 184 | ||
Countries | 104 | 104 | 101 | 101 | 64 | 64 | ||
2. wr and wr-squared | ||||||||
wr | 0.119 | −0.012 | 0.109 | 0.008 | −0.005 | 0.008 | ||
(1.16) | (0.05) | (1.08) | (0.03) | (0.04) | (0.03) | |||
wr-squared | −0.039 | −0.073 | −0.031 | −0.076 | −0.027 | 0.030 | ||
(1.46) | (1.46) | (1.20) | (1.55) | (0.70) | (0.55) | |||
R 2 | 0.054 | 0.179 | 0.141 | 0.228 | 0.352 | 0.376 | ||
Observations | 365 | 365 | 356 | 356 | 184 | 184 | ||
Countries | 104 | 104 | 101 | 101 | 64 | 64 | ||
3. wr and interaction with M2-GDP | ||||||||
wr | 0.933 | 0.564 | 0.617 | 0.429 | 0.076 | −1.068 | ||
(2.14)** | (0.84) | (1.46) | (0.64) | (0.14) | (1.20) | |||
wr X M2-GDP | −0.216 | −0.110 | −0.129 | −0.061 | −0.007 | 0.308 | ||
(1.69)* | (0.58) | (1.05) | (0.32) | (0.04) | (1.12) | |||
R 2 | 0.056 | 0.173 | 0.140 | 0.221 | 0.389 | 0.382 | ||
Observations | 365 | 365 | 356 | 356 | 184 | 184 | ||
Countries | 104 | 104 | 101 | 101 | 64 | 64 |
OLS and Fixed-Effects Instrumental Variables Regressions Explaining Per Capita GDP Growth as a Function of Workers’ Remittances and Different Conditioning Sets, All Countries
OLS and Fixed-Effects Instrumental Variables Regressions Explaining Per Capita GDP Growth as a Function of Workers’ Remittances and Different Conditioning Sets, All Countries
Conditioning Sets of Variables | ||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Basic Conditioning Set: Excludes Domestic Investment |
Basic Conditioning Set Plus Domestic Investment |
Full Conditioning Set, Including Institutional Variable |
||||||
OLS-IV | Fixed Effects-IV |
OLS-IV | Fixed Effects-IV |
OLS-IV | Fixed Effects-IV |
|||
Sample: All Countries | ||||||||
Specification: | ||||||||
1. wr only | ||||||||
fitted wr | 0.091 | −5.667 | 0.044 | −5.997 | 0.036 | 6.822 | ||
(1.07) | (2.33)** | (0.53) | (2.56)** | (0.36) | (1.35) | |||
R 2 | 0.037 | 0.169 | 0.128 | 0.233 | 0.353 | 0.382 | ||
Observations | 383 | 383 | 374 | 374 | 189 | 189 | ||
Countries | 108 | 108 | 105 | 105 | 66 | 66 | ||
2. wr and wr-squared | ||||||||
fitted wr | 0.047 | −5.525 | 0.011 | −5.814 | 0.040 | 3.863 | ||
(0.45) | (2.27)** | (0.10) | (2.49)** | (0.30) | (0.74) | |||
fitted wr-squared | −0.021 | −0.951 | −0.015 | −1.245 | 0.002 | −1.978 | ||
(0.75) | (1.22) | (0.54) | (1.65)* | (0.04) | (1.88)* | |||
R 2 | 0.035 | 0.187 | 0.126 | 0.241 | 0.349 | 0.400 | ||
Observations | 383 | 383 | 374 | 374 | 189 | 189 | ||
Countries | 108 | 108 | 105 | 105 | 66 | 66 | ||
3. wr and interaction with M2-GDP | ||||||||
fitted wr | 1.270 | −3.005 | 0.854 | −4.321 | 0.134 | 6.441 | ||
(2.86)*** | (1.10) | (1.98)** | (1.57) | (0.26) | (1.22) | |||
fitted wr X M2-GDP | −0.349 | −0.652 | −0.239 | −0.389 | −0.029 | 0.092 | ||
(2.70)*** | (2.07)** | (1.91)* | (1.16) | (0.19) | (0.25) | |||
R 2 | 0.052 | 0.195 | 0.134 | 0.237 | 0.350 | 0.382 | ||
Observations | 383 | 383 | 374 | 374 | 189 | 189 | ||
Countries | 108 | 108 | 105 | 105 | 66 | 66 |
OLS and Fixed-Effects Instrumental Variables Regressions Explaining Per Capita GDP Growth as a Function of Workers’ Remittances and Different Conditioning Sets, All Countries
Conditioning Sets of Variables | ||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Basic Conditioning Set: Excludes Domestic Investment |
Basic Conditioning Set Plus Domestic Investment |
Full Conditioning Set, Including Institutional Variable |
||||||
OLS-IV | Fixed Effects-IV |
OLS-IV | Fixed Effects-IV |
OLS-IV | Fixed Effects-IV |
|||
Sample: All Countries | ||||||||
Specification: | ||||||||
1. wr only | ||||||||
fitted wr | 0.091 | −5.667 | 0.044 | −5.997 | 0.036 | 6.822 | ||
(1.07) | (2.33)** | (0.53) | (2.56)** | (0.36) | (1.35) | |||
R 2 | 0.037 | 0.169 | 0.128 | 0.233 | 0.353 | 0.382 | ||
Observations | 383 | 383 | 374 | 374 | 189 | 189 | ||
Countries | 108 | 108 | 105 | 105 | 66 | 66 | ||
2. wr and wr-squared | ||||||||
fitted wr | 0.047 | −5.525 | 0.011 | −5.814 | 0.040 | 3.863 | ||
(0.45) | (2.27)** | (0.10) | (2.49)** | (0.30) | (0.74) | |||
fitted wr-squared | −0.021 | −0.951 | −0.015 | −1.245 | 0.002 | −1.978 | ||
(0.75) | (1.22) | (0.54) | (1.65)* | (0.04) | (1.88)* | |||
R 2 | 0.035 | 0.187 | 0.126 | 0.241 | 0.349 | 0.400 | ||
Observations | 383 | 383 | 374 | 374 | 189 | 189 | ||
Countries | 108 | 108 | 105 | 105 | 66 | 66 | ||
3. wr and interaction with M2-GDP | ||||||||
fitted wr | 1.270 | −3.005 | 0.854 | −4.321 | 0.134 | 6.441 | ||
(2.86)*** | (1.10) | (1.98)** | (1.57) | (0.26) | (1.22) | |||
fitted wr X M2-GDP | −0.349 | −0.652 | −0.239 | −0.389 | −0.029 | 0.092 | ||
(2.70)*** | (2.07)** | (1.91)* | (1.16) | (0.19) | (0.25) | |||
R 2 | 0.052 | 0.195 | 0.134 | 0.237 | 0.350 | 0.382 | ||
Observations | 383 | 383 | 374 | 374 | 189 | 189 | ||
Countries | 108 | 108 | 105 | 105 | 66 | 66 |
OLS and Fixed-Effects Instrumental Variables Regressions Explaining Per Capita GDP Growth as a Function of Workers’ Remittances and Different Conditioning Sets, Emerging Economies
OLS and Fixed-Effects Instrumental Variables Regressions Explaining Per Capita GDP Growth as a Function of Workers’ Remittances and Different Conditioning Sets, Emerging Economies
Conditioning Sets of Variables | ||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Basic Conditioning Set: Excludes Domestic Investment |
Basic Conditioning Set Plus Domestic Investment |
Full Conditioning Set, Including Institutional Variable |
||||||
OLS-IV | Fixed Effects-IV |
OLS-IV | Fixed Effects-IV |
OLS-IV | Fixed Effects-IV |
|||
Sample: Emerging Economies | ||||||||
Specification: | ||||||||
1. wr only | ||||||||
fitted wr | 0.094 | −5.312 | 0.052 | −5.732 | 0.035 | 6.877 | ||
(1.06) | (2.08)** | (0.60) | (2.33)** | (0.34) | (1.34) | |||
R 2 | 0.038 | 0.183 | 0.128 | 0.233 | 0.388 | 0.384 | ||
Observations | 365 | 365 | 356 | 356 | 184 | 184 | ||
Countries | 104 | 104 | 101 | 101 | 64 | 64 | ||
2. wr and wr-squared | ||||||||
fitted wr | 0.039 | −4.993 | 0.012 | −5.348 | 0.039 | 3.926 | ||
(0.36) | (1.95)* | (0.11) | (2.17)** | (0.30) | (0.74) | |||
fitted wr-squared | −0.027 | −1.069 | −0.019 | −1.325 | 0.003 | −2.145 | ||
(0.91) | (1.29) | (0.64) | (1.66)* | (0.06) | (1.96) | |||
R 2 | 0.037 | 0.188 | 0.126 | 0.241 | 0.349 | 0.404 | ||
Observations | 365 | 365 | 356 | 356 | 184 | 184 | ||
Countries | 104 | 104 | 101 | 101 | 64 | 64 | ||
3. wr and interaction with M2-GDP | ||||||||
fitted wr | 1.536 | −2.526 | 1.007 | −3.998 | 0.187 | 6.488 | ||
(3.22)*** | (0.88) | (2.15)** | (1.38) | (0.34) | (1.20) | |||
fitted wr X M2-GDP | −0.431 | −0.669 | −0.284 | −0.395 | −0.046 | 0.092 | ||
(3.08)*** | (2.07)** | (2.07)** | (1.14) | (0.28) | (0.24) | |||
R 2 | 0.060 | 0.197 | 0.136 | 0.237 | 0.349 | 0.384 | ||
Observations | 365 | 365 | 356 | 356 | 184 | 184 | ||
Countries | 104 | 104 | 101 | 101 | 64 | 64 |
OLS and Fixed-Effects Instrumental Variables Regressions Explaining Per Capita GDP Growth as a Function of Workers’ Remittances and Different Conditioning Sets, Emerging Economies
Conditioning Sets of Variables | ||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Basic Conditioning Set: Excludes Domestic Investment |
Basic Conditioning Set Plus Domestic Investment |
Full Conditioning Set, Including Institutional Variable |
||||||
OLS-IV | Fixed Effects-IV |
OLS-IV | Fixed Effects-IV |
OLS-IV | Fixed Effects-IV |
|||
Sample: Emerging Economies | ||||||||
Specification: | ||||||||
1. wr only | ||||||||
fitted wr | 0.094 | −5.312 | 0.052 | −5.732 | 0.035 | 6.877 | ||
(1.06) | (2.08)** | (0.60) | (2.33)** | (0.34) | (1.34) | |||
R 2 | 0.038 | 0.183 | 0.128 | 0.233 | 0.388 | 0.384 | ||
Observations | 365 | 365 | 356 | 356 | 184 | 184 | ||
Countries | 104 | 104 | 101 | 101 | 64 | 64 | ||
2. wr and wr-squared | ||||||||
fitted wr | 0.039 | −4.993 | 0.012 | −5.348 | 0.039 | 3.926 | ||
(0.36) | (1.95)* | (0.11) | (2.17)** | (0.30) | (0.74) | |||
fitted wr-squared | −0.027 | −1.069 | −0.019 | −1.325 | 0.003 | −2.145 | ||
(0.91) | (1.29) | (0.64) | (1.66)* | (0.06) | (1.96) | |||
R 2 | 0.037 | 0.188 | 0.126 | 0.241 | 0.349 | 0.404 | ||
Observations | 365 | 365 | 356 | 356 | 184 | 184 | ||
Countries | 104 | 104 | 101 | 101 | 64 | 64 | ||
3. wr and interaction with M2-GDP | ||||||||
fitted wr | 1.536 | −2.526 | 1.007 | −3.998 | 0.187 | 6.488 | ||
(3.22)*** | (0.88) | (2.15)** | (1.38) | (0.34) | (1.20) | |||
fitted wr X M2-GDP | −0.431 | −0.669 | −0.284 | −0.395 | −0.046 | 0.092 | ||
(3.08)*** | (2.07)** | (2.07)** | (1.14) | (0.28) | (0.24) | |||
R 2 | 0.060 | 0.197 | 0.136 | 0.237 | 0.349 | 0.384 | ||
Observations | 365 | 365 | 356 | 356 | 184 | 184 | ||
Countries | 104 | 104 | 101 | 101 | 64 | 64 |
The first two tables, which show estimations using wr, provide little evidence of an impact of workers’ remittances on economic growth through the TFP channel; a positive significant impact of remittances on growth arises only in a few OLS regressions, and mainly in the first column, where the conditioning set does not include the investment ratio. Once the investment ratio or country fixed effects are included, many significant impacts on growth disappear. Furthermore, the square of wr is often negative but does not reach statistical significance in any of the regressions, thus ruling out a quadratic effect of remittances on growth. Regarding the credit constraint hypothesis, although the term for the interaction between wr and the financial deepening variable (the M2-to-GDP ratio) tends to be negative across most regressions, it is significant in only one case: the OLS estimation for emerging economies that excludes the investment ratio (first column of Table 7.2). Thus, there might be a small effect of remittances easing credit constraints in countries with small banking systems. However, it should be stressed that such an effect would operate primarily through investment volume, since the interaction term becomes nonsignificant once the investment ratio is included, and such an effect is difficult to separate from the country fixed effects, since it also disappears once these are included.
One additional feature of the estimations is that there are only minor differences between the results for the full country and emerging economy samples. Since most industrial countries historically have not tended to report remittance inflows, few observations are lost when the growth regressions exclude these countries. The main difference in results was highlighted in the preceding paragraph: that the negative interaction between remittances and financial deepening appears to be slightly stronger within the emerging economy sample.
Tables 7.3 and 7.4 show the results of the instrumental variables estimations, using fitted wr as the relevant explanatory variable. Two main results contrast with those discussed in the last paragraph. First, some of the fixed-effects estimations, primarily those obtained under the second conditioning set, reveal a significant negative impact of remittances on economic growth. That is, the portion of domestic remittance inflows that is related to global trends in remittances appears to have a negative impact on economic growth. Given that the second conditioning set includes the investment rate, this effect must be operating primarily through a reduction in TFP. In some cases, the squared term of the fitted remittances is also negative and significant.
Second, the significance of the (negative) term for the interaction between remittances and financial deepening increases in the instrumental variables estimation. However, it is not always clear that the direct impact of workers’ remittances is positive; thus, whereas it appears that higher remittances coupled with greater financial deepening may be related to lower rates of economic growth, it is not clear whether even at very low levels of financial deepening remittances can have a positive impact. For example, in the second column of Table 7.4, the interaction term is negative and significant, but the direct impact is negative and nonsignificant. Thus, even in the most underdeveloped financial system, remittances would not have a positive impact on economic growth.
The estimation results show that it is difficult to obtain a robust positive effect of workers’ remittances on economic growth. In many of the specifications, the remittances-to-GDP ratio has no significant correlation with economic growth. A positive and significant coefficient on remittances appears only when investment is excluded from the estimation and in the absence of country fixed effects. To the extent that country fixed effects proxy for differences in investment, this specification is a better indication of remittances’ true contribution to growth. On the other hand, the country fixed-effects results may be indicating that the contribution of remittances to growth is highly dependent on individual country circumstances. The results suggest, moreover, that remittances may be reducing economic growth in many countries. When endogeneity is controlled for, the effect of remittances becomes negative and significant regardless of whether investment is excluded. This negative effect appears to be operating through a reduction in TFP, in accordance with the theoretical descriptions of how remittances can reduce growth.
Remittances and Macroeconomic Volatility
This section examines the relationship between macroeconomic volatility and remittances and relates it to the findings of previous chapters. The evidence presented in Chapters 4 and 5 suggests that macro-economic fluctuations exert a strong influence on remittances. But this same evidence, as well as the evidence analyzed in the previous section, suggests that remittances also affect economic fluctuations. As in the case of the correlation between remittances and GDP growth, there exist multiple pathways through which remittances can influence economic volatility, and these pathways imply contradictory effects.
Much of the theoretical evidence examined in Chapter 4 suggests that remittances are motivated by altruism, which implies a desire among migrants to compensate their households for the negative impacts of economic fluctuations in the home country. In addition, the empirical evidence presented in that chapter shows that remittances tend to be compensatory rather than opportunistic. In other words, remittances enable recipient households to smooth their consumption over time. This implies that if they are large enough, remittances will reduce economic fluctuations in a remittance-receiving country.
Remittances can also reduce the volatility of investment through two distinct pathways. First, because firms rely mostly on internal financing to fund their investments, smoother consumption implies smoother business earnings and hence smoother investment. Second, to the extent that remittances flow through the financial system, they may make it easier for firms to borrow and hence can enable firms to smooth their investment expenditures over time.
On the other hand, remittances may change recipients’ behaviors in ways that tend to increase economic volatility. This is a further implication of the moral hazard argument discussed in the chapter’s first section. First, there is a moral hazard in terms of labor income. If remittance recipients reduce their labor effort, this will increase the likelihood of poor firm performance, effectively imposing more risk on firms. Risk-neutral firms will react by adjusting labor contracts in ways that shift this risk back onto the households: by increasing the dispersion of wages and employment levels over the business cycle. The increased dispersion of firm earnings and wage income will then lead to increased economic volatility. Furthermore, the theoretical model presented in Chapter 6 also indicates that remittances may generate increased economic volatility if the presence of remittances causes household labor supply to become more procyclical. There is also a moral hazard in terms of investment effort. Recipients will choose riskier projects, or expend less effort on their existing investment projects, leading to an increased dispersion of investment returns and hence an increase in output volatility.
Two recent studies, IMF (2005) and World Bank (2006), estimated the correlation between remittances and output volatility.9 The IMF (2005), in conjunction with the growth estimations described in the previous section, found negative and significant relationships between the total remittances–to–GDP ratio and several measures of volatility: GDP volatility, consumption volatility, and investment volatility (all defined as the standard deviation of the annual growth rate of the variable). The study also used the largest annual decline in GDP over the period as an alternate measure of volatility and obtained similar results. The World Bank (2006) performed a panel estimation of the determinants of output growth volatility in conjunction with the growth regressions discussed in the previous section. In addition to total remittances–to–GDP, control variables were inflation, monetary policy, and fiscal policy volatility; real exchange rate overvaluation; frequency of banking crises; trade openness; terms of trade and foreign growth rate volatilities; country fixed effects; and time period effects. The study found a negative and significant coefficient on the ratio of total remittances to GDP that was robust to the different instruments used.
Given that the IMF and World Bank studies did not use the preferred definition of remittances, it is important to conduct new volatility estimations using this variable. Therefore, a cross-sectional regression was estimated for a sample of 70 countries, comprising 16 advanced economies and 54 developing countries. The dependent variable in the regression is defined as the standard deviation of real per capita GDP growth over the 1970–2004 period.10 The explanatory variables are similar to those that have been used in other studies examining output volatility (e.g., Easterly, Islam, and Stiglitz, 2001; Kose, Prasad, and Terrones, 2003)—relative income, relative income squared, terms of trade volatility, trade openness, financial openness, government consumption, institutional quality, an indicator of financial sector development, a trade concentration ratio, and an indicator of the commodity composition of exports—plus the ratio of workers’ remittances to GDP. Data sources and definitions of the variables are discussed in the appendix to this chapter. The explanatory variables are constructed as averages over the 1970–2004 period, except for the relative income variable, which is measured using its value in 1970, with at least 15 years of available data for a particular country required for inclusion of that country in the sample for the variable. Also, the averages for the variables are calculated including only data for those years for which data are present for all the explanatory variables included in the regression.
An OLS regression was estimated including all the possible explanatory variables in the regression. A preferred-specification regression was also conducted, with insignificant variables dropped from the regression, using a country sample identical to that employed in the regression that included all of the explanatory variables. The results of the cross-country regression, presented in Table 7.5, indicate that there is a negative relationship between workers’ remittances and the volatility of output and that this relationship is of marginal statistical significance. In practical terms, an increase in the workers’ remittances–to–GDP ratio of one percentage point leads to a reduction of 0.164 percent in the standard deviation of GDP growth, according to the regression results. This implies that countries with high workers’ remittances–to–GDP ratios experience significantly lower economic volatility than they would in the absence of remittances. Interestingly, the estimated coefficient on remittances has the same sign and nearly the same magnitude as the estimated coefficients in the studies mentioned previously. Figure 7.1 plots output volatility against the ratio of workers’ remittances to GDP for the countries in the regression sample and suggests that the negative relationship found in the regression would have been stronger if not for the presence of one outlier (Jordan).
Cross-Sectional Regression Explaining GDP Volatility as a Function of Workers’ Remittances and Conditioning Variables
Cross-Sectional Regression Explaining GDP Volatility as a Function of Workers’ Remittances and Conditioning Variables
Conditioning Set of Variables | ||
---|---|---|
Workers’ remittances to GDP | −0.164 | |
(−1.68)* | ||
Terms of trade volatility | 0.090 | |
(1.95)* | ||
Financial openness | 0.012 | |
(2.04)** | ||
Commodity export composition | 0.016 | |
(1.79)* | ||
Government consumption to GDP | 0.066 | |
(1.75)* | ||
Government consumption to GDP | −0.064 | |
* Industrial | (−2.28)** | |
R 2 | 0.374 | |
Observations | 70 |
Cross-Sectional Regression Explaining GDP Volatility as a Function of Workers’ Remittances and Conditioning Variables
Conditioning Set of Variables | ||
---|---|---|
Workers’ remittances to GDP | −0.164 | |
(−1.68)* | ||
Terms of trade volatility | 0.090 | |
(1.95)* | ||
Financial openness | 0.012 | |
(2.04)** | ||
Commodity export composition | 0.016 | |
(1.79)* | ||
Government consumption to GDP | 0.066 | |
(1.75)* | ||
Government consumption to GDP | −0.064 | |
* Industrial | (−2.28)** | |
R 2 | 0.374 | |
Observations | 70 |
Output Volatility and the Ratio of Workers’ Remittances to GDP
(In percent)
Sources: World Bank (2006) and authors’ calculations.The results of the foregoing estimation seem to imply that the volatility-dampening effects of remittances out-weigh the volatility-increasing effects described earlier. But there are several reasons why the empirical results do not necessarily support this conclusion. First, there is a data measurement issue. The theoretical model underlying the moral hazard effect is a business cycle model, similar to that used in Chapter 6, so its predictions are most relevant to variables measured at business cycle frequencies, say, quarterly or annually. The empirical exercises use long-run estimates of volatility out of necessity, so their results are not directly applicable to the theoretical model. Second, the theoretical model assumes that resources, most notably labor, are fully employed. In reality, most countries that receive remittances have high rates of under- or unemployment. Thus, the average household in remittance-receiving countries probably does not exhibit the strong labor-leisure trade-off present in the theoretical model, like those calibrated in the cash and credit economies of Chapter 6. Finally, given the evidence on remittances and investment presented in Chapter 4 as well as in the preceding section, any impact remittances may have on the riskiness of investment is probably too small to detect in aggregate data.
Nevertheless, the empirical results support the idea that remittances reduce macroeconomic volatility over long horizons. Yet the exercise does not shed light on the exact mechanism by which remittances reduce such volatility. Given the analysis on motives, intended uses, and end uses of remittances from Chapter 4 and the simulation results from Chapter 6, it appears likely that remittances reduce output volatility at the aggregate level because they dampen consumption volatility at the household level. The increased smoothness of consumption has a direct impact on measured GDP volatility, since consumption accounts for a large share of GDP. This will remain a conjecture, however, until detailed longitudinal studies of household consumption and investment, including both households that do and those that do not receive remittances, are conducted.
Workers’ Remittances and the Equilibrium Real Exchange Rate
As indicated in Chapter 5, one of the most important potential macroeconomic effects of remittance inflows is on the recipient country’s equilibrium real exchange rate. Changes in the equilibrium real exchange rate not only affect the distributional impacts of remittance inflows, both by altering the returns to factors employed in the traded and nontraded goods sectors and by affecting the relative price of traded and non-traded consumption goods, but may also be one of the mechanisms through which remittance flows exert their main impact on long-run growth, via Dutch disease effects. Deriving the theoretical implications of remittance inflows for the long-run equilibrium real exchange rates in recipient countries requires the use of a macroeconomic model. Surprisingly, there has been relatively little analytical work on t his issue. The discussion in this section is based on Montiel (2006), which explored the effects of remittance receipts on the longrun equilibrium real exchange rate in the context of a fairly standard two-sector open economy model. The equilibrium real exchange rate in the model is defined in Nurksian terms as the value of the real exchange rate that is simultaneously consistent with internal and external balance, conditioned on sustainable values of the economy’s underlying real fundamentals.
External balance refers to a situation in which the ongoing current account deficit is financed by sustainable capital inflows. In the model of Montiel (2006), this condition generates a positive trade-off between the real exchange rate and real domestic consumption (measured in units of traded goods), because an increase in domestic consumption creates an excess demand for traded goods, requiring a real depreciation to generate the offsetting excess supply required to maintain the trade balance at the level that can be financed by sustainable capital flows. The resulting locus is depicted as curve EB in Figure 7.2. On the other hand, internal balance refers to a situation in which the market for nontraded goods is in equilibrium at full employment. This condition generates a negative trade-off between the real exchange rate and real domestic consumption, since the excess demand for nontraded goods caused by an increase in domestic consumption requires a real appreciation to sustain equilibrium in the market for nontraded goods. The implied internal balance locus is depicted as curve IB in Figure 7.2. The intersection of these loci at point A in Figure 7.2, where external and internal balance hold simultaneously, determines the long-run equilibrium real exchange rate.
Remittances and the Equilibrium Real Exchange Rate
Interpreted as an exogenous transfer from the rest of the world, workers’ remittances are a component of the current account and thus affect the position of the EB curve. However, since remittances have no direct effect on the market for nontraded goods, changes in remittance flows leave the IB curve undisturbed.11 For a given level of capital inflows, a larger inflow of remittances permits the economy to sustain a larger trade deficit, and thus a more-appreciated real exchange rate, without violating the external balance condition. Thus, an increase in remittance receipts shifts the EB curve downward, resulting in a more-appreciated long-run equilibrium real exchange rate and a higher level of real domestic consumption, as shown at point B. Note that the quantitative effect of the change in remittance flows on the equilibrium real exchange rate depends on the elasticities of the external and internal balance curves, such that the more elastic these curves are, the smaller the change in the equilibrium real exchange rate resulting from a change in the amount of remittances. Thus, alterations in remittance flows have a smaller impact on the equilibrium real exchange rate the greater the degree of substitutability between traded and nontraded goods in both production and consumption.
Elements of the preceding analysis underlie the standard presumption that higher remittance flows are likely to result in an appreciation of the equilibrium real exchange rate. However, the analysis relies on several special assumptions. Montiel (2006) shows the following:
-
If remittance inflows include a component that is inversely related to real income in the recipient country, a change in the exogenous component of remittance receipts has weaker effects on the equilibrium than in the absence of this endogenous component.
-
Similarly, if remittance receipts are disproportionately devoted to spending on traded goods (say, because remittances are transferred in kind, or because they are used to import consumer durables), their effects on the long-run equilibrium real exchange rate tend to be weakened, and in the limit can be eliminated altogether. For example, if all remittance receipts are devoted to spending on traded goods, then the EB and IB curves in Figure 7.2 both shift to the right by exactly equal amounts in response to an increase in remittances. In that case, long-run domestic real consumption increases by the amount of increased remittance income, but the long-run equilibrium real exchange rate remains unchanged.
-
Somewhat surprisingly, if the receiving country’s external creditors treat remittance receipts as part of that country’s wealth, and if an increase in remittance receipts consequently lowers the risk premium the country faces in international capital markets, then a permanent increase in such receipts gives rise to a transitory consumption boom in the recipient country, but its long-run equilibrium real exchange rate remains unaffected.
Based on these considerations, the presumption from theory is that a permanent increase in remittance inflows is associated with an appreciation of the recipient economy’s long-run equilibrium real exchange rate. However, under certain empirically plausible conditions, this effect may be weak, or even absent altogether. Thus the effect of remittance receipts on the equilibrium real exchange rate is an empirical question.
The next step for understanding the relationship between remittances and the real exchange rate, beyond casual data analysis, is to include remittances in the standard exchange rate estimation. Despite their empirical importance for many countries and the strong theoretical presumption that remittance inflows affect the equilibrium real exchange rate, the literature on equilibrium real exchange rate estimation has not typically incorporated remittance flows into the set of real exchange rate fundamentals. The studies that do incorporate remittances into this set of fundamentals have focused on the experience both of individual countries and of various country groupings as well. Such studies typically include remittance flows in the set of fundamentals that enter a cointegrating equation for the real exchange rate, thus controlling for other potential real exchange rate determinants in a single-country or panel context. An early single-country study by Bourdet and Falck (2003) examined the effect of workers’ remittances on the equilibrium real exchange rate in Cape Verde over the period 1980–2000, confirming the conventional view that an increase in remittance receipts is associated with an appreciation of the equilibrium real exchange rate. Similar results were obtained by Hyder and Mahboob (2005), who found that higher remittance inflows tended to appreciate the equilibrium real exchange rate in Pakistan during 1978–2005, as well as by Saadi-Sedik and Petri (2006), who derived the same result for Jordan over 1964–2005.
For a sample of six Central American and Caribbean countries, Izquierdo and Montiel (2006) obtained mixed results over the period 1960–2004. They followed a procedure aimed at identifying cointegrating relationships between the real effective exchange rate and a set of nonstationary fundamental variables. Starting with a full set of possible fundamental variables—which included, in addition to the ratio of workers’ remittances to GDP, a measure of average labor productivity; the ratios to GDP of government consumption and of the international investor position; trade openness; and terms of trade—their procedure eliminated those variables that did not form part of a cointegrating vector or those whose sign was not theoretically appropriate. Table 7.6 shows the final cointegrating vectors Izquierdo and Montiel obtained. In Honduras, Jamaica, and Nicaragua, the authors found no influence of workers’ remittances on the equilibrium real exchange rate—that is, workers’ remittances were not part of a cointegrating vector with the real effective exchange rate—despite the fact that these countries received very large remittance inflows over the last half of their sample. For the Dominican Republic, El Salvador, and Guatemala, however, remittance inflows turned out to be important determinants of the equilibrium real exchange rate, with an increase in remittance inflows having a much more powerful effect on equilibrium real exchange rate appreciation in El Salvador and Guatemala than in the Dominican Republic.
Cointegrating Relations for the Real Exchange Rate, 1960–2004
Cointegrating Relations for the Real Exchange Rate, 1960–2004
Dominican Republic |
El Salvador | Guatemala | Honduras | Jamaica | Nicaragua | ||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Workers’ remittances/GDP | −1.085 | −35.255 | −44.611 | ||||
(0.720) | (0.444) | (2.937) | |||||
Other nonstattonary fundamentals | |||||||
Average productivity of labor | −0.174 | 6.626 | −5.340 | −7.544 | 22.091 | ||
(0.409) | (0.662) | (0.814) | (0.725) | (5.088) | |||
Government consumption/GDP | −0.410 | −0.010 | −0.028 | −0.025 | −0.008 | ||
(0.012) | (0.006) | (0.008) | (0.002) | (0.019) | |||
Trade openness | 0.008 | 0.003 | |||||
(0.008) | (0.000) | ||||||
Terms of trade | −0.006 | −0.003 | −0.007 | −0.065 | |||
(0.001) | (0.001) | (0.000) | (0.010) | ||||
International investor position/GDP | −0.004 | −0.003 | |||||
(0.000) | (0.000) | ||||||
Time trend | 0.241 | 0.069 | −0.032 | −0.061 | 0.222 | ||
(0.004) | (0.005) | (0.005) | (0.003) | (0.065) |
Cointegrating Relations for the Real Exchange Rate, 1960–2004
Dominican Republic |
El Salvador | Guatemala | Honduras | Jamaica | Nicaragua | ||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Workers’ remittances/GDP | −1.085 | −35.255 | −44.611 | ||||
(0.720) | (0.444) | (2.937) | |||||
Other nonstattonary fundamentals | |||||||
Average productivity of labor | −0.174 | 6.626 | −5.340 | −7.544 | 22.091 | ||
(0.409) | (0.662) | (0.814) | (0.725) | (5.088) | |||
Government consumption/GDP | −0.410 | −0.010 | −0.028 | −0.025 | −0.008 | ||
(0.012) | (0.006) | (0.008) | (0.002) | (0.019) | |||
Trade openness | 0.008 | 0.003 | |||||
(0.008) | (0.000) | ||||||
Terms of trade | −0.006 | −0.003 | −0.007 | −0.065 | |||
(0.001) | (0.001) | (0.000) | (0.010) | ||||
International investor position/GDP | −0.004 | −0.003 | |||||
(0.000) | (0.000) | ||||||
Time trend | 0.241 | 0.069 | −0.032 | −0.061 | 0.222 | ||
(0.004) | (0.005) | (0.005) | (0.003) | (0.065) |
Given the small set of countries examined in single-country studies to date, it is difficult to generalize from these results. However, other researchers have used panel methods to examine the effects of remittance inflows on the real exchange rate for larger samples of countries. Amuedo-Dorantes and Pozo (2004), for example, used a panel with 13 Latin American and Caribbean countries over the period 1978–98 and found that an increase in workers’ remittances appreciated the real exchange rate. Holzner (2006) derived the same result using a worldwide sample. In contrast with these results, Rajan and Subramanian (2005) found, for a sample of 15 countries during the 1990s, that higher remittance receipts were not associated with slower growth in manufacturing industries with higher labor intensity or greater export orientation, as one might expect if remittance receipts are associated with Dutch disease effects operating through an appreciated real exchange rate.
Thus, although neither the single-country nor panel evidence speaks with a single voice, most of the research to date is consistent with the conventional presumption that higher remittance receipts tend to appreciate the equilibrium real exchange rate. The implication is that if Dutch disease effects are indeed present, the beneficial short-run effects of remittance inflows on economic welfare in the recipient countries through higher and more stable levels of consumption may come at the expense of reduced long-run growth. Chapter 8 considers the policy challenge posed by this trade-off.
Remittances, Fiscal Policy, and Debt Sustainability
The notion that remittances have a significant effect on fiscal policy and debt sustainability may at first be surprising, since governments have no direct claims on these person-to-person transfers. The fact that remittances enter the recipient economy through family transfers means that remittances affect fiscal policy and debt sustainability indirectly through the activities of remittance-receiving households, primarily through their consumption decisions and saving patterns. In this respect remittances are quite different from natural resources, which governments may own and from which they derive revenue, and public aid transfers, which enter the government budget constraint directly. Since remittances contribute to higher consumption of domestic and imported goods, they may affect government revenues through consumption- and trade-based taxation.12 Furthermore, remittances may lead to increased deposits in the banking system and, to the extent that the marginal propensity to consume is less than unity, they may increase the level of private saving. Both of these channels may affect fiscal policy through credit market activity. As a result, remittances can play an important role in the assessment of a country’s debt sustainability, since they alter the fiscal balance and the evolution of the stocks of public and private sector liabilities over time.
To illustrate this concept, this section examines a simplified economy in which the government issues only domestic-currency-denominated debt. Furthermore, it is assumed that the household in this simplified economy receives remittances only in terms of domestic currency.13 Sustainability conditions are derived from the household and government budget constraints to illustrate the channel through which remittances alter the accumulation of liabilities and affect debt sustainability. After debt sustainability conditions are derived in this simplified setting, the more complex case with foreign-currency-denominated debt and the need to transfer remittances across the exchange rate is considered.
The government’s intertemporal budget constraint in the presence of remittances, derived explicitly in Box 7.1, is useful for understanding the impact of remittances on fiscal policy choices. Since the stock of debt issued during the previous period, Bt, must be taken as a given state variable, increases in remittances that do not result in a one-to-one increase in household consumption will support new sequences of taxes, money growth, and bond issuance. For example, given a stream of future tax revenues chosen by the fiscal authority and a future stream of money growth chosen by the monetary authority, an increase in remittances will be met with an increase in future debt issuance, Bt+i+1, for some future period. The increase in government bond issuance can be viewed as a mechanism to absorb additional levels of household saving, St+i, and support the household’s desire to smooth consumption across time. If these flows were instead channeled through the financial system, an increase in remittances that led to additional household saving could also lead to increases in financial system liabilities, which in turn could lead to additional private and public sector credit provision.
Remittances and Fiscal Sustainability
Remittances are unrequited, nonmarket personal transfers between households across countries, and as such they enter the household budget constraint as an addition to income separate from the domestic production process. Previously accumulated stocks of money balances (M) and real government bonds (B), income from production (Y) net of taxes (T), and real remittance transfers (Rem) are all used to finance household expenditures (C). In this simplified setting the aggregate household budget constraint is
where R is the gross domestic interest rate, or R = (1 + r), where r is the net domestic interest rate, and P is the price level. The government uses taxes, money creation, and real bond issuance to finance its expenditures (G) according to
Under the assumption that household and government consumption includes public and private investment, the economy-wide resource constraint is
A clearer picture of the effect of remittances on fiscal policy choices, including debt creation, can be obtained through examination of the intertemporal government budget constraint. Substituting for successive bond terms in the government budget constraint yields
where μ is the growth rate of nominal money balances and
The usual interpretation of this exercise is that a positive stock of debt in the present period must eventually be paid for by generating fiscal surpluses or money creation. Using the economy-wide resource constraint to substitute for the future sequence of government spending results in
where St+i is the level of household saving.
However, should the fiscal authority not want to increase future debt levels, the increase in remittances given a future stream of monetary policy will be met by an increase in future tax revenue. Though remittances do not enter directly into the government budget constraint and empirical evidence suggests that governments do not tax remittances directly, governments receive tax revenue from remittances indirectly. As shown in Chapter 6, additional tax revenue may be collected with the least amount of distortion through a consumption-based tax system.14 Consequently, remittances can be viewed as part of the potential tax base in addition to labor income from production, depending on the tax structure in place. Finally, for a given stream of future tax revenue and bond issuance by the fiscal authority, the monetary authority may also meet an increase in remittances with an increase in money creation. In this regard, inflows of remittances have macroeconomic policy implications similar to those of inflows of market-based capital, and countries that operate within inflation-target regimes need to conduct liquidity operations to deal with any changes in liquidity resulting from remittances.
To examine some of the implications of remittances for fiscal policy and debt levels, data were assembled from the IMF World Economic Outlook database and the World Bank’s World Development Indicators for the top 20 remittance-receiving economies, based on the average ratio of remittances to GDP between 1990 and 2005. Averages were computed for the ratio of workers’ remittances to GDP, credit to the government as a percentage of total credit, the net general government debt-to-GDP ratio, and government consumption as a percentage of GDP. The minimum and maximum average remittances-to-GDP ratios in this sample were 3.1 and 18.3 percent, respectively. As the countries in the data set are a subset of remittance-receiving economies, any results drawn from this data set should be interpreted as relating to economies that can be characterized as significantly remittance dependent.15
As shown in the first panel of Figure 7.3, the ratio of workers’ remittances to GDP has a positive relationship with the ratio of credit to the government to total credit, indicating that the banking system tends to channel additional household saving from remittances into credit provision to the government as opposed to the private sector. The figure’s second panel plots the relationship between the ratio of average workers’ remittances to GDP and the average net general government debt-to-GDP ratio. The positive relationship suggests that remittances also tend to result in higher levels of public sector debt. Finally, the third panel in Figure 7.3 plots the relationship between the ratios of average workers’ remittances to GDP and average government consumption to GDP in remittance-dependent economies. The data indicate that the government’s additional financing, whether channeled through the banking system or through an increase in government debt issuance, results in higher government consumption.
Remittance-Dependent Economies and Fiscal Policy, 1990–2005
Sources: IMF (2006b) and World Bank (2006).Note: Variables are averages for each country between 1990 and 2005. Remittance data include workers’ remittances while excluding employee compensation and migrants’ transfers.Given the discussion in earlier chapters regarding the stability of remittance flows and the focus in this chapter on total household resources (i.e., income from production plus remittances) when the intertemporal budget constraint is examined, a more accurate representation of debt sustainability for a country that receives significant remittance flows should employ as a base a more-aggregated measure of income than GDP. For example, gross national disposable income (GNDI) could be used instead of GDP when the evolution of liabilities in an open economy setting is computed. However, GNDI includes net factor income from nonresidents and public transfers, including grants, and may therefore be inappropriate, depending on the composition of flows that a particular country receives. Net factor income may not be suitable for inclusion as part of the potential revenue base of the fiscal authority, and public sector transfers may be lumpy and inconsistent over time. An alternative to using GNDI would be to construct a measure of GDP plus net current private transfers.
Normalizing the intertemporal government budget constraint in Box 7.1 by the sum of income from production and remittances yields the traditional debt sustainability relationship in terms of the debt-to-GNDI ratio, less net factor income and public transfers. Setting i = 0 and ignoring the use of money creation in debt financing results in the following equation describing the approximate evolution of debt in terms of growth rates:
where b is the stock of domestic-currency-denominated government debt, r is the net interest rate, π is the growth rate of the GDP deflator, γ is the growth rate of real GDP, η is the growth rate of remittances in domestic currency terms, and (tt − gt) is taxes less noninterest government spending, or the primary fiscal balance. In this case, for a given set of remaining variables, increases in the growth rate of remittances in domestic currency units improve debt sustainability.
A more complete derivation of (7.1) to assess debt sustainability would also include exchange rate effects on remittances and foreign currency debt issued by the public sector. In addition to the sustainability of public sector debt, remittances also affect external sustainability through their inclusion in net transfers as part of the noninterest current account balance. Box 7.2 discusses the role of remittances and external sustainability. Including the government’s foreign currency debt and the need to translate remittance flows across currencies results in a debt evolution equation of
Remittances and External Sustainability
Assessments of external sustainability are a key element in IMF surveillance of member countries and involve forming a view of how outstanding stocks of liabilities are likely to evolve over time. External debt evolves according to
where D represents the stock of public and private external debt and CAB the noninterest current account balance in U.S. dollars. Separating the components of the noninterest current account means the equation can also be written as
where TB is the balance on goods and services, Inc represents the balance on income less interest, and Tr is net current transfers, which includes workers’ remittances.
Normalizing the preceding equation by nominal GDP results in an external debt-to-GDP ratio of
where γ is the growth rate of real GDP and ρ is the growth rate of the U.S. dollar value of the GDP deflator.1 Here, lowercase variables (d, tb, inc, tr) are used to denote ratios to GDP (of D, TB, Inc, and Tr, respectively). The change in the debt-to-GDP ratio is then
According to this debt dynamics equation, an increase in the level of the remittances-to-GDP ratio, all else equal, improves external sustainability. Remittances also have indirect beneficial effects on debt dynamics to the extent that their presence reduces external borrowing costs and causes the domestic currency to appreciate.
However, as mentioned in the chapter text, the improvement in debt dynamics should be qualified when the empirical results regarding the cyclicality of remittance flows and any potential adverse effects of real exchange rate appreciation are considered. An increase in domestic GDP relative to GDP abroad will improve debt dynamics through the coefficient on dt but will be offset somewhat by a decline in remittances (e.g., transfers) and any increased demand for imports. Conversely, a relative increase in GDP abroad will lead to higher remittance inflows and possibly increase the demand for exports, both of which should lead to improvements in sustainability. Finally, external sustainability will improve if remittance transfers result in a real appreciation of the domestic currency, but such an appreciation will also adversely affect exports.
1 External sustainability analysis uses variables in U.S. dollars following traditional balance of payments accounting, whereas fiscal sustainability is analyzed in terms of domestic currency. The variable ρ captures the growth rate of the U.S. dollar value of the GDP deflator, which is similar to the use of changes in the GDP deflator (π) and the exchange rate (ε) in equations (7.1) and (7.2).where lowercase terms denote ratios to income from production and remittances (Yt+i + Remt+i) in domestic currency terms, ε = (et+1 − et)/et is the change in the exchange rate (e), defined as units of domestic currency per U.S. dollar, r* is the net interest rate on foreign-currency-denominated debt, bf is the stock of foreign-currency-denominated debt, and η is defined as ηt = 1 + (Remtt ∙ et)/Yt.
For a given exchange rate, an increase in the ratio of remittances to GDP in period t + 1 relative to period t improves debt dynamics, since ηt+1 increases relative to ηt. Essentially, the government’s potential revenue base has increased. An increase in the exchange rate, et+1 > et, however, has offsetting effects; it leads to an increase in the domestic currency value of foreign currency debt, which worsens sustainability. This can be observed in the numerator on the coefficient of bf (i.e., Δε > 0). On the other hand, an identical increase in the exchange rate for a given level of the remittances-to-GDP ratio improves sustainability through ηt+1 > ηt, because each unit of remittance inflow in foreign currency is worth more in terms of domestic currency than before. The exchange rate effect on remittances therefore serves as a potential channel for offsetting the upward adjustment in the debt stock from a depreciation of the domestic currency. The ability of remittances to serve as a buffer against exchange rate shocks depends on many factors, including the source country of the remittance flows, the stability of those flows, the response of remittances to changes in the exchange rate, and the degree to which remittances augment the government’s revenue base.
The empirical results on the cyclicality of remittance flows from Chapter 4, any potential adverse effects of real exchange rate appreciation as discussed in Chapter 5, and any effects of remittances on economic growth as examined earlier in this chapter should be taken into consideration as potential qualifiers on any improvement in debt dynamics. For example, an increase in domestic GDP relative to GDP abroad will improve debt dynamics, but a decline in remittances due to the countercyclicality of these flows, highlighted in Chapter 4, will offset this somewhat. Conversely, a relative increase in GDP abroad will lead to higher remittance inflows, which lead to improvements in sustainability either through a higher growth rate in equation (7.1) or via a higher remittances-to-GDP ratio in equation (7.2). Finally, debt sustainability will improve if remittance transfers result in a generalized real appreciation of the domestic currency.16
In the absence of remittances, the typical evaluation of an economy’s ability to sustain its debt level relies solely on a comparison of the growth in the country’s domestic income vis-à-vis the interest rate on its debt. As the remittance-determination equation in Chapter 4 shows, the growth rate in the remittance-sending country also positively affects remittances. This implies that periods of high growth in that country will lead to higher remittances, which will enhance the ability of the government in the remittance-receiving country to sustain its current policy stance, even if the local economy is concurrently experiencing a period of low growth. Consequently, the increased importance of remittance flows worldwide has opened a new channel through which changes in domestic income, income abroad, and market prices such as exchange rates and interest rates may have an impact on debt sustainability. The elasticities of remittances with respect to changes in these variables have become necessary inputs into a complete assessment of sustainability for countries that receive significant inflows of remittances relative to GDP.
In conclusion, in countries that receive remittance flows in sufficient quantities, the presence of remittances can support higher future debt levels, a finding that accords with the empirical conclusions in this section regarding the correlation between remittances, banking sector credit to the public sector, and public debt levels. These higher debt levels tend to be associated with increased government spending, yielding a positive correlation between remittances and the level of government spending in remittance-dependent economies, corroborating the empirical finding in this chapter that countries with higher remittances tend to have higher levels of government spending. In addition to the traditional focus on the stance of fiscal policy and the rate of domestic GDP growth versus interest rates in assessing sustainability, the ability of remittance-dependent economies to carry higher public sector debt loads also depends on the persistence of remittance flows and the elasticity of these flows with respect to income differentials, interest rate differentials, and changes in exchange rates, as estimated using the remittance-determination equation in Chapter 4. Inclusion of remittances in the government’s potential revenue base, however, depends on the tax structure in place and the government’s ability to access this potential tax base without injecting undue distortions into economic activity, a subject examined more thoroughly in the explicit theoretical monetary model in Chapter 6.
Appendix 7.1. Data Definitions, Sources, and Coverage
This appendix provides definitions and data sources for the variables used in the cross-sectional regressions in this chapter. It also defines the country groupings.
Data Definitions and Sources
Variables Included in the Preferred-Specification Regression
The following variables were used in the cross-sectional regressions presented in this chapter:
-
Volatility of per capita output growth is defined as the standard deviation of the real GDP per capita growth rate over 1970–2004. Per capita real GDP growth is measured using data on real per capita GDP in constant dollars (international prices, base year 2000) obtained from the Penn World Table, Version 6.2.
-
Workers’ remittances is the ratio of workers’ remittances to GDP. The source of the data is the World Bank’s World Development Indicators database.
-
Terms of trade volatility is measured as the standard deviation of the annual change in the terms of trade over 1970–2004. The source of the data is the IMF’s World Economic Outlook database.
-
Trade openness is defined as the sum of imports and exports of goods and services divided by GDP in constant 2000 prices. The source of the data is the Penn World Table, Version 6.2.
-
Financial openness is defined as the ratio of the stock of foreign liabilities and foreign assets to GDP. The source of the data is Milesi-Ferretti and Lane (2006).
The commodity export composition is the share of primary commodities in total exports. For each country, the average share of primary commodity exports in total exports over the 1999–2004 period is calculated. The calculations are based on information on 44 commodities. The source of the data is the UN Comtrade database.
Government consumption is the ratio of government consumption to GDP in constant 2000 prices. The source of the data is the Penn World Table, Version 6.2.
Variables Not Included in the Preferred-Specification Regression
-
Relative income is the level of real per capita income relative to the United States. The data on real per capita GDP in constant 2000 prices are obtained from Penn World Table, Version 6.2.
-
Relative income squared is the square of relative income.
The trade concentration ratio is the average over 1970–2005 of the ratio of exports to a country’s three largest trading partners to its total exports. The source of the data is the IMF’s Direction of Trade Statistics.
-
Financial sector development is proxied by the average ratio of private sector credit to GDP over the 1970–2005 period. The source of the data is Beck, Demirgüç-Kunt, and Levine (2006).
-
Institutional quality is proxied by an indicator of bureaucracy quality: the strength and expertise of the bureaucracy to govern without drastic changes in policy or interruptions in government services. Alternative indicators of institutional quality also examined in the chapter include (1) an index of corruption: the degree of all forms of corruption such as patronage, nepotism, and suspiciously close ties between politics and business; (2) an index of the rule of law: the strength and impartiality of the legal system and the extent of popular observance of the law; and (3) an aggregate index of institutional quality constructed as the equally weighted average of the bureaucracy quality, corruption, and rule of law indices, reported in the International Country Risk Guide. Each index is constructed as the average over the 1984–2005 period. The indices are rescaled from 1 to 12, with high values indicating good institutions.
Country Coverage
This section lists all the countries included in the data analysis in this chapter. A country’s inclusion in the data set included is determined by the availability of data for all the explanatory variables for that country.
-
Advanced economies (16): Austria, Belgium, Cyprus, Denmark, Finland, France, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Japan, New Zealand, Norway, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, and the United States.
-
Developing countries (54): Argentina, Bolivia, Burkina Faso, Cameroon, Chile, Colombia, Costa Rica, Côte d’Ivoire, the Dominican Republic, Ecuador, Egypt, El Salvador, Ethiopia, Gabon, Ghana, Guatemala, Honduras, Hungary, India, Indonesia, the Islamic Republic of Iran, Jamaica, Jordan, Kenya, the Republic of Korea, Madagascar, Malawi, Malaysia, Mali, Malta, Mexico, Morocco, Nicaragua, Niger, Nigeria, Pakistan, Panama, Papua New Guinea, Paraguay, Peru, the Philippines, Poland, Senegal, Sri Lanka, Sudan, the Syrian Arab Republic, Thailand, Togo, Trinidad and Tobago, Tunisia, Turkey, Uganda, República Bolivariana de Venezuela, and Zimbabwe.
References
Acosta, Pablo A. Lartey, Emmanuel K.K. Mandelman, Federico S. 2007, “Remittances and the Dutch Disease,” Working Paper No. 2007-8 (Atlanta:Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta).
Adelman, Irma Taylor, J. Edward 1990, “Is Structural Adjustment with a Human Face Possible? The Case of Mexico,” Journal of Development Studies, Vol. 26, pp. 387–407.
Amjad, Rashid 1986, “Impact of Workers’ Remittances from the Middle East on Pakistan’s Economy: Some Selected Issues,” Pakistan Development Review, Vol. 25, pp. 757–82.
Amuedo-Dorantes, Catalina Pozo, Susan 2004, “Workers’ Remittances and the Real Exchange Rate: A Paradox of Gifts,” World Development, Vol. 32 (August), pp. 1407–17.
Beck, Thorsten Demirgüç-Kunt, Asli Levine, Ross 2006, “Bank Supervision and Corruption in Lending,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 53 (November), pp. 2131–63.
Bourdet, Yves Falck, Hans 2003, “Emigrants’ Remittances and Dutch Disease in Cape Verde,” Working Paper No. 11 (Kristianstad, Sweden: Kristianstad University College).
Burney, Nadeem 1989, “A Macro-Economic Analysis of the Impact of Workers’ Remittances on Pakistan’s Economy,” in To the Gulf and Back: Studies on the Impact of Asian Labour Migration, ed. by Amjad Rashid (New Delhi: International Labor Organization).
Catrinescu, Natalia León-Ledesma, Miguel Pira-cha, Matloob Quillin, Bryce 2006, “Remittances, Institutions, and Economic Growth,” IZA Discussion Paper No. 2139 (Bonn: Institute for the Study of Labor).
Chami, Ralph Fullenkamp, Connel Jahjah, Samir 2003, “Are Immigrant Remittance Flows a Source of Capital for Development?” IMF Working Paper 03/189 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Durand, Jorge Parrado, Emilio A. Massey, Douglas S. 1996, “Migradollars and Development: A Reconsideration of the Mexican Case,” International Migration Review, Vol. 30 (Summer), pp. 423–44.
Easterly, William Islam, Roumeen Stiglitz, Joseph E. 2001, “Shaken and Stirred: Explaining Growth Volatility,” in Annual World Bank Conference on Development Economics, Pleskovic ed. by Boris Stern Nicholas (Washington: World Bank).
Faini, Riccardo 2002, “Migration, Remittances and Growth” (unpublished; Brescia, Italy:University of Brescia). Available via the Internet: http://www.wider.unu.edu/conference/conference-2002-3/conference%20papers/faini.pdf
Faini, Riccardo 2006, “Migration and Remittances: The Impact on the Countries of Origin” (unpublished; Rome: University of Rome). Available via the Internet: http://www.eudnet. net/download/Faini.pdf
Giuliano,Paola Ruiz-Arranz,Marta 2005, “Remittances, Financial Development, and Growth,” IMF Working Paper 05/234 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Glytsos,Nicholas P. 1993, “Measuring the Income Effects of Migrant Remittances: A Methodological Approach Applied to Greece,” Economic Development and Cultural Change, Vol. 42 (October), pp. 131–68.
Holzner,Mario 2006, “Real Exchange Rate Distortion in Southeast Europe,” Global Development Network Southeast Europe (Vienna: Vienna Institute for International Economics). Available via the Internet: http://www.wiiw. ac.at/balkan/files/HOLZNER.pdf
Hyder,Zulfiqar Mahboob,Adil 2005, “Equilibrium Real Effective Exchange Rate and Exchange Rate Misalignment in Pakistan” (Islamabad:State Bank of Pakistan). Available via the Internet: http://www.sbp.org.pk/ research/conf/Session_IV_Zulfiqar_Adil.pdf
Hyun,Oh-Seok 1989, “The Impact of Overseas Migration on National Development: The Case of the Republic of Korea,” in To the Gulf and Back: Studies on the Impact of Asian Labour Migration, ed. by Amjad Rashid (New Delhi: International Labor Organization).
International Monetary Fund, 2005, “Two Current Issues Facing Developing Countries,” in World Economic Outlook, April 2005: Globalization and External Imbalances, World Economic and Financial Surveys (Washington).
Itzigsohn,Jose 1995, “Migrant Remittances, Labor Markets, and Household Strategies: A Comparative Analysis of Low-Income Household Strategies in the Caribbean Basin,” Social Forces, Vol. 74 (December), pp. 633–55.
Izquierdo,Alejandro Montiel,Peter J. 2006, “Remittances and Equilibrium Real Exchange Rates in Six Central American Countries” (unpublished; Williamstown, Massachusetts: Williams College).
Kannan,K.P. Hari,K.S. 2002, “Kerala’s Gulf Connection: Remittances and Their Macroeconomic Impact,” in Kerala’s Gulf Connection: CDS Studies on International Labour Migration from Kerala State in India, Zachariah,ed. by K.C. Kannan,K.P. Irudaya Rajan S. (Thiruvananthapuram, India: St. Joseph’s Press).
Kaufmann,Daniel Kraay,Aart Mastruzzi,Massimo 2003, “Governance Matters III: Governance Indicators for 1996–2002,” Policy Research Working Paper No. 3106 (Washington: World Bank).
Kose,M. Ayhan Prasad,Eswar S. Terrones,Marco E. 2003, “Volatility and Comovement in a Globalized World Economy: An Empirical Exploration,” IMF Working Paper 03/246 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Kozel,Valerie Alderman,Harold 1990, “Factors Determining Work Participation and Labour Supply Decisions in Pakistan’s Urban Areas,” Pakistan Development Review, Vol. 29, pp. 1–18.
Lueth,Erik Ruiz-Arranz,Marta 2006, “A Gravity Model of Workers’ Remittances,” IMF Working Paper 06/290 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Milesi-Ferretti,Gian Maria Lane,Phillip R. 2006, “The External Wealth of Nations Mark II: Revised and Extended Estimates of Foreign Assets and Liabilities, 1970–2004,” IMF Working Paper 06/69 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Montiel,Peter J. 2006, “Workers’ Remittances and the LongRun Equilibrium Real Exchange Rate: Analytical Issues” (unpublished; Williamstown, Massachusetts: Williams College).
Nishat,Mohammed Bilgrami,Nighat 1991, “The Impact of Migrant Workers’ Remittances on Pakistan Economy,” Pakistan Economic and Social Review, Vol. 29, pp. 21–41.
Rajan,Raghuram Subramanian,Arvind 2005, “What Undermines Aid’s Impact on Growth?” IMF Working Paper 05/126 (Washington: International Monetary Fund) and NBER Working Paper No. 11657 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).
Rodrigo,Chandra Jayatissa,R.A. 1989, “Maximising Benefits from Labour Migration: Sri Lanka,” in To the Gulf and Back: Studies on the Impact of Asian Labour Migration, ed. by Amjad Rashid (New Delhi: International Labor Organization).
Saadi-Sedik,Tahsin Petri,Martin 2006, “To Smooth or Not to Smooth: The Impact of Grants and Remittances on the Equilibrium Real Exchange Rate in Jordan,” IMF Working Paper 06/257 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
Stahl,Charles W. Habib,Ahsanul 1989, “The Impact of Overseas Workers’ Remittances on Indigenous Industries: Evidence from Bangladesh,” Developing Economies, Vol. 27 (September), pp. 269–85.
Taylor,J. Edward Arango,Joaquin Hugo,Graeme Kouaouci,Ali Massey,Douglas S. Pellegrino,Adela 1996a, “International Migration and Community Development,” Population Index, Vol. 62, No. 3 (Autumn), pp. 397 –418.
Taylor,J. Edward Arango,Joaquin Hugo,Graeme Kouaouci,Ali Massey,Douglas S. Pellegrino,Adela 1996b, “International Migration and National Development,” Population Index, Vol. 62,No. 2 (Summer), pp. 181–212.
Tingsabadh,Charit 1989, “Maximising Development Benefits from Labour Migration: Thailand,” inTo the Gulf and Back: Studies on the Impact of Asian Labour Migration, ed. by Amjad Rashid (New Delhi: International Labor Organization).
World Bank, 2006, The Development Impact of Workers’ Remittances in Latin America, Vol. 2: Detailed Findings, Report No. 37026 (Washington).
Earlier studies investigating the macroeconomic impact of remittances used standard growth-accounting exercises or estimated Keynesian multipliers. See Amjad (1986), Burney (1989), Tingsabadh (1989), and more recently, Kannan and Hari (2002) for examples of the growth-accounting approach. Stahl and Habib (1989), Rodrigo and Jayatissa (1989), Adelman and Taylor (1990), Nishat and Bilgrami (1991), and Glytsos (1993) all estimate short-run Keynesian multipliers, whereas Durand, Parrado, and Massey (1996) further explore the implications of Adelman and Taylor’s analysis. At least one long-run multiplier estimate also exists in the literature. Hyun (1989) uses a computable general equilibrium model to estimate a long-run multiplier for the Korean economy and finds that a 10 percent increase in remittances increases GDP by 0.22 percent.
Chapter 4 reviews the empirical evidence on the extent to which remittance recipients invest the funds they receive.
For example, Kozel and Alderman (1990) studied labor force participation and labor supply in Pakistan using data from the 1986 survey by the Pakistan Institute of Development Economics and found a significant negative impact of remittances on the labor force participation of males. Similarly, Itzigsohn (1995) also found, in a sample of Caribbean Basin cities, that remittances significantly reduce the labor force participation of household heads as well as other members of remittance-receiving families.
The first-stage estimation showed that this ratio responded significantly and negatively to the income gap but did not respond significantly to the real interest rate gap. The negative relationship between workers’ remittances and relative GDP is consistent with the Chapter 3 finding of a negative cross-country correlation between remittances and level of income, whereas the result in a time-series sense is consistent with countercyclicality; as the gap between the recipient country and the United States closes—the upswing of the domestic business cycle—remittances decrease.
Faini (2002) also performed a cross-sectional regression of GDP growth on remittances, finding a positive relationship.
The study used three measures to proxy for the level of financial deepening, all expressed as a ratio to GDP: M2, aggregate banking sector deposits, and aggregate bank credit to the private sector.
Although other indicators, such as the ratio of private sector credit to GDP, might be better approximations for the degree of financial deepening, the M2-to-GDP ratio is used here because of its greater coverage across countries and time periods. It must also be noted that the term financial deepening is used rather than financial development, since the former has a connotation relating more to size than to overall performance. As argued in Chapter 5, financial development is related to a noticeable improvement in intermediation activities, which ultimately should be reflected in a reduction in the external finance premium. Although financial development and growth in the size of the banking sector (financial deepening) are often simultaneous processes, one does not imply the other.
Lueth and Ruiz-Arranz (2006) showed that, just as is the case for trade, a gravity equation explains a large portion of the variation in bilateral remittance flows. Thus, trade and remittance flows tend to be highly correlated.
Refer to the previous section for definitions of remittances, instruments, and other control variables used.
The standard deviation of output growth for each country is calculated only over the years for which data are present for all of the explanatory variables in the regression.
The model treats the supply of labor as exogenous, thus ruling out direct effects of remittance flows on the nontraded goods market arising from labor supply effects.
To the extent that remittances are transmitted through formal channels and hence are measurable, they can be taxed using financial transactions taxes, but governments generally avoid this type of taxation for several reasons. Such a tax may cause the transfers to migrate to informal channels, lowering welfare by increasing the costs of remitting; counter the ongoing international efforts against money laundering; and potentially reduce the overall quantity of remittances.
Some financial systems permit households to hold foreign-currency-denominated accounts in the financial system.
See Chapter 6 for additional discussion on tax structures in emerging markets and optimal tax structures in remittance-dependent economies.
For an examination of remittances and the fiscal balance across emerging economies, see Table 3.5.
Although a generalized appreciation of the domestic currency resulting from remittance inflows may improve the sustainability of the public debt, it may also worsen the trade balance and weaken external sustainability. See Box 7.2 and “Workers’ Remittances and the Equilibrium Real Exchange Rate” for additional discussion.