Abstract

Ghana’s economy has performed well in recent years compared with its regional peers. Per capita GDP growth averaged 1.6 percent annually in the 1990s. After a period of economic volatility around the turn of the century, Ghana has pursued economic policies that have delivered a degree of fiscal consolidation, lower inflation, and steadily increasing real GDP growth. Starting in 2000–01, international support jumped by several percentage points of GDP. Net aid averaged 7.3 percent of GDP during 2001–03 compared with 2.8 percent during 1996–2000 (Table 4.1).

Ghana’s economy has performed well in recent years compared with its regional peers. Per capita GDP growth averaged 1.6 percent annually in the 1990s. After a period of economic volatility around the turn of the century, Ghana has pursued economic policies that have delivered a degree of fiscal consolidation, lower inflation, and steadily increasing real GDP growth. Starting in 2000–01, international support jumped by several percentage points of GDP. Net aid averaged 7.3 percent of GDP during 2001–03 compared with 2.8 percent during 1996–2000 (Table 4.1).

Table 4.1.

Ghana: Net Aid Inflows and Selected Economic Indicators

(Percent of GDP)

article image

Net of arrears and debt relief, including Heavily Indebted Poor Countries (HIPC) Initiative.

Includes private transfers (largely remittances) reported in the current account.

This case study looks at Ghana’s experience during 1996–2003, a period when the country was almost continuously engaged in economic adjustment programs supported by the International Monetary Fund’s Enhanced Structural Adjustment Facility (ESAF) and its successor, the Poverty Reduction and Growth Facility (PRGF).1

Pattern of Aid Inflows

The pattern of aid inflows is critical to understanding Ghana’s policy response to aid during 2000–03 and the resulting economic outcomes. Net aid jumped in 2001, collapsed in 2002, and jumped again in 2003. This volatility was unexpected, and thus required large and rapid policy adjustments (Table 4.2). Most of these changes were driven by changes in gross aid flows. Debt relief under the Heavily Indebted Poor Countries (HIPC) Initiative was also a major, and much smoother, contributing factor. Ghana reached the HIPC Initiative “decision point” in 2002, and the value of the associated debt service relief was about half that of loans and grants in 2002–03. Private flows, mostly transfers but including unidentified items as well, also rose sharply, amplifying the effects of aid shocks.

Table 4.2.

Ghana: Aid Shocks

(In percent of GDP)

article image
Note: HIPC = Heavily Indebted Poor Countries Initiative. “Aid shocks” are defined as aid received in a given year less aid expected just prior to that year, as reflected in IMF staff projections. A negative number thus implies a shortfall in actual aid compared to the expected level of aid.

Was Aid Absorbed?

During the entire 2001–03 period when aid soared, Ghana’s non-aid current account deficit narrowed. In other words, the aid was not used to increase net imports, or more generally to raise investment relative to domestic savings. Rather, inflows were fully accumulated as reserves. The narrower non-aid current account deficit reflected stable or declining import volumes (Table 4.3).

Table 4.3.

Ghana: Balance of Payments

(In percent of GDP)

article image
Note: f.o.b. = free on board.

This definition of net aid is taken from the balance of payments and may differ from the net aid inflows reported in the government’s accounts and reported in Table 4.1.

Includes unidentified capital flows and errors and omissions.

Consistent with Ghana saving the aid as higher reserves, there was little evidence of Dutch disease. The real effective exchange rate changed by less than 1 percent during the period and exhibited little volatility.2 In view of the absence of real appreciation, it would seem unnecessary to examine the performance of exports for Dutch disease symptoms. Nonetheless, the decline in nontraditional export volumes during the period of higher aid is puzzling (Table 4.3).

This picture for 2001–03 masks three distinct episodes that mirrored the fluctuations in aid:

  • About half of the 2001 aid jump (equivalent to 5.1 percent of GDP) remained in reserves, while the rest financed a deterioration in the capital account (indeed, more than the rest, as the non-aid current account deficit shrank).

  • The 2002 aid collapse of 5.9 percent of GDP was more than outweighed by a decline of the non-aid current account deficit.3 This and some capital inflows permitted a further reserve accumulation equivalent to 3.3 percent of GDP.

  • Finally, the 2003 aid jump (equal to 6.5 percent of GDP) and a further decline of the non-aid current account deficit (of 1 percent of GDP) fed a further reserve build-up (to 7.3 percent of GDP).4

GDP growth and the real exchange rate were remarkably steady through the entire period. The nominal exchange rate for the cedi depreciated by nearly 50 percent in 2000, but the use of aid in 2001 helped arrest the decline. Reserve accumulation after 2001 contributed to ongoing nominal depreciation, a policy choice discussed below.

Was Aid Spent?

On a cumulative basis, none of the aid Ghana received was spent in the sense of allowing a widening fiscal deficit (net of aid). This does not mean that aid money itself was not spent, but that if it was, other spending was reduced correspondingly.

Aid going to the budget followed the same pattern as aid measured through the balance of payments (Table 4.4). During 2001–02, fiscal policy was sensitive to aid flows. In 2001, the fiscal deficit widened by half the increase in aid. The next year’s large and unexpected aid shortfall triggered a fiscal consolidation that was large but still not enough to close the shortfall. However, fiscal policymakers responded cautiously to the aid surge in 2003; the fiscal balance did not react at all. Although spending rose, it was fully financed by higher nongrant revenues. On a cumulative basis, aid had little fiscal impact during 2001–03.

Table 4.4.

Ghana: Net Aid Flows and the Fiscal Response

(In percent of GDP)

article image

Net domestic financing, given by the period’s change in the domestic net credit to government.

From 2001 on a cash basis.

Includes subventions in separate line items from 2002 onward.

The volatility of the aid flows seems to have complicated expenditure management and perhaps undermined the efficiency of spending (Figure 4.1). The increase in spending associated with the 2001 aid jump came mainly in the form of higher public capital expenditure, but also recurrent expenditure (Table 4.4). When aid declined by more than 8 percent of GDP in 2002, capital expenditure fell by nearly 7 percentage points of GDP, as current expenditures continued to rise. In 2003, capital expenditures rose with higher domestic revenues, but to levels well below the average of the four pre-aid boom years.

Figure 4.1.
Figure 4.1.

Ghana: Aid Flows and Public Expenditure Patterns

(In percent of GDP)

The volatile but increasing trend in net aid did not lead to any apparent reduction in Ghana’s revenue efforts. Revenues excluding grants have increased steadily as a share of GDP since 1999.

Why did Ghana not spend the aid on a cumulative basis? Three motivations seem to have been at work:

  • A desire to resolve underlying fiscal problems and achieve disinflation;

  • IMF conditionality on fiscal policy and its interaction with volatility; and

  • An underlying concern for the implications of aid volatility.

Throughout 2001–03, the IMF-supported program targets implied that a large part of the aid increment—between 2 and 4 percentage points of GDP—was not to be spent, in order to reduce the large stock of domestic public debt, high domestic interest rates, and the resulting large share of interest payments in expenditures.

Given the (unpredicted) volatility of aid to Ghana, the interaction between the surprise component of aid flows and the fiscal performance criteria is an important part of the story. The criteria were subject to asymmetric adjustors to account for deviations between expected and realized aid flows. Positive aid shocks were to be saved and were not to be used to increase spending. Negative aid shocks were to be partially dealt with through a reduction in spending and, hence, a narrower deficit (before grants) (Box 4.1).

As noted earlier, roughly half of each aid jump during 2001–03 was unexpected. In 2001, the increase in domestic credit roughly matched the expected component of the aid inflow. Correspondingly, the actual size of the primary deficit and domestic financing of the budget were close to, though somewhat below, the adjusted program targets. This small degree of outperformance implies that the program was almost binding; there was little scope to boost spending and this led the authorities to save almost all of the aid surprise. Figure 4.2 illustrates this point for domestic financing, which implies the same constraints applied to the fiscal deficit.

Figure 4.2.
Figure 4.2.

Ghana: Performance Against Domestic Financing Targets

(In billions of cedis)

Note: Shaded areas: positive aid surprise; nonshaded areas: negative aid surprise.

In 2002, Ghana’s IMF-supported program again called for a large reduction in domestic financing. This was because of the need to begin reducing the large stock of domestic debt—which had reached 20 percent of GDP—and because of high real interest rates. But the substantial fiscal consolidation (equivalent to 6.5 percent of GDP) did not fully compensate for the huge aid shortfall. The adjustors allowed for some rise in domestic financing, but the program’s targets were still breached.

In 2003, however, even the expected component of the surge was not spent. In this case, the targets were clearly not a binding constraint on fiscal policy. This is illustrated by the large degree of outperformance against the domestic borrowing criteria in Figure 4.1, indicating that the authorities had room to increase spending under the program. Such increases in government expenditure as were observed were largely financed by terms-of-trade-related increases in tax revenues.

Ghana’s choice not to spend the aid surge of 2003 requires further explanation. One obvious inference is that the largely unexpected aid volatility of the previous few years dictated caution, particularly in view of the impact of aid and, hence, fiscal volatility on capital expenditures.

Ghana’s fiscal caution in 2003 is consistent with its policy on reserve accumulation. The authorities saved the entire 2003 aid jump (and more) in reserves. Spending the aid in the face of reserve accumulation would have been equivalent to a domestically-financed fiscal expansion. Thus, the reserve accumulation policy made the fiscal savings more advisable. The reserve accumulation itself may have been driven partly by fiscal policymakers’ desire to save the aid jump. In any case, the two policies together served to save the aid inflows.

Finally, the lack of fiscal expansion in 2003 despite the surge in aid afforded the authorities scope to use the aid inflows to stabilize the exchange rate and inflation, which had increased sharply in late 2002 and early 2003. In order to understand this better, we now turn to Ghana’s monetary policy response to the aid inflows.

Monetary Policy Response

The pattern of absorption and spending in Ghana—essentially the don’t-absorb-and-don’t-spend strategy on a cumulative basis—implies that the aid flows in and of themselves had no overall impact on Ghana’s monetary policy. In effect, the aid left the country in the form of higher reserves, and the government compensated for any aid-related expenditure increase by cutting spending elsewhere. This contrasts with the strategy outlined in Ghana’s PRGF-supported program, which was to mostly absorb and partly spend the expected aid increments in order to reduce the burden of domestic debt on the economy.

Again, this big picture masks some interesting year-by-year variations. Ghana experienced two major surges of inflation during the period—in 2000–01 and again in 2002–03. Each followed sharp and unexpected aid declines, and in the first case a major terms-of-trade decline as well. Each was also accompanied by a loosening of domestic monetary and fiscal policy. And each was followed by an aid surge. In the first case, the authorities used aid to help stabilize the economy; in the second, they did not.

The first aid surge came when the Ghanaian economy was still reeling from a terms-of-trade decline of 25 percent during 1999–2000 (Box 4.2).5 In response to this shock, and with foreign reserves equal to one month of imports at the end of 2000, the authorities failed to tighten fiscal policy sufficiently; rather, they increased domestic borrowing and ran up domestic arrears to plug the shortfall. Reserve money growth took off and the result was a 50 percent loss in the currency’s nominal effective value and a sharp rise in inflation, which rose to an annual average of about 40 percent (Figure 4.3).

Figure 4.3.
Figure 4.3.

Ghana: Exchange Rates, Inflation, and Aid Flows

(In percent annual change)

Note: NEER = nominal effective exchange rate.

The aid surge in 2001 was partly sold into the foreign exchange market, strengthening the cedi and helping reduce money growth. Given the worsening capital account, it is likely that in the absence of the aid surge the nominal exchange rate declines in 2001 would have been much larger than the modest 5 percent experienced.

Ghana: Program Adjustors for Aid Surprises

The criteria set out in the program supported by the Poverty Reduction and Growth Facility for Ghana were subject to asymmetric adjustors to account for deviations between expected and realized aid flows. Positive aid shocks were to be saved in higher net international reserves (NIR) and lower net domestic assets (NDA), while negative aid shocks were to be partially dealt with through a reduction in NIR and some increase in NDA. Some cushion was built in, so that the adjustment was some proportion of the aid shortfall. But if the criteria were binding, shortfalls still implied a tightening of policy.

IMF-Supported Program Aid Flow: Relevant Performance Criteria

article image

The adjustor allowing for a higher ceiling to account for unexpected aid shortfalls changed from 50 percent of the shortfall to a fixed $50 million cap in June 2001. This cap was raised to $75 million in March 2002.

The performance criteria were changed from reserve money to net domestic assets in June 2001. Reserve money became an indicative target.

The adjustor allowing for a lower floor to account for unexpected aid shortfalls changed from 50 percent of the shortfall to a fixed $50 million in June 2001. This limit was raised to $75 million in March 2002. Aid shortfalls could therefore only be partly financed by drawing down reserves.

Excludes grants and foreign-financed capital expenditure.

In 2001, IMF staff supported the Ghanaian monetary authorities’ strategy, advising that aid flows be used to support the currency as a way to curb inflation. The IMF-supported program specified a floor for the accumulation of net international reserves (NIR) and a ceiling for central bank net domestic assets (NDA). Both targets were generally met in 2001, except that NDA targets were waived as money demand increased more than what was forecast, while inflation eased.

As the aid shortfall hit in 2002, monetary policy was eased. The fiscal contraction was less than the aid decline, and the government borrowed directly from the central bank to partly cover the resulting financing gap. There was little sterilization of these liquidity injections during this period, either domestically or in terms of foreign exchange, as reserves continued to be accumulated. In part, reserve accumulation was programmed, because import cover at the start of 2002 remained fairly low (at just 2.3 months). The nominal exchange rate depreciation accelerated and inflation began to pick up by the end of 2002.6

The monetary and fiscal targets under the IMF-supported program were overshot by the end of 2002. These slippages prevented the IMF’s Executive Board from completing the final review of the 2002 PRGF-supported program.7 Reserve floors under the program were exceeded, however. Thus, the program left substantial room to sell reserves; indeed, reserves ended the year $80 million above the adjusted program floor. Selling some reserves would have reduced monetary expansion without requiring further contraction of domestic credit by the central bank.8

In 2003, the authorities faced a need to stabilize. One approach might have been to sell some reserves to reduce money growth and stabilize the exchange rate. The authorities in fact steadily reduced the rate of nominal exchange rate depreciation, contributing to the inflation stabilization. However, the authorities could have made more aggressive use of foreign exchange sales. Instead, as discussed above, the authorities continued to accumulate more reserves. One motivation, emphasized earlier, was the need to create a buffer for volatile aid flows. A desire to keep the real exchange rate from appreciating may have also played a role, however, as the authorities actually bought reserves in the foreign exchange market and accumulated more than would be implied by the aid jump.

To reduce inflation, the authorities conducted policy through domestic monetary operations, selling treasury bills for local currency and increasing reserve requirements for domestic banks to reduce money supply growth and raise interest rates. In the event, inflation fell to less than 5 percent on a six-month annualized basis by the end of 2003.

IMF staff urged the authorities to avoid further reserve accumulation and once again use the aid to allow the currency to adjust, in order to slow the pace of monetary expansion, restrain inflation expectations, and avoid the crowding-out effects of domestic sterilization. Reserve accumulation exceeded the program floor by $310 million, approximately $200 million more than the positive aid surprise. Despite this, high-powered money was just 7 percent above its indicative target as a result of the aggressive domestic monetary tightening.

The potential costs of domestic sterilization were twofold: the possible effect on private investment and the quasi-fiscal costs of the higher domestic debt level. Excluding the early part of the year, when petrol prices affected inflation, real interest rates in Ghana tended to rise from already high levels in 2003 (Figure 4.4). Private investment remained stable, at about 14 percent of GDP. Meanwhile, domestic debt remained high, at 20 percent of GDP, and with interest rates high, domestic debt service continued to absorb 5 percent of GDP, or 17 percent of total public expenditure.

Figure 4.4.
Figure 4.4.

Ghana: Real Treasury Bill Rates Using Annualized Quarterly Inflation

(In percent)

Note: Shaded area denotes the aid-surge period.

One aim of policy over this period was to reduce the domestic debt burden in order to lower real rates, stimulate private investment, and reduce the burden of domestic interest payments on the budget. A number of factors supported higher private investment after 2001, including improving terms of trade, recovering GDP growth, and fiscal consolidation.9 It is possible that the domestic sterilization policy may have kept real interest rates higher, the domestic debt burden higher, and private investment lower than otherwise would have been the case (Table 4.5). While some of this may have been appropriate in view of the need to reduce inflation, a more aggressive use of aid—via sales of foreign exchange—may have mitigated some of these problems.

Table 4.5.

Ghana: Monetary Conditions

(In millions of cedis, except where indicated)

article image

Ghana: Terms-of-Trade Shocks and Aid Inflows

The table below illustrates the relative importance of net aid flows, private flows, and the trade balance for overall foreign exchange flows to Ghana between 1998 and 2003. Three commodities dominate the terms of trade: gold and cocoa exports, and oil imports. Price volatility in these commodities can greatly influence the flow of foreign exchange into the economy.

In 1996, two commodities, gold and cocoa, accounted for roughly equal shares of 74 percent of exports; by 2003, this had declined modestly to roughly equal shares of 64 percent (i.e., one-third each). Price independence provides some diversification (the correlation of annual price changes of the two commodities since 1996 is not significantly different from zero), but overall exposure to prices remains high. Between 10 and 20 percent of imports are accounted for by oil.

In 2000, Ghana suffered a large negative terms-of-trade shock that amplified the impact of the aid decline. During 2001–03, terms-of-trade effects were not as large as aid movements but were still important. In 2002, they offset some of the decline, and in 2003 they moved in the same direction as the large jump in aid, driven largely by export price increases.

Net Aid and Terms-of-Trade Effects

(In millions of U.S. dollars)

article image

Conclusions

Ghana avoided real exchange rate appreciation and Dutch disease during a three-year period when aid flows were 4.4 percentage points of GDP higher than during the previous five years. This cannot be attributed to offsetting exogenous forces, as Ghana’s terms of trade improved and private inflows rose significantly during the same period. Rather, the fact that Ghana effectively saved all of the aid and prevented it from having a cumulative impact on the economy explains the lack of a real exchange rate effect.

The aid inflows and Ghana’s policy response differed in each of the three years:

  • In 2001, aid inflows jumped unexpectedly. Fiscal policy was restrained, in keeping with the IMF-supported program, which did not allow spending of aid surprises. Much of the extra aid was absorbed in that it was sold in the foreign exchange market, putting this episode in the category of aid mostly absorbed but not spent. The sale of foreign exchange and associated policies allowed the exchange rate to stabilize and inflation to fall.

  • In 2002, aid inflows fell just as unexpectedly. Fiscal policy contracted, but not proportionally, leaving a net increase in domestic financing of the deficit. Reserves were further accumulated, in excess of the actual aid flows. The combined impact of the less-than-full fiscal adjustment and the accumulation of reserves was a loose monetary policy that contributed to an increase in inflation by the end of 2002.

  • In 2003, aid again surged unexpectedly. This time, the authorities more than accumulated the jump in reserves and avoided any increase in the fiscal deficit before grants. Aid was neither absorbed nor spent. Inflation was stabilized, in part through the sale of government paper that contracted the money supply, which contributed to high interest rates and a large stock of domestic public debt. The authorities did not take the opportunity to stabilize through more aggressive foreign exchange sales, a more appreciated real exchange rate, and a reduction in the level of domestic public debt.

A number of conclusions emerge. First, why did policymakers limit the impact of aid on the economy? The answer does not seem to lie in the strictures of the IMF-supported program. Most notably, the lack of fiscal and exchange rate reaction to the 2003 aid inflow expansion cannot be ascribed to program fiscal and reserve accumulation targets.

Part of the reason for the reserve accumulation was presumably Ghana’s desire to rebuild reserves from low levels. And part of the reason for the lack of proportionate increase in the fiscal deficit was a desire to “crowd in,” that is, to reduce the large stock of domestic public debt that had led to high real interest rates and incurred large interest costs for the budget.

However, these explanations are perhaps not the full story. The clearest indication of this is that IMF floors for reserve accumulation and ceilings on domestic financing of the deficit were substantially exceeded in 2003. In addition to the above motivations, the policy may have reflected a desire to avoid real exchange rate appreciation. However, there is little direct evidence on this point.

Aid volatility—particularly unexpected and large swings—has contributed to Ghana’s policy difficulties and, most likely, to the authorities’ caution in spending the 2003 aid surge. The volatility of aid carried other costs as well. It is surely more difficult to revert to a given level of expenditure after an increase than to simply maintain the current level of spending. In this sense, the volatility in 2001–02 contributed to the fiscal, and then monetary, policy relaxation, and to high inflation in 2002. Moreover, recurrent expenditures appear to have been harder to restrain than capital spending during the 2002 downturn. This implies that spending the aid as it arrives could help reduce the share of capital expenditures over time. Recent improvements in donor coordination in Ghana should help limit the volatility of aid flows in the future.10

IMF-supported program targets, with their asymmetric adjustors, may significantly affect how aid surprises are absorbed. The system of adjustors in Ghana was, in part, designed to reduce the risks of excessive public domestic borrowing and facilitate crowding in. With these objectives in mind, although the asymmetric adjustors may have appeared excessively tight ex ante, in the event, they turned out to be useful. Had the aid jump of 2001 been fully spent, the collapse of 2002 would have been even harder to manage.11 Had the effect of the aid collapse on policy been fully smoothed by domestic borrowing, the public debt stock would have risen from already high levels, while the emerging inflation problem of 2003 would have been worse.

1

An earlier version of this chapter appears in Isard and others (2006).

2

The real exchange rate versus the U.S. dollar appreciated by roughly 10 percent, mainly when the dollar began to broadly depreciate.

3

This was driven by a $307 million narrowing in the trade balance, plus an $80 million rise in private transfers, largely made up of remittances.

4

In one sense, some of the aid could be said to have been absorbed, with the terms-of-trade-related increase in export proceeds going into reserves. However, the terms-of-trade effect simply means that it would have taken a larger real exchange rate appreciation to absorb the aid than otherwise.

5

Compounding the effect of the terms-of-trade shock was a decline in net aid inflows of 0.3 percent of GDP, as against IMF staff expectations of a 5.8 percent of GDP increase in aid flows in 2000 (Table 4.1).

6

In early 2003, inflation pressures were exacerbated by one-off petroleum price hikes linked to the removal of subsidies.

7

It would seem unlikely that this event contributed much to the shortfall in aid, which had already mostly emerged by then.

8

The monetary performance criterion was changed from reserve money to net domestic assets in June 2001. Reserve money became an indicative target.

9

Private investment is only an estimate, constructed by IMF staff, and therefore any inference about its level or change needs to be treated with appropriate caution. Ghana’s Statistics Service does not produce expenditure components of GDP.

10

The government takes the overall lead in coordinating external assistance and has introduced a “mini-Consultative Group” process, in which it meets with external partners on a quarterly basis. The World Bank has stepped back from its traditional role to leave scope for the government to lead external partner coordination.

11

The assumption is that the aid collapse of 2002 was not a result of donor or recipient dissatisfaction with the partial failure to spend the aid in 2001.

Cited By

  • Collapse
  • Expand
Lessons from Recent Experience
  • Figure 4.1.

    Ghana: Aid Flows and Public Expenditure Patterns

    (In percent of GDP)

  • Figure 4.2.

    Ghana: Performance Against Domestic Financing Targets

    (In billions of cedis)

  • Figure 4.3.

    Ghana: Exchange Rates, Inflation, and Aid Flows

    (In percent annual change)

  • Figure 4.4.

    Ghana: Real Treasury Bill Rates Using Annualized Quarterly Inflation

    (In percent)

  • Acemoglu, Daron, Simon Johnson, James Robinson and Yungyung Thaicharoen, 2003, “Institutional Causes, Macroeconomic Symptoms: Volatility, Crises and Growth,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 50 (January), pp. 12531.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Adam, Christopher, 2001, “Uganda: Exchange Rate Management, Monetary Policy and Aid” (unpublished; Bank of Uganda/UK Department for International Development).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Adam, Christopher, and David L. Bevan, 2003, “Aid, Public Expenditure and Dutch Disease,” Center for the Study of African Economies Working Paper No. 2003–02 (February).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Adam, Christopher, Stephen O’Connell, Edward Buffie, and Catherine Pattillo, 2006, “Monetary Policy Responses to Aid Surges in Africa,” paper presented at the UNU-Wider Conference on Aid: Principles, Policies and Performance, Helsinki, June 16–17.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Adenauer, Isabelle, and Laurence Vagassky, 1998, “Aid and the Real Exchange Rate: Dutch Disease Effects in African Countries,” Intereconomics: Review of International Trade and Development, Vol. 33 (July/August), pp. 17785.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Adler, John H., 1965, “Absorptive Capacity: The Concept and its Determinants,” Brookings Institute Staff Paper (Washington: Brookings Institution).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Agenor, Pierre-Richard, Nihal Bayraktar, and Karim El Aynaoui, 2005, “Roads Out of Poverty? Assessing the Links Between Aid, Public Investment, Growth and Poverty Reduction,” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 3490 (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Arellano, Cristina, Aleš Bulíř, Timothy Lane, and Leslie Lipschitz, 2005, “The Dynamic Implications of Foreign Aid and Its Variability,” IMF Working Paper No. 05/119 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Berg, Andrew, and Anne Krueger, 2003, “Trade, Growth and Poverty: A Selective Study,” IMF Working Paper No. 03/30 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Berg, Andrew, Philippe Karam, and Douglas Laxton, 2006, “Practical Model-Based Monetary Policy Analysis: A How-To Guide,” IMF Working Paper No. 06/81 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Berg, Elliot, 1961, “Backward Sloping Labor Supply Functions in Dual Economies: The Africa Case,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 3, pp. 46892.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Berg, Elliot, 1983, “Absorptive Capacity in the Sahel Countries,” Report to the Club Du Sahel (Paris: Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bevan, David L., 2005, “An Analytic Overview of Aid Absorption: Recognizing and Avoiding Macroeconomic Hazards,” paper presented at the Seminar on Foreign Aid and Macroeconomic Management, Maputo, Mozambique, March 14–15.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Blanchard, Olivier, and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki, 1987, “Monopolistic Competition and the Effects of Aggregate Demand,” American Economic Review, Vol. 77, pp. 64766.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bourguignon, François, Hans Lofgren, Maurizio Bussolo, Hans Timmer, and Dominique van der Mensbrugghe, 2005, “Building Absorptive Capacity to Meet the MDGs” (unpublished; Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Buffie, Edward, Christopher S. Adam, Stephen O’Connell, and Catherine Pattillo, 2004, “Exchange Rate Policy and the Management of Official and Private Capital Flows in Africa,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 51, Special Issue.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bulíř, Aleš, and Javier Hamann, forthcoming, “Volatility of Development Aid: From the Frying Pan into the Fire?IMF Working Paper (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Calvo, Guillermo, 1983, “Staggered Prices in a Utility Maximizing Framework,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 12, pp. 38398.

  • Carroll, Christopher, 2001, “Death to the Log-Linearized Consumption Euler Equation! And Very Poor Health to the Second-Order Approximation,” Advances in Macroeconomics, Vol. 1, No. 1.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Celasun, Oya, and Jan Walliser, 2005, “Predictability of Budget Aid: Experiences in Eight African Countries,” paper prepared for the World Bank Practitioners’ Forum on Budget Support, May, Cape Town, South Africa.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Chowdhury A., and T. Mckinley, 2006, “Gearing Macroeconomic Policies to Manage Large Inflows of ODA: Implications for HIV/AIDS Programmes,” International Poverty Center Working Paper No. 17.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Clemens, Michael, Steven Radelet, and Rikhil Bhavnani, 2004, “Counting Chickens When they Hatch: The Short-Term Effect of Aid on Growth,” Center for Global Development Working Paper 44 (Washington: Center for Global Development).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Clement, Jean A.P., 2005, Postconflict Economics in Sub-Saharan Africa, Lessons from the Democratic Republic of the Congo (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Deninger, K., and J. Okidi, 2001, “Rural Households: Incomes, Productivity and Nonfarm Enterprises,” in Uganda’s Recovery: The Role of Farms, Firms and Government, ed. by R. Reinikka and P. Collier (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Easterly, William, Ross Levin, and David Roodman, 2003, “New Data, New Doubts: A Comment on Burnside’s and Dollar’s ‘Aid, Policies and Growth’,” NBER Working Paper No. 9846 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Elbadawi, Ibrahim A., 1999, “External Aid: Help or Hindrance to Export Orientation in Africa?Journal of African Economies, Vol. 8, No. 4, pp. 578616.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Elbadawi, Ibrahim A., 2002, “Real Exchange Rate Policy and Non-Traditional Exports in Developing Countriesin Non-Traditional Export Promotion in Africa: Experience and Issues, ed. by Gerald Helleiner (New York: Palgrave).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fanizza, Domenico, 2001, “Foreign Aid, Macroeconomic Stabilization, and Growth in Malawi,” IMF Seminar Series No. 07 (January), pp. 121 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Foster, Mick, and Tony Killick, 2006, “What Would Doubling Aid do for Macroeconomic Management in Africa?ODI Working Paper 264 (London: Overseas Development Institute).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gapen, Michael T., and Thomas F. Cosimano, 2005, “Solving Ramsey Problems with Nonlinear Projection Methods,” Studies in Nonlinear Dynamics and Econometrics, Vol. 9, No. 2.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Guillaumont, Patrick, 1971, L’absorption du Capital (Paris: Cujas).

  • Guillaumont, Patrick, and Lisa Chauvet, 2001, “Aid and Performance: A Reassessment,” Journal of Development Studies, Vol. 37, No. 6 (August), pp. 6692.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gupta, Sanjeev, Benedict Clements, Alexander Pivovarsky, Erwin R. Tiongson, 2003, “Foreign Aid and Revenue Response: Does the Composition of Aid Matter?IMF Working Paper No. 03/176 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gupta, Sanjeev, Robert Powell, and Yongzheng Yang, 2005, “The Macroeconomic Challenges of Scaling Up Aid to Africa,” IMF Working Paper No. 05/179 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hausmann, Ricardo, Lant Pritchett, and Dani Rodrik, 2004, “Growth Accelerations,” NBER Working Paper No.10566 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Heller, Peter, 2005, “Pity the Finance Minister: Issues in Managing a Substantial Scaling Up of Aid Flows,” IMF Working Paper No. 05/180 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Heller, Peter, and Sanjeev Gupta, 2002, “Challenges in Expanding Development Assistance,” IMF Policy Discussion Paper 02/5 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, 2003a, “Fund Assistance for Countries Facing Exogenous Shocks” (unpublished; Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, 2003b, “Tanzania—Financial System Stability Assessment” (unpublished; Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, 2004, “The Federal Democratic Republic of Ethiopia—Ex Post Assessment of Long-Term Fund Engagement” (unpublished; Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, 2005a, “The Macroeconomics of Managing High Aid Inflows,” IMF Policy Paper (August). Available via the Internet: http://www.imf.org/external/np/pp/eng/2005/080805a.pdf.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, 2005b, “Update on the Assessments and Implementation of Action Plans to Strengthen Capacity of HIPCs to Track Poverty-Reducing Public Spending” (unpublished; Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, 2006, “United Republic of Tanzania—Ex Post Assessment of Longer-Term Program Engagement” (unpublished; Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund Independent Evaluation Office, 2004, “Evaluation of the IMF’s Role in Poverty Reduction Strategy Papers (PRSPs) and the Poverty Reduction and Growth Facility (PRGF)” (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Isard, Peter, Leslie Lipschitz, Alexandros Mourmouras, and Boriana Yontcheva, eds., 2006, The Macroeconomic Management of Foreign Aid: Opportunities and Pitfalls (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kappel, R., J. Lay, and S. Steiner, 2005, “Uganda: No More Pro-Poor Growth?Development Policy Review, Vol. 23, No. 1.

  • Keynes, John Maynard, 1929, “The German Transfer Problem,” Economic Journal, Vol. 39 (March), pp. 17.

  • Kim, Jinill, and Sunghyun Henry Kim, 2003, “Spurious Welfare Reversals in International Business Cycle Models,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 60, Issue 2 (August), pp. 471500.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Klein, Michael, and Tim Harford, 2005, The Market for Aid (Washington: World Bank).

  • Leite, Carlos, and Charalambos Tsangarides, forthcoming, “Infrastructure for Developing Countries: The Growth Pill?IMF Working Paper (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • McGillivray, Mark, and Oliver Morrissey, 2001, “Fiscal Effects of Aid,” WIDER Discussion Paper 2001/61 (August), (Helsinki: World Institute for Development Economics Research, United Nations University).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Milesi-Ferretti, Gian Maria, and Philip R. Lane, 2004, “The Transfer Problem Revisited: Net Foreign Assets and Real Exchange Rates,” Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 86 (November), No. 4, pp. 84157.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Miranda, Mario J. and Paul L. Fackler, 2002, Applied Computational Economics and Finance (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press).

  • Mohanty, M.S., and Philip Turner, 2006, “The Global Economy and Africa: The Challenges of Increased Financial Inflows,” paper presented at conference on Central Banks and the Challenge of Development, Bank for International Settlements, Basel, March 14–15. Available via the Internet: http://www.bis.org/events/cbcd06.htm.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Nkusu, Mwanza, 2004a, “Aid and Dutch Disease in Low-Income Countries: Informed Diagnosis for Prudent Prognoses,” IMF Working Paper No. 04/49 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Nkusu, Mwanza, 2004b, “Financing Uganda’s Poverty Reduction Strategy: Is Aid Causing More Pain Than Gain?IMF Working Paper No. 04/170 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Nyoni, Timothy S., 1998, “Foreign Aid and Economic Performance in Tanzania,” World Development, Vol. 26, No. 7, pp. 1235240.

  • Obstfeld, Maurice, and Kenneth Rogoff, 1995, “Exchange Rate Dynamics Redux,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 103 (June), pp. 62460.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • O’Connell, Stephen A., Christopher Adam, Edward F. Buffie, and Catherine A. Pattillo, 2006, “Managing External Volatility: Central Bank Options in Low-Income Countries,” in Monetary Policy in Emerging Markets and Other Developing Countries, ed. by Nicoletta Batini (Hauppauge, New York: Nova Science Publishers).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ogun, Oluremi, 1995, “Real Exchange Rate Movements and Export Growth: Nigeria, 1960-1990” (unpublished; Nairobi: African Economic Research Consortium).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ouattara, Bazoumana, and Eric Strobl, 2003, “Do Aid Inflows Cause Dutch Disease? A Case Study of the CFA Franc Countries Using Dynamic Panel Analysis,” Manchester University School of Economics Discussion Paper Series No. 0330 (Manchester, UK: Manchester University).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Prati, Alessandro, and Thierry Tressel, 2005, “What Monetary Policy for Aid-Receiving Countries?Paper presented at the DESAA Development Forum on Integrating Economic and Social Policies to Achieve the United Nations Development Agenda, March 14–15.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Rajan, Raghuram, and Arvind Subramanian, 2005a, “What Undermines Aid’s Impact on Growth?IMF Working Paper No. 05/126 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Rajan, Raghuram, and Arvind Subramanian, 2005b, “Aid and Growth: What Does the Cross-Country Evidence Really Show?IMF Working Paper No. 05/127 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Sackey, Harry A., 2001, “External Aid Inflows and the Real Exchange Rate in Ghana,” AERC Paper No. 110 (November) (Nairobi: African Economic Research Consortium).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Sekkat, Khalid, and Aristomene Varoudakis, 2000, “Exchange Rate Management and Manufactured Exports in Sub-Saharan Africa,” Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 61, No. 1, pp. 23753.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Selassie, Abebe A., Benedict Clements, Shamsuddin Tareq, Jan Kees Martijn, and Gabriel Di Bella, 2006, Designing Monetary and Fiscal Policy in Low-Income Countries, IMF Occasional Paper No. 250 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Torvik, Ragnar, 2001, “Learning by Doing and the Dutch Disease,” European Economic Review, Vol. 45, No. 2, pp. 285306.

  • United Nations, 2006, “Dealing with the Macroeconomic Impact of the Scaling up of Aid,” background paper for a conference of African ministers of finance entitled “Financing for Development: From Commitment to Action,” May 21–22, Abuja, Nigeria. Available via the Internet: http://www.financingmdgsconference.org/session_papers.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • United Nations Millennium Project, 2005, Investing in Development: A Practical Plan to Achieve the Millennium Development Goals (New York: United Nations Development Program).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • White, Howard, and Ganeshan Wignaraja, 1992, “Exchange Rates, Trade Liberalization and Aid: The Sri Lankan Experience,” World Development, Vol. 20, No. 10 (October), pp. 1471480.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • World Bank and International Monetary Fund, 2005, Global Monitoring Report—MDGs: From Consensus to Momentum (Washington: World Bank and International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation