V. The Distributional Impact of Agricultural Sector Reforms in Africa: A Review of Past Experience
Author:
Mr. Robert Gillingham
Search for other papers by Mr. Robert Gillingham in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close

Abstract

This chapter reviews the distributional impact of agricultural sector reforms in Africa. African governments have intervened in the agricultural sector for decades, but generous pricing policies and operational inefficiencies have often necessitated large budgetary transfers to parastatals. Over the past 20 years many African countries attempted to liberalize their agricultural sector, with mixed success. This chapter describes the forms of government intervention in agricultural markets, the liberalizing reforms undertaken in the past 20 years, the channels by which these reforms affected stakeholders, and the outcomes of the reforms on poor households.100

A. Introduction

This chapter reviews the distributional impact of agricultural sector reforms in Africa. African governments have intervened in the agricultural sector for decades, but generous pricing policies and operational inefficiencies have often necessitated large budgetary transfers to parastatals. Over the past 20 years many African countries attempted to liberalize their agricultural sector, with mixed success. This chapter describes the forms of government intervention in agricultural markets, the liberalizing reforms undertaken in the past 20 years, the channels by which these reforms affected stakeholders, and the outcomes of the reforms on poor households.100

Four main lessons emerge from past experience. First, past reforms have not lived up to expectations, reflecting erratic policy implementation, low levels of public goods, and weak market institutions. In particular, price liberalization alone has proven insufficient to spur agricultural growth in the presence of structural weaknesses in rural markets. Second, postreform price changes have not significantly harmed the poor in the aggregate. The feared increase in the consumer price of food, which would have reduced the purchasing power of the majority of the rural poor who are net food consumers, never materialized. Instead, liberalizing procurement markets increased competition among traders and processors, which reduced marketing margins and benefited both producers and consumers. Third, reforms that removed input subsidies and devalued the currency did not markedly increase agriculture yields, as private credit and input markets functioned poorly after reforms. In many cases, however, the poor were not major beneficiaries of input subsidies and were therefore less affected by their withdrawal. Finally, farmers in more remote locations were disproportionately harmed by the removal of both direct input subsidies and cross-subsidies from uniform national pricing.

Therefore, reforms of input market reforms should proceed carefully, and compensation should be considered for farmers in more remote areas. This compensation should, if possible, build on existing social safety net programs. It could consist of targeted transfers to poor remote households, or conditional targeted transfers that promote human capital investment (including agricultural extension services), or investments in physical infrastructure, such as irrigation, roads, or utilities.

For most households, the primary effects of agricultural sector reforms are changes in producer or consumer prices. In principle, the best way to measure the distributional impact of price changes is to use a household survey to examine the relationship between households’ economic welfare and their net consumption of the goods in question. This chapter does not discuss this kind of price-incidence analysis, which is described in Chapter III above. Instead, it reviews the contextual background and lessons from past reforms. Section B describes the historical background of marketing boards and the need for reform. Section C lays out the channels by which producers, consumers, and private traders were affected by the reforms. Section D presents four case studies of reforms, and Section E concludes by reviewing the effects of the reforms.

B. Rationale for Intervention and Reform

Public intervention in agricultural markets is common throughout the world because of the importance and volatility of these markets. In most developing countries, agricultural markets are the main source of livelihood for the majority of households in rural areas, where poverty is concentrated, and they provide staple foods for urban consumers. Subsidizing rural farmers and domestic consumers, sometimes at the same time, was perceived politically both as an obligation of postcolonial governments and as an effective strategy to reduce poverty. In most developing countries, these attitudes matched many leaders’ general distrust of the free market and specific concerns about the market power of traders and farmers’ access to credit for inputs. Furthermore, in many African countries, the economic importance of agriculture made it a natural source of tax revenue, which was collected by setting producer prices substantially below world prices and channeling output through publicly run marketing boards.

Price volatility in international and domestic agricultural markets encouraged state intervention. For export crops, price volatility stems from weather or other supply shocks that affect competing exporters. For domestically consumed food crops, farm households often sell only the portion of their harvest that remains after self-consumption, so that weather shocks can lead to large relative changes in supply and prices. Underdeveloped credit and insurance markets also exacerbate price volatility. In theory, policies that reduce price volatility in food and export crops can increase investment and benefit producers, to the extent that farmers currently sacrifice higher returns to mitigate risk.

In Africa, a desire to smooth volatility, support the poor, and capture rents led governments to establish state marketing boards. Appendix Table A5.1 lists 14 sectors in 12 African countries where state marketing boards maintained fixed prices, price ceilings, floors, or bands. Fixed prices were constant throughout the year (pan-seasonal) and throughout the country (pan-territorial). To enforce state-set prices, marketing boards were granted monopsony and sometimes monopoly power. As an additional incentive to accept below-market producer prices, marketing boards also offered input subsidies. Seeds, pesticides, and especially fertilizer were tightly controlled and heavily subsidized. Input subsidies also took the form of exemptions from indirect taxes, concessionary credit, insurance, subsidized extension services, and transport services. In cases where the state did not set prices by law, marketing boards maintained a price band by setting aside a fund and conducting open-market

operations. Quantity rationing was less common, although production quotas were imposed in formerly socialist countries such as Ethiopia, Madagascar, and Guinea.

In most countries, state marketing boards proved financially unsustainable. The oil price shocks in the 1970s dramatically increased the price of fertilizer in dollar terms and governments increased subsidies rather than prices. Because of pan-territorial and pan-seasonal pricing, rising oil prices also increased transport and storage costs, which were absorbed by marketing boards. In some countries, pan-seasonal and pan-territorial pricing led to high marketing costs in remote areas because of the circuitous transport of food to urban areas for storage and back to rural areas for consumption (Seshamani, 1998). Predictably, subsidizing both producers and consumers proved expensive, particularly in years when harvests were good. Finally, in general the parastatals themselves were corrupt and/or poorly managed. Many governments responded to increasingly large revenue shortfalls by cutting producer prices further, which led to the emergence of parallel markets and further depressed production. Figure 5.1 shows examples of the substantial losses incurred by state marketing boards in four countries, which ranged from 1 to 6 percent of GDP.

Figure 5.1.
Figure 5.1.

Agricultural Sector Losses in Selected Countries

Parastatals’ fiscal difficulties, falling export commodity prices, and donor pressure led most countries in sub-Saharan Africa to implement structural adjustment programs during the 1980s. Agricultural reforms were a major part of these programs, which followed three major paradigms. First, input and output prices were liberalized, by removing input subsidies, setting domestic prices in line with world prices, eliminating pan-territorial and pan-seasonal pricing, and in some cases devaluing the currency. Second, regulatory controls were lifted in the transport, procurement, marketing, and, occasionally, the production sectors. Third, public enterprises were restructured to focus on support activities such as maintaining buffer stocks and providing information instead of pricing and marketing activities. Because of the importance of the agricultural sector in these countries, these reforms had far-reaching effects.

C. Stakeholders and Channels of Impact

Consumers, producers, and traders are generally the groups most widely affected by reforms, though processors and parastatal employees are also affected. Of course, reforms have heterogeneous effects within groups. These effects are primarily felt through changes in consumer and producer prices, input prices and subsidies, and the structure of the market.

For producers, the effect of changes in producer prices on welfare depends on the household’s net production of the good. Many reforms eliminate producer price or input subsidies. These harm net producers, who tend to be wealthier farm households. However, the patterns of net production vary by crop and by country. Therefore, if possible, the incidence of producer price changes should be assessed using a household survey with production and consumption data. However, such analyses should be treated with proper caution, because they typically ignore crop substitution effects on both the intensive and extensive margins. In particular, wealthier and better-educated households are likely to adapt to price changes more effectively (Schultz, 1975), in which case first-order incidence likely overstates the loss of wealthier households relative to poorer households.

The removal of input subsidies will harm farmers to the extent that they purchase subsidized inputs. Prereform input subsidies were often poorly targeted, as large farmers generally used more inputs and in some cases captured the subsidies. However, the effect of removing input subsidies for the poor can still be substantial, because the increased cost may significantly reduce their income and the fall in input use may have a larger effect on the yield of poor farms. Again, information on poor households’ use of inputs and input subsidies may be available in a household survey or agricultural census. Finally, reforms that improve competition in procurement and transport markets reduce marketing margins, which can be passed through at least partially to producers in the form of higher producer prices.

For consumers, the effect of a price change in a food crop, because of the withdrawal of subsidies, will depend on household net consumption of the good. Urban consumers have higher net consumption on average. Price increases in food crops tend to hit poor households harder because food budget shares fall as income rises. In most countries, large-scale household data can be used to examine the correlation between household budget shares and household economic well-being. Because demand is generally more elastic for poor households, such first-order incidence analysis may overestimate the impact of a price increase on the poor relative to the nonpoor, especially for nonstaple goods.101 This is particularly true when close substitutes are available. Also, consumer prices typically fall after restrictions in transport markets are removed, which reduces marketing margins and benefits consumers across the board.

Liberalizing transport and procurement markets has in most cases led to the entry of private traders, who benefit from the opportunity to compete away the monopsony rents earned by marketing boards. The removal of interregional trade restrictions and taxes benefits these new traders. Of course, employees of parastatals typically suffer from the loss of rents. Market liberalization and/or privatization of parastatals lead to layoffs following reforms; the distributional effects of these layoffs depend on the negotiated severance agreements as well as the state of the labor market in the country.

Many past reforms harmed poor urban consumers and remote rural farmers. Reforms create winners and losers through their effects on prices and rents. Policies that remove output subsidies and lower producer prices harm net producers, who tend to be wealthier. Policies that lead to consumer price increases in food items harm consumers in proportion to the percentage of their budget devoted to that item. Typically, poor urban consumers bear the brunt of food price increases, especially for staples. Liberalizing procurement and transport markets benefits consumers and producers by reducing marketing margins. However, rural producers in remote areas, who tend to be poor, are disproportionately harmed by the removal of both direct input subsidies and the implicit subsidies deriving from pan-territorial pricing. Farmers in remote areas may also be constrained by poorly functioning collection markets because of the difficulties in obtaining information and credit.

D. Case Studies

Malawi’s Maize Market

The Agricultural Development and Marketing Corporation (ADMARC) is a monopsonistic buyer for smallholders’ maize at fixed prices. ADMARC was established in 1971 to market agricultural produce and inputs, assist smallholder agriculture, act as a buyer and seller of last resort, and store food and inputs at about 350 market centers located throughout the country. ADMARC’s financial position deteriorated for several reasons. Revenues from tobacco exports, which originally subsidized these activities, dried up when tobacco prices fell in the late 1970s. As a result, Malawi signed a structural adjustment agreement in 1981, but little progress was made, as maize subsidies continued to amount to between 0.4 and 1 percent of GDP. (Sahn, Dorosh, and Younger, 1997). Marketing and procurement markets were liberalized in 1987, reforms in 1993 opened up the fertilizer market, and subsequent reforms in 1995 liberalized prices. However, ADMARC still maintains a price band and acts as a residual buyer.

The liberalizing reforms were generally unsuccessful, partly because of uneven implementation and continued ADMARC involvement in the sector. Although the reforms coincided with a short period of growth in both GDP and the agricultural sector, they failed to reduce the fiscal deficit or promote longer-run growth (Appendix Figure A5.1), and the poverty rate increased from 54 to 65 percent between 1991 and 1998. The 1995 price liberalization led to price increases, which harmed net consumers, including many of the rural poor (Chilowa, 1998). The liberalization did not increase the number of traders, and marketing margins remained high, although higher prices increased production. ADMARC’s financial performance continues to be hampered by ill-fated business ventures and high overhead costs. Until 2002, ADMARC ran a cotton ginning company and a bus company, both of which lost money. As a result, repeated ADMARC bailouts of 1.6 percent of GDP in 1997/1998, 1.9 percent in 2000/2001, and 3.6 percent in 2002 threatened macroeconomic stability. Finally, ADMARC’s unauthorized sale of its grain reserve in 2000, allegedly to politically well-connected buyers, depressed producer prices and contributed to a food security crisis in 2001.

Mali’s Cereals Sector

Mali traditionally subsidized urban cereal consumers by imposing low pan-seasonal and pan-territorial producer prices on farmers. For example, in 1979, Mali’s millet and sorghum producer price was half of Burkina Faso’s price. Producers were legally required to sell to OPAM (Office des Produits Agricoles du Mali) or Office du Niger, which were the official grain and rice marketing agencies. However, the majority of marketed cereals were sold through private channels or smuggled to neighboring countries. Farmers also responded to depressed producer prices by switching to other crops. In the late 1970s, Mali moved from being a net exporter to being a net importer of grains. Because the subsidized consumer price was below the imported price, the budget deficit increased rapidly, as OPAM’s deficit reached 7.5 percent of GDP in 1979.

The government agreed to liberalize the grain trade and improve the marketing boards’ operating efficiency in 1981. The multi-donor-financed Cereals Market Restructuring Programme first focused on eliminating parastatal monopolies by negotiating changes in their role, providing management assistance, and financing severance pay for laid-off employees. Producer, consumer, and export prices of cereals were fully liberalized in 1987. By the mid-1990s, the program had shifted to helping the marketing board establish a marketing information system and provide subsidized credit to private traders.

The liberalization program was successful. Both GDP and the agricultural sector grew following reforms, despite continued fluctuations, and the fiscal deficit was virtually eliminated by 1996 (see Appendix Figure A5.1). In the grain sector, the large-scale entry of traders following liberalization reduced margins and led to cost savings on the order of 3 percent of GDP (Akiyama and others, 2001). In the rice sector, reform proceeded more slowly. Parastatal millers remained inefficient until privatization in 1994, and the Office du Niger required a budgetary transfer of 0.4 percent of GDP in 1990. Nonetheless, rice and maize production increased dramatically following the reforms (Dembele and Staatz, 1999). Most farmers added $100 per year to their incomes. In a 1999 survey of farmers, 74 percent of the respondents indicated that their incomes had improved since cereal markets were liberalized. Medium-sized and large farmers experienced 143 percent and 62 percent increases, respectively, in the real return to family labor, whereas small farms increased by only 35 percent (Dembele, Staatz, and Weber, 2003).

Senegal’s Groundnut Sector

Sonacos, a Senegalese parastatal, traditionally enjoyed a near monopoly on groundnut oil processing and export. Groundnut oil is an important source of revenue for much of the rural population, and exports amounted to 1.4 percent of GDP and 4.6 percent of total exports in 2003. Sonacos processes around 20 percent of the total amount of groundnuts grown in Senegal and produces roughly 90 percent of total groundnut oil exports. Besides processing groundnuts, Sonacos ran a subsidiary called Sonagraines, which licensed agents to provide subsidized inputs and collect groundnuts from farmers. A quasi-public regulatory association sets a pan-territorial and pan-seasonal producer price each year. In 2001, the government intervened to further increase the producer price, which along with the continued subsidization of seeds and fertilizer caused Sonacos to run a large deficit. The resulting bailout amounted to 1.9 percent of GDP. In the aftermath of this transfer, with donor encouragement, the government dissolved Sonagraines and allowed private traders to engage in procurement.

The elimination of Sonagraines has been criticized for its haste. Reportedly, after Sonagraines withdrew, private traders obtained below-market prices by exploiting farmers’ ignorance or need for cash, although there is no systematic evidence on the price received by groundnut farmers. The reported disruption of seed markets caused a steep decline in groundnut production in the 2002-03 campaign. Agricultural output fell as well, before recovering the following year (see Appendix Figure A5.1). After that, Sonacos barely turned a profit. Under continued donor pressure, the government sold Sonacos to a private bidder in 2005. The newly privatized Sonacos has agreed to buy groundnuts for a price of CFAF105 per kilogram, but the regulatory association has set the producer price of CFAF150 per kilogram; the difference will be made up by government subsidies amounting to 0.3 percent of GDP. In addition, Sonacos has successfully lobbied to maintain tariffs on imported refined vegetable oil that protect its vegetable oil refining business.

Zambia’s Maize Sector

Subsidies to the state-controlled maize sector became unsustainable in the late 1980s. Prior to 1990, the government set maize prices, and the procurement, distribution, and processing of maize was undertaken solely by state-owned enterprises and cooperatives. Maize is the staple food in Zambia, and these marketing agencies were subsidized in order to maintain low margins. The cost of these subsidies rose from 1.6 percent of GDP in 1984 to 3.5 percent in 1990, as cotton prices fell in the 1980s. In 1990, with the fiscal deficit at 8 percent of GDP, maize procurement was partially liberalized, which allowed private traders to enter while retaining the state monopoly on international and long-distance trade.

After multiparty elections in 1991, the new government undertook major macroeconomic reforms, including the liberalization of exchange rates and commercial interest rates, tighter fiscal and monetary policy, and the liberalization of agricultural markets. In 1993, one year after a major drought, maize prices were liberalized and maize marketing and processing was decentralized.

Zambia’s experience following the reforms was mixed. A poorly planned decentralization of state-led marketing created difficulties in the provision of credit to farmers. Parallel efforts at macroeconomic stabilization drew investments into treasury bonds, at high real interest rates designed to curb inflation. The resulting private sector credit crunch, along with the inexperience of the new credit institutions, proved disastrous. At the end of the season in October 1993, farmers were owed a total of 1.5 percent of GDP for their crops, and most were not paid until February 1994. The unsuccessful liberalization of credit and fertilizer supply increased rural poverty, primarily impacting net maize producers, who tend to be better off (McCulloch, Baulch, and Cherel-Robson, 2001). Nonetheless, this experience illustrates the difficulties of abrupt liberalization of micro-level credit institutions in countries undertaking aggressive macroeconomic stabilization policies.

The privatization of the industrial milling agency and liberalization of milling markets was far more successful. Prior to the reform, poor households spent 15 percent of their budget on industrial maize and it was feared they would be harmed by the withdrawal of subsidies. However, the liberalization of the processing market allowed small-scale hammer mills, which produce maize that is up to 80 percent cheaper, to increase their market share. As a result, between 1991 and 1998, the poor reduced their consumption of industrial maize from 12 percent to 4 percent, and increased consumption of hammer-milled maize from negligible levels to 18 percent of their budget (Balat and Porto, 2005). This underscores the positive effect of reforms of uncompetitive processing and milling markets in mitigating the harmful effects of withdrawing subsidies on the poor.

Overall, the liberalization policies were not implemented consistently and in some cases reversed. Until 1995, publicly set floor prices were announced, impeding the entry of private traders. An export ban was introduced for one year in 1995, but subsequent tight licensing restrictions depressed producer prices. Pan-territorial prices were reintroduced in 1997 and continued to provide subsidized fertilizer inputs. Since then, GDP growth stabilized at approximately 4 percent and the agricultural sector became less volatile, but the fiscal deficit has gradually worsened, to 7 percent of GDP in 2001 (Appendix Figure A5.1).

An important obstacle to effective reform has been the continued intervention of the Food Reserve Agency (FRA). The FRA, ostensibly created to stabilize prices, continued to sell maize to selected large urban millers at up to 25 percent below the market price, depressing competition in processing. The FRA also sold imported maize at below-market prices in 1997 and 1998, which in turn crowded out private importers. In 2001, the FRA instituted a floor price for maize. The FRA’s plans and ability to import maize are not announced beforehand, and resulting uncertainty over the market price complicates the decisions of private importers and farmers. Finally, the FRA imports maize only for large-scale millers, which lowers the supply of hammer-milled maize. Households purchase cheaper hammer-milled maize in the four months following the harvest, until stocks run out at local markets and they are forced to purchase more expensive industrial milled maize.

E. The Impact of the Reforms

Reforms failed to generate a large supply response. Donors and policymakers expected that liberalizing the sector would raise producer prices and generate a supply response that would spur growth in the sector. Over time, it became clearer that insufficient implementation, poorly functioning institutions, and insufficient public goods hampered the expansion of the sector.

In many countries, reforms were not fully implemented. Appendix Table A5.2 describes these reforms in more detail for the sample of countries and sectors listed in Appendix Table A5.1, and illustrates the incomplete progress of reforms as of 2002. Of the 14 sectors listed, private trading was liberalized in 11, but parastatal companies or marketing boards remained active in 11 cases. Price intervention of some sort still occurs in 9 of the 14 countries, though in some countries, such as Kenya and Uganda, the price regulations are relatively mild. Concerns about food security led governments in southern and eastern Africa to continue intervention in the maize market, as in Zambia. Marketing boards still conduct a large share of crop marketing in some countries, such as Malawi. State-owned enterprises or multinational firms continue to dominate input markets in many countries. Reforms also have been reversed, particularly in Eastern and Southern Africa. For example, Malawi has revoked and reinstated fertilizer subsidies twice in the past 20 years, and Zambia reinstated pan-territorial maize pricing. Zimbabwe, after liberalizing its internal trading and milling markets for maize in 1993, subsequently increased the role of its grain marketing board and reintroduced price controls in 1998. Kenya reintroduced maize price supports in 1998 after eliminating them in 1994.

Lasting and effective implementation of reforms was hampered by several factors. Liberalizing reforms impinged on rents earned from state intervention. Donor-led reform efforts failed to generate ownership and enthusiasm from either the bureaucracy charged with implementing reforms or stakeholders in civil society. The rationale for reforms was rarely explained publicly. Loan disbursements were conditional on a wide package of economy-wide reforms, and donors were reluctant to delay disbursements owing to noncompliance in the agricultural sector. Donor coordination in policies was lacking in some instances. Finally, African government officials are often undertrained and underpaid, and state capacity for monitoring and implementation is weak.

Despite inconsistent implementation in some countries, the liberalizing reforms have overall had a positive effect on export crops and a mildly positive effect on the sector as a whole. The liberalization of internal procurement and transport markets induced large-scale entry of private traders, which reduced marketing margins and more closely integrated agricultural markets, increasing producer prices for farmers and decreasing consumer prices. In addition, the reforms engendered a limited supply response, which was stronger for export crops than for food crops. In some countries, devaluations raised the producer price of export crops relative to food crops. Also, fertilizer is used more intensively for export crops, partly because their markets tend to be more vertically integrated and public stabilization policies reduce price volatility.

Several factors moderated the effect of the reforms on poor households, although the effect on poor households was mixed. In grain markets, most poor rural households are net consumers, but grain prices did not generally increase after reforms because of the decline in marketing margins. Food and fertilizer subsidies often did not reach the poor or were distributed inefficiently, which attenuated the negative effects of the withdrawal of these subsidies. However, private rural credit markets did not function well, and reforms reduced overall fertilizer use.

The reforms were particularly beneficial for export crop farmers and farmers in more accessible areas with marketable surpluses. Declining marketing margins and exchange rate depreciation increased the income of small export growers by roughly 20 percent. Meanwhile, net producers in remote areas suffered from the elimination of pan-territorial and pan-seasonal pricing and from the withdrawal of input subsidies. This highlights the need for consideration for farmers in remote areas who may be hurt by reforms.

Overall, the outcomes of the reforms were mixed. Liberalizing reforms in the agricultural sector were precipitated by inefficient and unsustainable state involvement in price-setting, transport, and marketing. Reforms generally scaled back the role of state marketing boards, liberalized internal trade, and removed subsidies or restrictions on inputs, outputs, and price. Liberalizing transport and procurement markets reduced marketing margins. However, the hoped-for supply response did not materialize, largely because of weak implementation, institutions, and public goods provision. State involvement in input markets was not replaced by well-functioning private markets. Finally, reforms that ended input subsidies and pan-territorial pricing disproportionately harmed farmers in more remote areas.

Appendix Figure A5.1.
Appendix Figure A5.1.
Appendix Figure A5.1.

Pre- and Postreform Trends in GDP Growth, Fiscal Deficits, and Agricultural Production

Appendix Table A5.1.

Marketing Boards and Interventions

article image
Appendix Table A5.2.

Agricultural Market Reforms

article image
  • Collapse
  • Expand
Review of Methodology and Selected Evidence
  • Figure 5.1.

    Agricultural Sector Losses in Selected Countries

  • Appendix Figure A5.1.

    Pre- and Postreform Trends in GDP Growth, Fiscal Deficits, and Agricultural Production

  • Abed, G., and others, 1998, Fiscal Reforms in Low-Income Countries: Experience Under IMF-Supported Programs, IMF Occasional Paper No. 160 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Adelman, I., and S. Robinson, 1978, Income Distribution Policy in Developing Countries: A Case Study of Korea (Palo Alto, California: Stanford University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Adelman, I., and S. Robinson, 1989, “Income Distribution and Development,in Handbook of Development Economics, Vol. 2, ed. by H. Chenery and T. Srinivasan (Amsterdam: North-Holland).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Adelman, I.,E. Taylor, and S. Vogel, 1988, “Life in a Mexican Village: A SAM Perspective,Journal of Development Studies, Vol. 25, pp. 524.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Agénor, P.-R., 2004, “Macroeconomic Adjustment and the Poor: Analytical Issues and Cross-Country Evidence,Journal of Economic Surveys, Vol. 18 (July), pp. 351408.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Agénor, P.-R., A. Izquierdo, and H. Fofack, 2003, “ The Integrated Macroeconomic Model for Poverty Analysis: A Quantitative Macroeconomic Framework for the Analysis of Poverty Reduction Strategies,Policy Research Working Paper No. 3092 (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Agénor, P.-R., and P. Montiel, 1999, Development Macroeconomics (Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press, 2nd ed.).

  • Ahmad, E., and s. Ludlow. 1989. “The Distributional Consequences of Tax Reform: On a VAT for Pakistan,Policy Research Working Paper No. 238 (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ahmad, E., and N. Stern, 1984, “Theory of Reform and Indian Indirect Taxes,Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 25 (December), pp. 25995.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ahmad, E., and N stern. 1987, “Alternative Sources of Government Revenue: Illustrations from India,in The Theory of Taxation for Developing Countries, ed. by D. Newbery and N. Stern (Oxford, United Kingdom: Oxford University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ahmad, E., and N. Stern. 1990, “Tax Reform and Shadow Prices for Pakistan.Oxford Economic Papers, Vol. 42, pp. 13559.

  • Ahmad, E., and N. Stern 1991, The Theory and Practice of Tax Reform in Developing Countries (Cambridge, United Kingdom: Cambridge University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Akiyama, T., J. Baffes, D. Larson, and P. Varangis, eds., 2001, Commodity Market Reforms: Lessons of Two Decades (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Allen, M., C. Rosenberg, C. Keller, B. Setser, and N. Roubini, 2002, “A Balance Sheet Approach to Financial Crisis,IMF Working Paper 02/210 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Anderson, J., 1999, “Trade Reform with a Government Budget Constraint,in International Trade Policy and the Pacific Rim: Proceedings of the IEA Conference Held in Sydney, Australia, ed. by J. Piggott and A. Woodland (London: Macmillan).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Anderson, K., 2004, “Agricultural Trade Reform and Poverty Reduction in Developing Countries,Policy Research Working Paper No. 3396 (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Atkinson, A.B., and F. Bourguignon, 1991, “Tax-Benefit Models for Developing Countries: Lessons from Developed Countries,in Tax Policy in Developing Countries, ed. by J. Khalilzadeh-Shirazi and A. Shah (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Attanasio, O., P. Goldberg, and N. Pavcnik, 2004, “Trade Reforms and Wage Inequality in Colombia,Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 74 (August), pp. 33166.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Azam, J.P., 2004, “Poverty and Growth in the WAEMU after the 1994 Devaluation,Journal of African Economies, Vol. 13 (December), p. 53662.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Baffes, J., D. Larson, P. Varangis, and T. Akiyama, 2003, “Commodity Market Reform in Africa: Some Recent Experience,Policy Research Working Paper No. 2995 (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Baig, T., A. Mati, D. Coady, and J. Ntamatungiro, 2007, “Domestic Petroleum Product Prices and Subsidies: Recent Developments and Reform Strategies,IMF Working Paper 07/71 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Balat, J., and G. Porto, 2005, “Globalization and Complementary Policies: Poverty Impacts in Rural Zambia,NBER Working Paper No. 11175 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Banks, J., R. Blundell, and A. Lewbel, 1996, “Tax Reform and Welfare Measurement: Do We Need Demand System Estimation?Economic Journal, Vol. 106 (September), pp. 1227241.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Barbone, L., A. Das-Gupta, L. De Wulf, and A. Hansson, 1999, “Reforming Tax Systems: The World Bank Record in the 1990s,Policy Research Working Paper No. 2237 (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Barrett, C, 1997, “Food Marketing Liberalization and Trader Entry: Evidence from Madagascar,World Development, Vol. 25 (May), pp. 76377.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Barrett, C, and P.A. Dorosh, 1996, “Farmers’ Welfare and Changing Food Prices: Nonparametric Evidence from Rice in Madagascar,American Journal of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 78 (August), pp. 65669.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Basu, P., and McLeod, D., 1991, “Terms of Trade Fluctuations and Economic Growth in Developing Economies,Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 37 (November), pp. 89110.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bautista, R, S. Robinson, and M. El-Said, 2001, “Alternative Industrial Development Paths for Indonesia: SAM and CGE Analyses,in Restructuring Asian Economies for the New Millennium, Research in Asian Economic Studies, Vol. 9-B, ed. by J. Behrmann and others (Amsterdam: Elsevier Science).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Berg, A., and A. Krueger, 2003, “Trade, Growth and Poverty: A Selective Survey,IMF Working Paper 03/30 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Besley, T., and I. Preston, 1988, “Invariance and the Axiomatics of Income Tax Progression: A Comment,Bulletin of Economic Research, Vol. 40, No. 2, pp. 15963.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bevan, D., P. Collier, N. Gemmell, and D. Greenaway, eds., 2000, Trade and Fiscal Adjustment in Africa (London: Macmillan).

  • Binswanger, H., and R. Townsend, 2000, “The Growth Performance of Agriculture in Sub-Saharan Africa,American Journal of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 82 (December), pp. 107586.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bird, R., 1992, Tax Policy and Economic Development (Baltimore: John Hopkins University Press).

  • Booth, D., F. Lungngira, P. Masanja, A. Mvungi, R. Mwaipopo, and others, 1993, “Social, Economic and Cultural Change in Contemporary Tanzania: A People Oriented Focus” (Stockholm: Swedish International Development Authority).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bourguignon, F., and L.A. Pereira da Silva, eds., 2003, The Impact of Economic Policies on Poverty and Income Distribution: Evaluation Techniques and Tools (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bruno, M., M. Ravallion, and L. Squire, 1997, “Equity and Growth in Developing Countries: Old and New Perspectives on the Policy Issues,in Income Distribution and High Quality Growth, ed. by V. Tanzi and K.-Y. Chu (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Budd, 1993, “Changing Food Prices and Rural Welfare: A Nonparametric Examination of the Cote d’lvoire,Economic Development and Cultural Change, Vol. 41 (April), pp. 587603.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Burgess, R., and N. Stern, 1993, “Taxation and Development,Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 31 (June), pp. 762830.

  • Burnside, C, M. Eichenbaum, and S. Rebelo, 2003, “Government Finance in the Wake of Currency Crises,NBER Working Paper No. 9786 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Burstein, A., M. Eichenbaum, and S. Rebelo, 2002, “Why Is Inflation So Low After Large Devaluations,NBER Working Paper No. 8748 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Burstein, A., M. Eichenbaum, and S. Rebelo, 2004, “Large Devaluations and the Real Exchange Rate,NBER Working Paper No. 10986 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Case, A., 2000, “Implications of Policy Reform Given Income Distribution and Expenditure Patterns in South Africa” (unpublished).

  • Cashin, P., P. Mauro, C. Pattillo, and R. Sahay, 2001, “Macroeconomic Policies and Poverty Reduction: Stylized Facts and an Overview of Research,IMF Working Paper 01/135 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Chen, D., J. Matovu, and R. Reinikka, 2001, “A Quest for Revenue and Tax Incidence in Uganda,IMF Working Paper 01/24 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Chen, S., and M. Ravallion, 2003, “Household Welfare Impacts of China’s Accession to the World Trade Organization,Policy Research Working Paper No. 3040 (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Chia, N., S. Wahba, and J. Whalley, 2000, “Analyzing the incidence of taxes in the Cote dTvoire,in Trade and Fiscal Adjustment in Africa, ed. by D. Bevan, P. Collier, N. Gemmell, and D. Greenaway (London: Macmillan).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Chilowa, W., 1998, “The Impact of Agricultural Liberalisation on Food Security in Malawi,Food Policy, Vol. 23 (December), pp. 55369.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Christianson, L., L. Demery, and S. Paternostro, 2002, “Growth, Distribution, and Poverty: Messages from the 1990’s” (unpublished; Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Clarete, R., 1991, “A general equilibrium analysis of the tax burden and institutional distortions in the Philippines,in Tax Policy in Developing Countries, ed. by J. Khalilzadeh-Shirazi and A. Shah (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Coady, D., 1997a, “Agricultural Pricing Policies in Developing Countries: An Application to Pakistan,International Tax and Public Finance, Vol. 4 (January), pp. 3957.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Coady, D., 1997b, “Fiscal reform in developing countries,in Fiscal Reforms in the Least Developed Countries, ed. by C. Patel (Cheltenham, United Kingdom: Edward Elgar).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Coady, D., 2006, “Indirect Tax and Public Pricing Reforms,in Analyzing the Distributional Impact of Reforms: A Practitioner’s Guide to Pension, Health, Labor Markets, Public Sector Downsizing, Taxation, Decentralization and Macroeconomic Modeling, Vol. 2, ed. by A. Coudouel and S. Paternostro (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Coady, D., and J. Dré, 2002, “Commodity Taxation and Social Welfare: The Generalized Ramsey Rule,International Tax and Public Finance, Vol. 9 (May), pp. 295316.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Coady, D., M. El Said, R. Gillingham, K. Kpodar, P. Medas, and D. Newhouse, 2006, “The Magnitude and Distribution of Fuel Subsidies: Evidence from Bolivia, Ghana, Jordan, Mali, and Sri Lanka,IMF Working Paper 06/247 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Coady, D., M. Grosh, and J. Hoddinott, 2004, “Targeting Outcomes Redux,World Bank Research Observer, Vol. 19 (Spring), pp. 6185.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Coady, D., and R. Harris, 2004, “Evaluating Transfer Programmes Within a General Equilibrium Framework,Economic Journal, Vol. 114 (October), pp. 77899.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Coady, D., and E. Skoufias, 2004, “On the Targeting and Redistributive Efficiencies of Alternative Transfer Instruments,Review of Income and Wealth, Vol. 50 (March), pp. 1127.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cockburn, J., 2001, “Trade Liberalisation and Poverty in Nepal: A Computable General Equilibrium Micro Simulation Analysis,CREFA Discussion Paper No. 01-18 (Laval, Quebec: Centre de Recherche en Èconomie et Finance Appliquees). Available via the Internet at http://www.cfnpp.cornell.edu/images/9781589066625_wp91.pdf.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cogneau, D., and A.-S. Robilliard, 2000, “Growth, Distribution and Poverty in Madagascar: Learning from Microsimulation Model in a General Equilibrium Framework,TMD Discussion Paper No. 61 (Washington: International Food Policy Research Institute).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Corbacho, A., M. Garcia-Escribano, and G. Inchauste, 2003, “Argentina: Macroeconomic Crisis and Household Vulnerability,IMF Working Paper 03/89 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cornia, G, R. Jolly, and F. Stewart, eds., 1987, Adjustment with a Human Face: Protecting the Vulnerable and Promoting Growth (Oxford: Clarendon Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Coudouel, A., and S. Paternostro, eds., 2006, Analyzing the Distributional Impact of Reforms: A Practitioner’s Guide to Pension, Health, Labor Markets, Public Sector Downsizing, Taxation, Decentralization and Macroeconomic Modeling, Vol. 2 (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Coxhead, I., and P. Warr, 1995, “Does Technical Progress in Agriculture Alleviate Poverty? A Philippine Case Study,Australian Journal of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 39 (April), pp. 2554.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dahl, H., and P. Mitra, 1991, “Applying Tax Policy Models in Country Economic Work: Bangladesh, China, and India,in Tax Policy in Developing Countries, ed. by J. Khalilzadeh-Shirazi and A. Shah (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Davies, J., 2004, “Microsimulation, CGE and Macro Modelling for Transition and Developing Economies,WIDER Discussion Paper No. 2004/08 (Helsinki: World Institute for Development Economic Research, United Nations University). Available via the Internet at http://www.crefa.ecn.ulaval.ca/cahier/0118.pdf..

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • de Janvry, A., E. Sadoulet, and A. Fargeix, 1991, “Politically Feasible and Equitable Adjustment: Some Alternatives for Ecuador,World Development, Vol. 19 (November), pp. 157794.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Deaton, A. 1987. “Econometric Issues for Tax Design in Developing Countries,in The Theory of Taxation for Developing Countries, ed. by D. Newbery and N. Stern(New York: Oxford University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Deaton, A. 1988. “Quality, Quantity and Spatial Variation in Price,American Economic Review, Vol. 78. pp. 41830.

  • Deaton, A. 1989, “Rice Prices and Income Distribution in Thailand: A Non-Parametric Analysis,Economic Journal, Vol. 99, No. 395 (Conference Supplement), pp. 137.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Deaton, A. 1990, “Price Elasticities from Survey Data: Extensions and Indonesian Results,Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 44, pp. 281309.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Deaton, A. 1995, “Data and Econometric Tools for Development Analysis,in Handbook of Development Economics, Volume 3 A, ed. by J. Behrman and T. Srinivasan (Amsterdam: North-Holland).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Deaton, A. 1997, The Analysis of Household Surveys: A Microeconomic Approach to Development Policy (Baltimore, Maryland: Johns Hopkins University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Deaton, A. 2003, “Prices and Poverty in India, 1987-2000,Economic and Political Weekly (January 25), pp. 36268.

  • Deaton, A. and N. Stern, 1986, “Optimally Uniform Commodity Taxes, Taste Differences and Lump-Sum Grants,Economics Letters, Vol. 20, pp. 26366.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Decaluwé, B., A. Patry, L. Savard, and E. Thorbecke, 1999, “Poverty Analysis Within a General Equilibrium Framework,CREFA Working Paper No. 99-06 (Laval, Quebec: Centre de Recherche en Economie et Finance Appliquées). Available via the Internet at http://www.crefa.ecn.ulaval.ca/cahier/9906.pdf..

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Deininger, K., and P. Olinto, 2000, “Asset Distribution, Inequality and Growth,World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 2375 (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Delgado, C, J. Hopkins, V. Kelly, and others, 1998, “Agricultural Growth Linkages in Sub-Saharan Africa,IFPRI Research Report No. 107 (Washington: International Food Policy Research Institute).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dembele, N., and J. Staatz, 1999, “The Impact of Market Reform on Agricultural Transformation in Mali,MSU Agricultural Economics Staff Paper No. 99-29 (East Lansing, Michigan: Michigan State University).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dembele, N., and M. Weber, 2003, “Impact of the Malian Cereals Market Reform Program on FarmersInternational Development Policy Syntheses No. 68 (East Lansing, Michigan: Department of Agricultural Economics, Michigan State University).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dercon, S., 2002, The Impact of Economic Reforms on Rural Households in Ethiopia (Washington: World Bank).

  • Dervis, K., J. de Melo, and S. Robinson, 1982, General Equilibrium Models for Development Policy (New York: Cambridge University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Devarajan, S., and D. Go, 2003, “The 123PRSP Model,in The Impact of Economic Policies on Poverty and Income Distribution: Evaluation Techniques and Tools, ed. by F. Bourguignon and L. Pereira da Silva (Washington: World Bank), pp. 277300.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Devarajan, S., and S. Hossain, 1995, “The Combined Incidence of Taxes and Public Expenditures in the Philippines,Policy Research Working Paper No. 1543 (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Devarajan, S., J. Lewis, and S. Robinson, 1993, “External Shocks, Purchasing Power Parity, and the Equilibrium Real Exchange Rate,World Bank Economic Review, Vol. 7 (January), pp. 4563.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Devarajan, S., K. Thierfelder, and S. Suthiwart-Narueput, 2002, “The Marginal Cost of Public IMFs in Developing Countries,in Policy Evaluation with Computable General Equilibrium Models, ed. by A. Fossati and W. Wiegard (London: Routledge).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Diamond, P., 1975, “A Many-Person Ramsey Tax Rule,Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 4 (November), pp. 33542.

  • Diamond, P., and J. Mirrlees, 1971a, “Optimal Taxation and Public Production I: Production Efficiency,American Economic Review, Vol. 61 (March), pp. 827.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Diamond, P., 1971b, “Optimal Taxation and Public Production II: Tax Rules,American Economic Review, Vol. 61 (June), pp. 26178.

  • Diamond, P., 1975, “Private Constant Returns and Public Shadow Prices,Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 43, pp. 4147.

  • Dixit, A., 1975, “Welfare Effects of Tax and Price Changes,Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 4 (February), pp. 10323.

  • Dixit, A., 1985, “Tax Policy in Open Economies,Handbook of Public Economics, Volume 1, ed. by A. Auerbach and M. Feldstein (Amsterdam: North-Holland).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dollar, D., 1992, “Outward-Oriented Developing Economies Really Do Grow More Rapidly: Evidence from 95 LDCs, 1976-1985,Economic Development and Cultural Change, Vol. 40 (April), pp. 52314.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dollar, D., and A. Kraay, 2002, “Growth Is Good for the Poor,Journal of Economic Growth, Vol. 7, No. 3, pp. 195225.

  • Dorosh, P., and D. Sahn, 2000, “A General Equilibrium Analysis of the Effect of Macroeconomic Adjustment on Poverty in Africa,Journal of Policy Modeling, Vol. 22 (November), pp. 75376.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dréze, J., and N. Stern, 1987, “The Theory of Cost-Benefit Analysis,in Handbook of Public Economics, Volume 2, ed. by A. Auerbach and M. Feldstein (Amsterdam: North-Holland).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Easterly, W., and A. Kraay, 2000, “Small States, Small Problems? Income, Growth, and Volatility in Small States,World Development, Vol. 28 (November), pp. 201327.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ebrill, L, M. Keen, J.-P. Bodin, and V. Summers, 2001, The Modern VAT (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

  • Ebrill, L., J. Stotsky, and R. Gropp, 1999, Revenue Implications of Trade Liberalization, IMF Occasional Paper No. 180 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Edwards, S., 1986, “Are Devaluations Contractionary?Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 68 (August), pp. 501508.

  • Edwards, S., 1989, “On the Sequencing of Structural Reforms,NBER Working Paper No. 3138 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Edwards, S., 1994, “Trade and Industrial Policy Reform in Latin America,NBER Working Paper No. 4772 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Edwards, S., 1998, “Openness, Productivity and Growth: What Do We Really Know?Economic Journal, Vol. 108 (March), pp. 38398.

  • Ellis, F., 1998, “Household Strategies and Rural Livelihood Diversification,Journal of Development Studies, Vol. 35 (October), pp. 138.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Emran, M., and J. Stiglitz, 2005, “On Selective Indirect Tax Reform in Developing Countries,Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 89 (April), pp. 599623.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Essama-Nssah, B., 2005, “The Poverty and Distributional Impact of Macroeconomic Shocks and Policies: A Review of Modeling Approaches,Policy Research Working Paper No. 3682 (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fallon, P., and R. Lucas, 2002, “The Impact of Financial Crises on Labor Markets, Household Incomes, and Poverty: A Review of Evidence,World Bank Research Observer, Vol. 17 (Spring), pp. 2145.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Federico, G., J. Daniel, and B. Bingham, 2001, “Domestic Petroleum Price Smoothing in Developing and Transition Countries,IMF Working Paper 01/75 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fletcher, K., 2005, “Increasing Public Sector Revenue in the Philippines: Equity and Efficiency Considerations,IMF Working Paper 05/22 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fourie, F., and A. Owen, 1993, “Value-added Tax and Regressivity in South Africa,South African Journal of Economics, Vol. 61, No. 4.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Frankenberg, E., J. Smith, and D. Thomas, 2003, “Economic Shocks, Wealth, and Welfare,Journal of Human Resources, Vol. 38 (Spring), pp. 280321.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gemmell, N. 1987, “Taxation and Development,in Surveys in Development Economics, ed. by N. Gemmell (Oxford, United Kingdom: Basil Blackwell).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gemmell, N. and O. Morrissey, 2003, “Tax Structure and the Incidence on the Poor in Developing Countries,CREDIT Research Paper 03/18 (Nottingham, United Kingdom: University of Nottingham).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gemmell, N. 2005, “Distribution and Poverty Impacts of Tax Structure Reforms in Developing Countries: How Little We Know,Development Policy Review, Vol. 23, No. 2, pp. 13144.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gibson, J., 1998, “Indirect Tax Reform and the Poor in Papua New Guinea,Pacific Economic Bulletin, Vol. 13, No. 2, pp. 2939.

  • Gillis, M., ed., 1989, Tax Reform in Developing Countries (Durham, North Carolina: Duke University Press).

  • Gisselquist, D., and J. Grether, 2000, “An Argument for Deregulating the Transfer of Agricultural Technologies to Developing Countries,World Bank Economic Review, Vol. 14, No. 1, pp. 11127.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Go, D., M. Kearney, S. Robinson, and K. Thierfelder, 2005, “An Analysis of South Africa’s Value Added TaxPolicy Research Working Paper No. 3671 (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Goetz, S.J., 1992, “A Selectivity Model of Household Food Marketing Behavior in Sub-Saharan Africa,American Journal of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 74 (May), pp. 44452.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Goldberg, P., and N. Pavcnik, 2004, “Trade, Inequality, and Poverty: What Do We Know? Evidence from Recent Trade Liberalization Episodes in Developing Countries,NBER Working Paper No. 10593 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Goldberg, P., and N. Pavcnik, 2007, “Distributional Effects of Globalization in Developing Countries,NBER Working Paper No. 12885 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Grimard, F., 1997, “Household Consumption Smoothing Through Ethnic Ties: Evidence from Cote d’lvoire,Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 53 (August), pp. 391122.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Grossman, G., and E. Helpman, 1991, Innovation and Growth in the Global Economy (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press).

  • Guesnerie, R., 1979, “General Statements on Second Best Pareto Optimality,Journal of Mathematical Economics, Vol. 6 (July), pp. 16994.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gunning, J., and M. Keyzer, 1995, “Applied General Equilibrium Models for Policy Analysis,in Handbook of Development Economics, Volume 3A, ed. by J. Behrman and T. Srinivasan(Amsterdam: North-Holland).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gunter, B.G., M.J. Cohen, and H. Lofgren, 2005, “Analysing Macro-Poverty Linkages: An Overview,Development Policy Review, Vol. 23 (May), pp. 24365.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gupta, S., M. Verhoeven, R. Gillingham, J. Cordoba, C. Schiller, and M. Ali, 2000, Equity and Efficiency in the Reform of Price Subsidies: A Guide for Policymakers (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gupta, S., and others, 2002, Is the PRGF Living Up to Expectations? An Assessment of Program Design, IMF Occasional Paper No. 216 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gylfason, T., and M. Radetzki, 1991, “Does Devaluation Make Sense in the Least Developed Countries?Economic Development and Cultural Change, Vol. 40 (October), pp. 125.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gylfason, T., and M. Schmid, 1983, “Does Devaluation Cause Stagflation?Canadian Journal of Economics, Vol. 16 (November), pp. 64154.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Harrison, G., T. Rutherford, and D. Tarr, 1993, “Piecemeal Trade Reform in the Partially Liberalized Economy of Turkey,World Bank Economic Review, Vol. 7, (May), pp. 191217.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Harrison, G., T. Rutherford, and D. Tarr, 2003, “Trade Liberalization, Poverty and Efficient Equity,Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 71 (June), pp. 97128.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hazell, P., C. Ramasamy, and V. Rajagopalan, 1991, “An Analysis of the Indirect Effects of Agricultural Growth on the Regional Economy,in The Green Revolution Reconsidered: The Impact of High-Yielding Rice Varieties in South India, ed. by P. Hazell and C. Ramasamy (Baltimore, Maryland: Johns Hopkins University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Heady, C, 2001, “Taxation Policy in Low-Income Countries,WIDER Discussion Paper No. 2001/81 (Helsinki: World Institute for Development Economic Research, United Nations University). Available via the Internet at. http://www.wider.unu.edu/publications/dps/dp2001-81.pdf.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Heady, C, and P. Mitra, 1982. “Restricted Redistributive Taxation, Shadow Prices and Trade Policy,Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 17, No. 1, pp. 122.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Heady, C, 1987, “Optimal Taxation and Shadow Prices in a Developing Economy,in The Theory of Taxation for Developing Countries, ed. by D. Newbery and N. Stern (New York: Oxford University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Heltberg, R., and F. Tarp, 2002, “Agriculture Supply Response and Poverty in Mozambique,Food Policy, Vol. 27 (April), pp. 10324.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hertel, T., and J. Reimer, 2004, “Predicting the Poverty Impacts of Trade Reform,Policy Research Working Paper No. 3444 (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hertel, T., and L. Winters, 2005, “Poverty Impacts of a WTO Agreement: Synthesis and Overview,in Poverty and the WTO: Impacts of the Doha Development Agenda, World Bank Trade and Development Series, ed. by T. Hertel and L. Winters (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hossain, S., 1995. “The Equity Impact of the Value-Added Tax in Bangladesh,IMF Staff Papers, Vol. 42 (June), pp. 41132.

  • Hossain, S., 2003, “Poverty and Social Impact Analysis: A Suggested Framework,IMF Working Paper 03/195 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hughes, G, 1986, “A New Method for Estimating the Effects of Fuel Taxes: An Application to Thailand,World Bank Economic Review, Vol. 1, No. 1, pp. 65101.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hughes, G, 1987, “The Incidence of Fuel Taxes: A Comparative Study of Three Countries,in The Theory of Taxation for Developing Countries, ed. by D. Newbery and N. Stern(New York: Oxford University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Inchauste, G, 2002, “Poverty and Social Impact Analysis in PRGF-Supported Programs,IMF Policy Discussion Paper 02/11 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund (IMF), 1987, Theoretical Aspects of the Design of IMF-Supported Adjustment Programs, IMF Occasional Paper No. 55 (Washington).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Jacoby, H., and E. Skoufias, 1997, “Risk, Financial Markets, and Human Capital in a Developing Country,Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 64 (July), pp. 31136.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Jalan, J., and M. Ravallion, 1999, “Are the Poor Less Well Insured? Evidence on Vulnerability to Income Risk in Rural China,Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 58 (February), pp. 6181.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Jayne, T., and S. Jones, 1997, “Food Marketing and Pricing Policy in Eastern and Southern Africa: A Survey,World Development, Vol. 25 (September), pp. 150527.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Jayne, T., and others, 1996, “Trends in Real Food Prices in Six Sub-Saharan African Countries,International Development Policy Synthesis No. 2 (East Lansing, Michigan: Department of Agricultural Economics, Michigan State University).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Jayne, T., and others, 1999, “Successes and Challenges of Food Market Reform: Experiences from Kenya, Mozambique, Zambia, and Zimbabwe,MSU International Development Working Paper No. 72 (East Lansing, Michigan: Department of Agricultural Economics, Michigan State University). Available via the Internet at http://www.cfnpp.cornell.edu/fs2/papers/idwp72.pdf.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Jayne, T., Z. Tschirley, and L. Rubey, 1995, “Policy Synthesis: The Effect of Market Reform on Access to Food by Low Income Households: Evidence from Four Countries in Eastern And Southern Africa,USAID Policy Synthesis (Washington: U.S. Agency for International Development).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Julius, D., and A. Alicbusan, 1986, “Public Sector Pricing Policies: A Review of Bank Policy and Practice” (unpublished; Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Keen, M., and J. Ligthart, 2002, “Coordinating Tariff Reduction and Domestic Tax Reform,Journal of International Economics, Vol. 56 (March), pp. 489507.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Keen, M., and A. Simone, 2004, “Tax Policy in Developing Countries: Some Lessons from the 1990s and Some Challenges Ahead,in Helping Countries Develop: The Role of Fiscal Policy, ed. by S. Gupta, B. Clements, and G. Inchauste (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kehoe, T., T. Srinivasan, and J. Whalley, eds., 2005, Frontiers in Applied General Equilibrium Modeling: In Honor of Herbert Scarf (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Khalilzadeh-Shirazi, J., and A. Shah, eds., 1991, Tax Policy in Developing Countries (Washington: World Bank).

  • Khan, M., P. Montiel, and N. Haque, 1990, “Adjustment with Growth: Relating the Analytical Approaches of the IMF and the World Bank,Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 32 (January), pp. 15579.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Khattry, B., and M. Rao, 2002, “Fiscal Faux Pas? An Analysis of the Revenue Implications of Trade Liberalization,World Development, Vol. 30 (August), pp. 143144.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kherallah, M., C. Delgado, E. Gabre-Madhin, N. Minot, and M. Johnson, 2002, Reforming Agricultural Markets in Africa (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kochar, A., 1995, “Explaining Household Vulnerability to Idiosyncratic Income Shocks,American Economic Review: Papers and Proceedings, Vol. 85 (May), pp. 15964.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Krueger, A., 1992, The Political Economy of Agricultural Pricing Policy: A Synthesis of the Political Economy in Developing Countries, Vol. 5 (Baltimore, Maryland: Johns Hopkins University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Krueger, A., M. Schiff, and A. Valdes, 1988, “Agricultural Incentives in Developing Countries: Measuring the Effect of Sectoral and Economywide Policies,World Bank Economic Review, Vol. 2, No. 3, pp. 25571.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lambert, S., 1994, “La Migration Comme Instrument de Diversification Intrafamilialle des Risques. Application au Cas de la Cote dTvoire,Review of Economic Development, Vol. 2, pp. 338.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lee, H., L. Ricci, and R. Rigobon, 2004, “Once Again, Is Openness Good for Growth?NBER Working Paper No. 10749 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Little, I., and J. Mirrlees, 1974, Project Appraisal and Planning in Developing Countries (London: Heinemann Educational).

  • Lofgren, H., 2000, “Trade Reform and the Poor in Morocco: A Rural-Urban General Equilibrium Analysis of Reduced Protection,in Earnings Inequality, Unemployment and Poverty in the Middle East and North Africa, ed. by W. Shahin and G. Dibeh (Westport, Connecticut: Greenwood Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lofgren, H., R. Harris, and S. Robinson, with assistance from M. Thomas and M. El-Said, 2002, A Standard Computable General Equilibrium (CGE) Model in GAMS, Microcomputers in Policy Research, Vol. 5 (Washington: International Food Policy Research Institute).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lofgren, H., S. Robinson, and M. El-Said, 2003, “Poverty and Inequality Analysis in a General Equilibrium Framework: The Representative Household Approach,in The Impact of Economic Policies on Poverty and Income Distribution: Evaluation Techniques and Tools, ed. by F. Bourguignon and L. Pereira da Silva (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lopez, R., J. Nash, and J. Stanton, 1995, “Adjustment and Poverty in Mexican Agriculture: How Farmers’ Wealth Affects Supply Response,Policy Research Working Paper No. 1494 (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lucas, R., 1988, “On the Mechanics of Economic Development,Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 22 (July), pp. 342.

  • Lundberg, M., 2005, “Agricultural Market Reforms” (unpublished; Washington: World Bank).

  • Lutz, M., and H.W. Singer, 1994, “The Link Between Increased Trade Openness and the Terms of Trade: An Empirical Investigation,World Development, Vol. 22 (November), pp.1697709.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lysy, F., and L. Taylor, 1980, “The General Equilibrium Model Income Distribution,in Models of Growth and Distribution for Brazil, ed. by L. Taylor, E. Bacha, E. Cardoso, and F. Lysy (Oxford, United Kingdom: Oxford University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mas-Colell, A., M. Whinston, and J. Green, 1995, Microeconomic Theory (Oxford, United Kingdom: Oxford University Press).

  • Matusz, S., and D. Tarr, 1999, “Adjusting to Trade Policy Reform,Policy Research Working Paper No. 2142 (Washington: World Bank).

  • McCulloch, N., B. Baulch, and M. Cherel-Robson, 2001, “Poverty, Inequality and Growth in Zambia during the 1990s,WIDER Discussion Paper No. 2001/123 (Helsinki: World Institute for Development Economic Research, United Nations University).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • McCulloch, N., A. Winters, and X. Cirera, 2001, Trade Liberalization and Poverty: A Handbook (London: Centre for Economic Policy Research and Department for International Development).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • McKay, A., O. Morrissey, and C. Vaillant, 1997, “Trade Liberalization and Agricultural Supply Response: Issues and Some Lessons,European Journal of Development Research, Vol. 9, No. 2, pp. 12947.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • McKenzie, D., 2001, “The Household Response to the Mexican Peso Crisis,Working Paper No. 01017 (Stanford, California: Department of Economics, Stanford University).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Minot, N., 1998, “Distributional and Nutritional Impact of Devaluation in Rwanda,Economic Development and Cultural Change, Vol. 46 (January), pp. 379402.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Minot, N., and F. Goletti, 2000, “Rice Market Liberalization and Poverty in Vietnam,IFPRI Research Report No. 114 (Washington: International Food Policy Research Institute).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Munoz, S., and S. Cho, 2004, “Social Impact of a Tax Reform: The Case of Ethiopia,in Helping Countries Develop: The Role of Fiscal Policy, ed. by S. Gupta, B. Clements, and G. Inchauste (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Newbery, D., 1986, “On the Desirability of Input Taxes,Economics Letters, Vol. 20, No. 3, pp. 26770.

  • Newbery, D., 1995, “Distributional Impact of Price Changes in Hungary and the United Kingdom,Economic Journal, Vol. 105 (July), pp. 84763.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Newbery, D., and N. Stern, eds., 1987, The Theory of Taxation for Developing Countries (New York: Oxford University Press).

  • Nicita, A., 2003, “The Effects of Mexican Trade Liberalization on Household Welfare” (unpublished; Washington: World Bank).

  • Nicita, A., 2004, “Efficiency and Equity of a Marginal Tax Reform: Income, Quality and Price Elasticities for Mexico,Policy Research Working Paper No. 3266 (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Nicita, A., 2005, “Doha Implications for Poverty Reduction in Ethiopia” (unpublished; Washington: Development Research Group, World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Orcutt, G., 1957, “A New Type of Socio-Economic System,Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 39 (May), pp. 11623.

  • Patel, C, ed.,1997, Fiscal Reforms in the Least Developed Countries (Cheltenham, United Kingdo: Edward Elgar).

  • Perry, G., J. Whalley, and G. McMahon, eds., 2000, Fiscal Reform and Structural Change in Developing Countries, Volumes I and II (London: Macmillan).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Peters, P., 1996, “Failed Magic or Social Context? Market Liberalization and the Rural Poor in Malawi,HIID Discussion Paper No. 562 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard Institute for International Development).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Pfahler, W., 1987, “Redistribute Effects of Tax Progressivity: Evaluating a General Class of Aggregate Measures,Public Finance, Vol. 42, No. 3, pp. 131.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Pfingsten, A., 1986, The Measurement of Tax Progression (Berlin: Springer Verlag).

  • Piggott, J., and J. Whalley, 2001, “VAT Base Broadening, Self-Supply and the Informal Sector,American Economic Review, Vol. 91 (September), pp. 108494.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Pinstrup-Andersen, P., ed., 1988, Food Subsidies in Developing Countries: Costs, Benefits, and Policy Options (Baltimore: John Hopkins University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Porto, G, 2003a, “Trade Reforms, Market Access and Poverty in ArgentinaPolicy Research Working Paper No. 3135 (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Porto, G, 2003b, “Using Survey Data to Access the Distributional Effects of Trade Policy” (unpublished; Washington: World Bank).

  • Porto, G, I. Brambilla, and J. Balat, 2004, “An Analysis of the WTO Development Round on Poverty in Rural and Urban Zambia” (unpublished; Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Powell, M., and J. Round, 2000, “Structure and Linkage in the Economy of Ghana: A SAM Approach,in Economic Reforms in Ghana: The Miracle and the Mirage, ed. by E. Aryeetey, J. Harrigan, and M. Nissanke (Trenton, New Jersey: Africa World Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Rajemison, H., S. Haggblade and S. Younger, 2003, “Indirect Tax Incidence in Madagascar: Updated Estimates Using the Input-Output Table” (Ithaca, New York: Cornell Food and Nutrition Policy Program).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Rajemison, H., and S. Younger, 2000, “Indirect Tax Incidence in Madagascar: Estimations Using the Input-Output Table,Working Paper No. 106 (Ithaca, New York: Cornell Food and Nutrition Policy Program). Available via the Internet at http://www.crefa.ecn.ulaval.ca/cahier/0118.pdf.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ramsey, F., 1927, “A Contribution to the Theory of Taxation,Economic Journal, Vol. 37 (March), pp. 4761.

  • Rattso, J., 1982, “Different Macroclosures of the Original Johansen Model and Their Impact on Policy Evaluation,Journal of Policy Modeling, Vol. 4 (March), pp. 8597.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ravallion, M., 1990, “Rural Welfare Effects of Food Price Changes under Induced Wage Responses: Theory and Evidence for Bangladesh,Oxford Economic Papers, Vol. 42 (June), pp. 57485.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ravallion, M., 1995, “Growth and Poverty: Evidence for Developing Countries in the 1980s,Economics Letters, Vol. 48 (June), pp. 41117.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ravallion, M., 2001, “Growth, Inequality and Poverty: Looking Beyond Averages,World Development, Vol. 29 (November), pp. 18315.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ravallion, M., 2004, “Looking Beyond Averages in the Trade and Poverty Debate,Policy Research Working Paper No. 3461 (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ravallion, M., and M. Lokshin, 2004, “Gainers and Losers from Trade Reform in Morocco,Policy Research Working Paper No. 3368 (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ravallion, M., and D. van de Walle, 1991, “The Impact on Poverty of Food Pricing Reforms: A Welfare Analysis for Indonesia,Journal of Policy Modeling, Vol. 13 (Summer), pp. 28199.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Razin, A., and A. Rose, 1994, “Business-Cycle Volatility and Openness: An Exploratory Cross-Sectional Analysis,in Capital Mobility: The Impact on Consumption, Investment and Growth, ed. by L. Leiderman and A. Razin(Cambridge, United Kingdom: Cambridge University Press), pp. 4882.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Reardon, T., C. Barrett, V. Kelly, and K. Savadogo, 1999, “Policy Reforms and Sustainable Agricultural Intensification in Africa,Development Policy Review, Vol. 17 (December), pp. 37595.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Refaqat, S., 2003, “Social Incidence of the General Sales Tax in Pakistan,IMF Working Paper 03/216 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Reimer, J., 2002, “Estimating the Poverty Impacts of Trade Liberalization,Policy Research Working Paper No. 2790 (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Rivera-Batiz, L., and P. Romer, 1991, “Economic Integration and Endogenous Growth,Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 106 (May), pp. 53155.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Robilliard, A., F. Bourguignon, and S. Robinson, 2003, “Examining the Social Impact of the Indonesian Financial Crisis Using a Micro-Macro Model,paper presented at ABCDE-Europe 2003 (Workshop Session J), “Effects of Globalization Factors on Poverty and Inequality in National Economies,” Paris, May 1516.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Robinson, S., 1989, “Multisectoral Models,in Handbook of Development Economics, Vol. 2, ed. by H. Chenery and T.N. Srinivasan (Amsterdam: Elsevier Science Publishers).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Robinson, S., 1991, “Macroeconomics, Financial Variables, and Computable General Equilibrium Models,World Development, Vol. 19 (November), pp. 150925.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Robinson, S., 2005, “Macro Models and Multipliers: Leontief, Stone, Keynes, and CGE Models,in Poverty, Inequality and Development: Essays in Honor of Erik Thorbecke, ed. by A. de Janvry and R. Kanbur (Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Robinson, S., A. Cattaneo, and M. El-Said, 2001, “Updating and Estimating a Social Accounting Matrix Using Cross Entropy Methods,Economic Systems Research, Vol. 13 (March), pp. 4764.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Robinson, S., and M. El-Said, 2000, “GAMS Code for Estimating a Social Accounting Matrix (SAM) Using Cross Entropy Methods (CE),TMD Discussion Paper No. 64 (Washington: International Food Policy Research Institute).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Robinson, S., and H. Lofgren, 2005, “Macro Models and Poverty Analysis: Theoretical Tensions and Empirical Practice,Development Policy Review, Vol. 23 (May), pp. 26783.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Rodriguez, F., and D. Rodrik, 2001, “Trade Policy and Economic Growth: A Skeptic’s Guide to the Cross National Evidence,NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2000, ed. by B. Bernanke and K. Rogoff (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press), pp. 261324.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Romer, P., 1990, “Endogenous Technological Change,Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 98 (October), pp. S71S102.

  • Rosenzweig, M., and K. Wolpin, 1993, “Credit Market Constraints, Consumption Smoothing, and the Accumulation of Durable Production Assets in Low-Income Countries: Investment in Bullocks in India,Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 101 (April), pp. 22344.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Round, J., 2003, “Social Accounting Matrices and SAM-Based Multiplier Analysis,in The Impact of Economic Policies on Poverty and Income Distribution: Evaluation Techniques and Tools, ed. by F. Bourguignon and L. Pereira da Silva (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Sachs, J., and A. Warner, 1995, “Economic Convergence and Economic Policies,Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: I, Brookings Institution, pp. 195.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Sadoulet, E., and A. de Janvry, 1992, “Agricultural Trade Liberalization in Low-Income Countries: A General Equilibrium-Multimarket Approach,American Journal of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 74 (May), pp. 26880.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Sadoulet, E., and A. de Janvry, 1995, Quantitative Development Policy Analysis (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press).

  • Sahn, D., P. Dorosh, and S. Younger, 1997, Structural Adjustment Reconsidered: Economic Policy and Poverty in Africa (Cambridge, United Kingdom: Cambridge University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Sahn, D., and S. Younger, 1999a, “Dominance Testing of Social Sector Expenditures and Taxes in Africa,IMF Working Paper 99/172 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Sahn, D., and S. Younger, 1999b, “Fiscal Incidence in Africa: Microeconomic Evidence,Working Paper No. 91 (Ithaca, New York: Cornell Food and Nutrition Policy Program). Available via the Internet at http://www.cfnpp.cornell.edu/images/wp91.pdf.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Savard, L., 2003, “Poverty and Income Distribution in a CGE-Household Micro-Simulation Model: Top Down/Bottom Up Approach,CIRPEE Working Paper No. 03-43 (Montreal: Centre Interuniversitaire sur le Risque, les Politiques Economiques et l’Emploi, Universite Laval).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Schiff, M., and A. Valdes, 1992, The Political Economy of Agricultural Pricing Policy: A Synthesis of the Economics in Developing Countries: A World Bank Comparative Study, Vol. 4 (Baltimore: John Hopkins University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Schultz, T., 1975, “The Value of the Ability to Deal with Disequilibria,Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 13 (September), pp. 82746.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Sen, A., 1963, “Neo-Classical and Neo-Keynesian Theories of Distribution,Economic Record, Vol. 39, pp. 5464.

  • Seshamani, V., 1998, “The Impact of Market Liberalisation on Food Security in Zambia,Food Policy, Vol. 23 (December), pp. 53951.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Shah, A., and J. Whalley, 1991, “The Redistributive Impact of Taxation in Developing Countries,in Tax Policy in Developing Countries, ed. by J. Khalilzadeh-Shirazi and A. Shah (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Sobarzo, H., 2000, “Interactions Between Trade and Tax Reform in Mexico: Some General Equilibrium Results,in Fiscal Reform and Structural Change in Developing Countries, Vols. I and II, ed. by G. Perry, J. Whalley, and G. McMahon(London: Macmillan).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Stern, N., 1987, “The Effects of Taxation, Price Control and Government Contracts in Oligopoly and Monopolistic Competition,Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 32 (March), pp. 13358.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Stewart, F., 1995, Adjustment and Poverty: Options and Choices (London and New York: Routledge).

  • Stiglitz, J., and P. Dasgupta, 1971, “Differential Taxation, Public Goods, and Economic Efficiency,Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 38 (April), pp. 15174.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Stone, R., 1985, “The Disaggregation of the Household Sector in the National Accounts,in Social Accounting Matrices: A Basis for Planning, ed. by G. Pyatt and J. Round (Washington: World Bank), pp. 14585.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Tanzi, V., 1987, “Quantitative Characteristics of the Tax Systems of Developing Countries,in The Theory of Taxation for Developing Countries, ed. by D. Newbery and N. Stern (New York: Oxford University Press)

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Tanzi, V., 2000, “Taxation and Economic Structure,in Fiscal Reform and Structural Change in Developing Countries, Vols. 1 and II, ed. by G. Perry, J. Whalley, and G. McMahon (London: Macmillan).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Taylor, A., 1998, “On the Costs of Inward-Looking Development: Price Distortions, Growth, and Divergence in Latin America,Journal of Economic History, Vol. 58 (March), pp. 128.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Taylor, L., 1990, “Structuralist CGE Models,in Socially Relevant Policy Analysis, ed. by Lance Taylor (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Taylor, L., 2004, Reconstructing Macroeconomics: Structuralist Proposals and Critiques of the Mainstream (Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Thirsk, W., ed., 1997, Tax Reform in Developing Countries (Washington: World Bank).

  • Topalova, P., 2004, “Factor Immobility and Regional Effects of Trade Liberalization: Evidence from India” (unpublished: Cambridge, Massachusetts: Massachusetts Institute of Technology).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Topalova, P., 2006, “Trade Liberalization, Poverty, and Inequality: Evidence from Indian Districts,in Globalization and Poverty, NBER Conference Report, ed. by A. Harrison (Chicago: University of Chicago Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Townsend, R., and R. Mueller, R., 1998, “Mechanism Design and Village Economies: From Credit to Tenancy to Cropping Groups,Review of Economic Dynamics, Vol. 1 (January), pp. 11972.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Trairatvorakul, P., 1984, “The Effects on Income Distribution and Nutrition of Alternative Rice Price Policies in Thailand,Research Report No. 46 (Washington: International Food Policy Research Institute).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Triest, R., 1990, “The Relationship Between the Marginal Cost of Public Funds and Marginal Excess Burden,American Economic Review, Vol. 80, No. 3, pp. 55766.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Udry, C, 1995, “Risk and Saving in Northern Nigeria,American Economic Review, Vol. 85 (December), pp. 1287300.

  • Wacziarg, R., 2001, “Measuring the Dynamic Gains from Trade,World Bank Economic Review, Vol. 15, No. 3, pp. 393429.

  • Warr, P., 2001, “Welfare Effects of an Export Tax: Thailand’s Rice Premium,American Journal of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 83 (November), pp. 90320.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Winters, L., 2000, “Trade Liberalisation and Poverty,PRUS Working Paper No. 7 (Sussex, United Kingdom: Poverty Research Unit, University of Sussex). Available via the Internet at http://www.sussex.ac.ukAJnits/PRU/wps/wp7.pdf.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Winters, L., N. McCulloch, and A. McKay, 2004, “Trade Liberalization and Poverty: The Evidence So Far,Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 42 (March), pp. 72115.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • World Bank, 2003, Reforming the Malawi Agricultural Development and Marketing Corporation (ADMARC) (Washington).

  • Young, A., 1991, “Learning by Doing and the Dynamic Effects of International Trade,Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 106 (May), pp. 369405.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation