IV Understanding Persistent Regional Disparities in Unemployment
Author:
Mr. Philippe Egoume Bossogo
Search for other papers by Mr. Philippe Egoume Bossogo in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
,
Mr. Jerald A Schiff
Search for other papers by Mr. Jerald A Schiff in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
,
Ms. Miho Ihara
Search for other papers by Ms. Miho Ihara in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
,
Mr. Tetsuya Konuki
Search for other papers by Mr. Tetsuya Konuki in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
, and
Ms. Kornelia Krajnyak
Search for other papers by Ms. Kornelia Krajnyak in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close

Abstract

Labor market performance not only varies across transition countries, but also across regions within a country, and such regional differences are substantial.

Labor market performance not only varies across transition countries, but also across regions within a country, and such regional differences are substantial.

Differences in Labor Market Performance: An Overview

For most transition countries, the unemployment rate in the highest-unemployment NUTS2 region exceeds that in the lowest by 10 to 20 percentage points.19 The picture is similar for participation rates as well as the incidence of long-term unemployment. Although such differences are not out of line with the experience of EU–15 countries, they appear to be at the high end, comparable to Belgium or Spain (Figure 4.1). In addition, the differences are persistent—for example, the ranking of regions with respect to unemployment rates tended to remain unchanged in 1995–2001 within each country, with increasing or stable dispersion.

Figure 4.1.
Figure 4.1.

Unemployment and Its Regional Dispersion1

Source: Eurostat and IMF staff calculations.1 Regional dispersion is the difference between maximum and minimum unemployment rates in regions.

These persistent disparities are a cause for concern. First, the ossification of pockets of high-unemployment may contribute to higher aggregate unemployment. Unemployed workers in areas with depressed labor markets are at high risk of losing their labor market attachment. Persistently poor job prospects may weaken motivation to update skills. As a result, a portion of the labor force may become unemployable. Second, job search intensity and labor market participation rates may decline. And third, regional fragmentation of the labor market may weaken social cohesion, making needed structural reforms more difficult to implement.

What causes these regional disparities? A full explanation is unlikely to be provided by institutional factors discussed in previous chapters. Arguably, regions of the same country are at roughly the same stage of economic transition, share the same institutional and legal infrastructure,20 and are exposed to largely the same policy shocks. At least part of the answer should, therefore, lie elsewhere. This Section explores—by building on the existing empirical literature that mostly covers Hungary and the Czech Republic, as well as on the insights from two simple, stylized models—what other factors may contribute to the emergence and persistence of the regional variation in labor market performance.

The origins of regional differences in unemployment are likely to be found in transition-related shocks. Many of these shocks were related to sudden relative price changes and therefore had significant industry specific components. This in turn translated into initial regional differences in unemployment. In addition, ongoing structural change—for example, due to second and third rounds of restructuring in heavy industry and mining—may have contributed to widening regional unemployment differentials even at later stages of transition. To illustrate this, Figure 4.2 plots the level and change in unemployment against a measure of structural change in 1998–99 for transition countries and transition country regions.21 Changes in industry structure and unemployment indeed appear to be positively correlated. However, transition-related shocks would need to be very particular—recurring in certain regions but not in others—in order to explain fully the observed pattern of persistent regional differences in unemployment.

Figure 4.2.
Figure 4.2.

Unemployment and Structural Change

(In percent)

Sources: Eurosatc; and IMF staff calculations.

A fuller explanation of persistent regional disparities could rely on a long list of factors. Among the possibilities that have been put forth are the following:

  • Inadequate wage flexibility. If wages are not sufficiently flexible downward—because the minimum wage is binding, or because centrally negotiated wage demands are excessive for high-unemployment regions—the brunt of labor market adjustment in response to a negative regional shock will occur through reduced employment. Inadequate wage flexibility also prolongs the period necessary for increased unemployment to dissipate.

  • High benefits. If the difference between labor and benefit income is small or negative, workers will voluntarily become unemployed, will have minimal incentive for job search and improving skills, and may drop out of the labor market altogether. For practical reasons, benefit payments usually do not take into account regional variation in wage and price levels;22 hence, these effects may be especially strong in distressed regions, and differences in unemployment and participation rates may persist.

  • Limited factor mobility. Movement of workers and jobs can help even out differences in regional labor markets. However, the equalizing process may slow or halt if factor mobility is impeded. Examples of impediments include the limited transferability of certain assets—such as housing—labor market segmentation, high transportation costs, regional differences in physical or business infrastructure endowments, and the emergence of agglomeration externalities.

There is little evidence to support the notion that wages across regions are particularly inflexible in transition economies (Table 4.1). In contrast to a number of EU–15 countries—for example, Belgium or Italy—with national wage bargaining systems, wage setting is typically local,23 and regional wage differentials can be substantial. For example, Kertesi and Köllő (1999) report a 30 percent gap between the wages of comparable workers in Hungary’s highest and lowest unemployment regions; similar differences are observed in other countries. However, with large regional productivity differentials, a nationally set minimum wage may contribute to inadequate wage flexibility at the low end of the wage distribution, particularly in low-productivity, high-unemployment regions.

Table 4.1

Basic Indicators, Hungarian and Czech Regions

article image
Sources: Czech and Hungarian statistical offices; and Köllö (2001).

In percent of country average.

Of course, some of this difference reflects the regional labor market situation. A frequently used measure of wage flexibility is the responsiveness of individual wages to regional unemployment, or the slope of the wage curve (Blanchflower and Oswald, 1994). In mature economies, typical estimates of the elasticity of wages with respect to regional unemployment are around −0.1, implying that a doubling of the regional unemployment rate is associated with a 10 percent fall in wages. Estimates for transition countries by Blanchflower (2001) and others24 indicate that the responsiveness of wages to regional unemployment is at this level or even higher. In addition, nonparticipation tends to be very high in high-unemployment, low-wage regions—including because subsistence activity may generate income levels comparable to employment, or because outdated or insufficient skills and the scarcity of jobs owing to large regional capital destruction discourage workers.25 If these factors are relevant, further falls in wages alone are unlikely to markedly improve the labor market situation in high-unemployment regions.

Can high benefits be blamed? The empirical evidence here is mixed. As noted above, unemployment benefits are generally not high in transition economies. Further, for Hungary, Köllő (2001) finds no difference in the job-finding probability of unemployed with and without benefits. In the same vein, workers leaving unemployment appear to take larger wage cuts compared with their previous wages in depressed regions—that is, the reservation wage appears to decline with regional unemployment.26 If relatively high benefits kept the reservation wage high, we would observe the opposite: job-finding unemployed would accept smaller wage cuts in high-benefit regions. On the other hand, social or family benefits may give rise to welfare traps for specific demographic groups—for example, low-wage families with several children.27 For these workers, benefits may exceed their likely wages, and unemployment or nonparticipation may be an appealing option.

While migration of workers could reduce regional unemployment differentials, it appears that this mechanism is not particularly strong or speedy. Workers in transition countries appear even less willing to migrate than their Western European counterparts. Cseres-Gergely (2002) reports that annual gross migration between Hungarian regions is, at about 2 percent of the population, comparable to Swedish or Dutch internal migration, but migration flows are only half this large or smaller for the Czech Republic, the Slovak Republic, and Poland. Fidrmuc (2002) estimates that, despite large regional differentials in unemployment rates and wages, migration flows induced by such variations in regional labor market conditions are less important in the Czech Republic, Slovak Republic, Hungary, and Poland than they are in Italy or Portugal. Migration appears to respond to economic incentives—people tend to move from high-unemployment, low-wage regions to more prosperous ones (Fidrmuc, 2002; Cseres-Gergely, 2002; Fidrmuc and Huber, 2003). But so few people move that migration is unlikely to eliminate regional differences in unemployment rates.

Commuting to work is a possible substitute to migration. With commuting, a change of residence is not necessary to participate in another labor market. In fact, Eurostat data indicate that the frequency of commuting is correlated with regional unemployment (Figure 4.3), with people who reside in depressed regions commuting more. This is consistent with Köllő (2002a), who reports, for Hungary, that about half of those exiting unemployment to employment find work in a settlement other than their primary residence. It appears that commuting may alleviate regional differences in unemployment but is not a strong enough mechanism to narrow them substantially. There appear to be two main obstacles to commuting on a larger scale. First, as (Table 4.2). shows, commuting is expensive—both in money and time reflecting in part poor public transportation28 and transport infrastructure. Second, if the size of the depressed region is large, there may be nowhere to commute to, especially if car ownership is limited (Figure 4.4). For example, the highest-unemployment regions in Hungary appear to be rural regions that are either isolated or are in the neighborhood of a high-unemployment urban center.

Figure 4.3.
Figure 4.3.

Commuting Frequency and Unemployment

(In percent)

Source: Eurostat.1 Excluding Strředni Čhechy region.
Figure 4.4.
Figure 4.4.

Unemployment and Car Ownership, Hungarian Regions, 2002

Source: Hungarian Statistical Office.
Table 4.2.

Indicators of Commuting Costs in Selected Countries1

article image
Source: IMF staff calculations.

Data for 2003 (rail prices) and 2002 (gasoline prices-minimum and average wage).

For distance of about 30 km.

For Hungary, includes employee and employer share.

Capital mobility could also potentially help eliminate regional disparities, but capital appears to favor advantaged regions despite their tighter labor markets. For instance, Fazekas (2003) reports that during 1993–2000, foreign firms increased their employment in the quartile of lowest-unemployment regions in Hungary by 8 percent. In the highest-unemployment quartile, they expanded employment by less than 1 percent. Other indicators also show that high-unemployment regions are not attractive for capital (Table 4.3), and instead of disappearing, the differences between advantaged and disadvantaged regions appear to widen over time.29

Table 4.3.

Indicators of Job Creation by Regional Unemployment Quintiles in Hungary1

article image
Source: Kertesi and Köllő (1999).

From lowest to highest unemployment.

Annual change in the number of firms per thousand population (excluding sole-proprietorships).

Annual change in the number of sole-proprietorships per thousand population.

Percent of workers employed in majority foreign-owned firms.

The chapter focuses on limited factor mobility, with a view to identifying impediments to such mobility and policies that could help mitigate them. Because of data limitations—regional information on a comparable basis across countries is available only for a few variables—we center the analysis around two illustrative models. First, we examine a stylized model of individual labor market behavior, holding capital constant. This provides an opportunity to take a closer look at the individual’s incentives to participate in the local labor market or to move to another region. Next, we look at another simple model to describe how jobs might be allocated across regions and draw attention to factors that might make regions attractive or unattractive for capital. The number and skills of available workers may influence the attractiveness of regions, so that migration and participation decisions may have an effect on job creation.

Labor Mobility: The Individual Worker’s Decision

This section considers the determinants of regional labor supply—workers’ incentives to participate in the local labor market and to move to another region. To simplify the exposition, we focus on the individual’s decisions when facing a fixed labor demand—that is, we abstract from job creation or destruction stemming from capital accumulation or capital decumulation. While labor supply decisions depend broadly on the same factors in transition and mature market economies, some structural features of the economy are likely to have particular importance in transition countries.

  • Regional differences in unemployment rates have been accompanied by a large differentiation in participation rates, but migration flows remained even weaker than in other European countries. To the extent that migration and changes in labor market participation are substitute mechanisms in adjusting to labor market shocks, they should be jointly examined. If “too low” migration rates shift the burden of adjustment to participation rates in transition countries, employment and output will be lower during an adjustment to a negative shock. In transition, tilting the balance toward migration may result in a brighter employment outcome.

  • An inefficient housing market is a possible impediment to mobility. Housing markets are probably more distorted in transition economies than in more developed economies. In many countries, the state-owned housing stock was privatized by selling the apartments to the sitting tenant at low prices, generating very high home ownership rates but keeping the housing market thin (Table 4.4). There is some evidence suggesting that countries with high rates of home ownership tend to have higher unemployment rates (Figure 4.5). The problem is compounded by credit market imperfections—mortgage financing is unlikely to be available without significant collateral, something that migrants from depressed regions are unlikely to offer. Further, the rental market is small, and rent controls and a bias toward tenant rights may be an obstacle for its future development. As a result, moving to a new address is relatively infrequent. For example, while in Sweden, the Netherlands, and the United Kingdom 10–12 percent of the population moves house each year, in Hungary only about 4 percent does so.30

  • Labor market segmentation along dimensions other than regional may be stronger in transition economies than elsewhere in Europe because of more skill heterogeneity. At one extreme is the part of the labor force with skills rendered obsolete by transition. These workers have joined the ranks of the unskilled, who in many cases comprise a larger share of the labor force than in industrial countries (Table 4.5). At the other extreme are young and newly trained individuals with highly marketable skills. Because the skills and work experience of older workers with similar training—obtained before transition—may have been devalued, they may represent another, medium-skill category and compete with the young workers only to a limited degree. Kertesi and Köllő (2003) find evidence that, with the appearance of new technologies, this skill obsolescence for the educated workers took place in Hungary, as “skill appreciation” (an increase in the returns to education) became restricted to younger workers. Jurajda (2004) finds similar evidence of skill obsolescence for the Czech Republic.

  • Subsistence activity is more important in transition economies, and may be a viable substitute to labor mobility or labor market participation. The reasons for this are many. First, a larger gray economy provides more opportunities for the unemployed or those outside the labor force to earn income (monetary or in kind). Second, land or plot ownership is more widespread as a result of land privatization and agricultural reform and the popularity of “dachas.” More people are able to supplement their income with their own agricultural produce. Third, average income levels are much closer to subsistence in transition countries than in industrial countries. For example, calculations by the Romanian Statistical Office indicate that per capita income was significantly lower in households involved in private farming than in employed or unemployed households (about 40 percent and 90 percent, respectively). However, the differences disappear if “in kind” income is also considered.31

Table 4.4.

House Ownership in Selected Countries1

article image
Sources: OECD data; and IMF staff calculations.

For transition countries-data refer to 1999 (share of owner-occupied housing) and 2000 (mortgages); for EU countries-data refer to 1995 and 1998, respectively.

Share of owner-occupied housing in 1997.

“Owner-occupied” includes private rented. In percent of country average.

Table 4.5.

Skill Endowments

article image
Sources: Marin (2004-Table 12); and IMF staff calculations.

Tertiary education. Ratio of people with tertiary education.

Up to second level. Ratio of people up to secondary education.

Weighted by 2003 population.

Figure 4.5.
Figure 4.5.

Unemployment and Home Ownership: Selected European Nations in the 1990s

(In percent)

Source: Oswald (1999).1 Data refer to western Germany.

A stylized model that incorporates these features (Appendix III) is applied to examine the costs and benefits of moving. Workers decide simultaneously whether to move and whether to participate based not only on their expected wages in the two regions, but also on available benefits and subsistence income. An additional consideration for the moving decision is transaction costs (including capital gains and losses) related to selling a house in the home region and buying another one in the target region. The model yields the following conclusions:

  • Migration follows economic incentives: relatively higher wages and lower probability of unemployment in the target region tend to induce individuals to move.

  • However, deteriorating labor market conditions—declining wages or increasing unemployment—may trigger nonparticipation rather than out migration. This can be particularly the case for older workers and suggests that high unemployment regions may end up with a large number of nonparticipating workers who do not have the necessary incentives to migrate.

  • The level of benefits and subsistence income tends to influence participation but has less impact on mobility. Participation may be more strongly influenced by changes in subsistence income than changes in benefits.

  • Imperfections in the housing market—large differences in house prices across regions and/or large transaction costs—bias workers toward staying in their region of origin. This effect is likely to be stronger for older workers, who are more likely to own a house or rent at favorable rates.

  • Migration and participation decisions differ across worker groups with different labor market status. If workers are split between outsiders (those with a weaker labor market position, such as long-term unemployed with few marketable skills) and insiders (those with a strong labor market position—for instance, employed highskill workers), the labor-supply behavior of the two groups will differ. Because of their worse labor market prospects, outsiders are more prone to dropping out of the labor force—they decide not to participate at lower levels of benefits and subsistence income than insiders do. In addition, assuming that insider status is transferred with the worker when he moves to another region, insiders will have a higher propensity to move. Outsiders will tend to drop out of the labor force rather than move to another region.

These conclusions suggest that labor mobility should not necessarily be relied on to address persistent high regional unemployment. Rather, they point to the possibility that high-unemployment regions could move toward low participation, with older and lower-skilled potential workers remaining at home, and others moving to more favored regions.

Job Mobility: The Firm’s Decision

Having considered short-term determinants of regional labor supply, this section examines factors that are likely to influence regional labor demand. When thinking over the factors influencing the firm’s location decision—incentives for or deterrents to regional investment and job creation—four stylized facts that can be gleaned from the literature need to be considered.

  • Although cheap labor can help attract capital, direct cost factors appear to be a relatively unimportant motive, at least for foreign direct investment. A survey of Austrian investors (Table 4.6), for example, shows labor costs as distant third to market access and other considerations. Because foreign direct investment inflows are strongly correlated with other indicators of investment and job creation activity, the framework should allow market size to play a role as an incentive for capital flows.

  • Empirical evidence suggests that agglomeration economies influence regional productivity and therefore attractiveness for capital. Wage differentials have tended to widen between the central agglomerations and less densely populated regions in transition economies, owing in part to the tightness of the regional labor markets. However, Kertesi and Köllő (1999) find for Hungary that the main agglomeration’s labor costs declined relative to other regions as its relative productivity increased. Fazekas (2003) also finds quicker productivity growth for foreign direct investment firms that settled in the advantaged low-unemployment regions.

  • Third, a region’s location appears to matter both for its ability to attract capital and its labor market performance. (Table 4.7) illustrates this for the case of Hungary. The capital and the regions close to the EU–15 border (those listed in italics in Table 4.7) tend to do much better along both dimensions. Similar location effects are observable in the Czech Republic and Slovak Republic, suggesting that proximity to large markets and low transportation costs are a factor in capital’s location decision.

  • Last, regional unemployment rates and investment (particularly foreign direct investment) activity are negatively correlated (Tables 4.3 and 4.7). This confirms the idea that the performance of regional labor markets is strongly related to the region’s ability to attract businesses and foster job creation.

Table 4.6.

Motivation of Austrian Outward Direct Investors-End-1999

article image
Source: Oesterreichische National bank, “Austrian Outward and Inward Direct Investment at the End of 1999” (Focus on Austria 2/2001), Table 10.1.

EU–11 refers to: Austria, Belgium, Denmark, France, Germany, Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg, the Netherlands, Portugal, and Spain.

Table 4.7.

Unemployment Rate and the FDI Sector’s Share in the Corporate Sector’s Employment in Hungarian Regions1

(In percent)

article image
Sources: Eurostat; and Fazekas (2000-Table 2).

FDI: foreign direct investment.

Central agglomeration.

Western border.

A “new economic geography” model provides an analytical framework for examining firm location decisions. Puga (1999) explains the location of manufacturing as a function of the strength of agglomeration and dispersion forces. Similarly to Krugman and Venables (1995), manufacturing firms generate demand for other firms’ output, which makes “bunching” of firms advantageous. At the same time, however, transportation costs and the limited availability of labor in regions tend to induce firms to spread across regions. More precisely, agglomeration of manufacturing is promoted by two effects. The first is demand linkages. In a region where many firms are located, demand for manufactured goods is higher, since the manufacturing sector itself generates demand for its own product as an intermediate input. The second is cost linkages. If many firms are located in the same region, intermediate inputs for a new firm are cheaper, since the prices of locally supplied varieties are not augmented by transport costs. If nothing else were at work, these forces—demand and cost linkages—would cause manufacturing to concentrate in one region. However, a larger number of firms means stronger competition. If a larger share of the demand for manufactures is satisfied by local production, the average price of manufactures is lower, forcing individual firms to lower their prices or reduce the scale of production. Second, the presence of many firms generates larger labor demand and pushes up wage costs.

This framework suggests that two types of equilibria can be distinguished: those in which manufacturing spreads across regions, and those with agglomerates in one region. In the first type of equilibrium, agglomeration and dispersion forces balance each other, and firms earn zero profits in both regions. In the second type, all firms concentrate in one region without any incentive to relocate. As transport costs influence the strength of some of the agglomeration and dispersion forces, they also have an effect on the long-run equilibrium, with the relationship between transport costs and agglomeration being Ω–shaped. With very high transport costs, the advantages of producing close to market dominate, most sales occur locally, and manufacturing is dispersed across regions. As transport costs fall, export markets gain in importance, local product market competition weakens as a dispersion force, and manufacturing tends to agglomerate. If transport costs become lower yet, manufacturing starts to spread again, attracted by lower wages and low competition in the deindustrialized regions. In the limit, manufacturing is again fully dispersed, and wages equalize across regions. Under some conditions, multiple equilibria may also arise—regions with a small initial manufacturing base may lose their manufacturing sector altogether, while regions with a critical mass of manufacturing will attract additional firms.

This model suggests that different initial positions may cause regions to diverge over both the short and the long run. We assume that the model economies are characterized by low-to-medium transport costs, and that multiple equilibria are possible.32 In this case, in a region hard-hit by the transition shock, the manufacturing sector and thus the home market may be too small to make production profitable, and firms exit. Manufacturing shrinks, and the region gets caught in a vicious cycle. By contrast, in the lucky region a virtuous cycle operates: profits are positive, new firms enter, and the home market expands. Even if the manufacturing base is large enough in both regions to eventually attract new firms, the lucky region may initially be more successful. Because the manufacturing sector is larger there, agglomeration effects may lead to higher profits. The faster entry of firms to the lucky region may reinforce the differences temporarily, since it strengthens the benefits from agglomeration. But with the entry of more and more firms, keener competition on the product market and factor cost increases start eroding profits. Eventually, the cost advantage of the unlucky region will induce firms to locate there, and the regions start to converge.

The analysis also points to transport costs as a significant factor in a region’s attractiveness. There is a large variation in the density and quality of road and rail networks across transition country regions, and anecdotal evidence suggests that the poor state of transport infrastructure acts as a deterrent to investment. In addition, it may also hinder commuting and further contribute to persistent high unemployment. Having a disadvantage in the area of transport infrastructure may increase the likelihood that a region will see more firm exit or less enthusiastic firm entry compared with a better-provided region, especially if other elements of business infrastructure also compare unfavorably (Figure 4.6). Therefore, offsetting such disadvantages—that is-reducing transport costs where they are particularly high—may increase the chances of eventual regional convergence.

Figure 4.6.
Figure 4.6.

Unemployment and Main Phone Lines, Hungarian Regions, 2002

Source: Hungarian Statistical Office.

The size of the effective labor force may be another important factor in attracting firms. The effective supply of labor not only depends on the number of workers available, but also on their skill. The labor force may shrink more in unlucky regions than in lucky ones, for several reasons. Skill mismatch—that is, a large number of workers with skills appropriate for the outdated industry but not fit for modern manufacturing—is likely to reduce the size of the effective labor force more in the unlucky region. In addition, if the economy shrinks, non, participation may become more attractive, again reducing the size of the labor force and the potential to exploit agglomeration economies. Further, local knowledge spillovers may increase the productivity edge of the region with a large manufacturing base, increasing the likelihood of regional divergence in the size of manufacturing. This points to the potential importance of reducing regional differences in productivity—possibly by ensuring an even level of general education and the preconditions for an adequate skill mix across regions—to help even out differences in regions’ attractiveness to capital and possibly labor market outcomes.

  • Collapse
  • Expand
The Experience of Central and Eastern European Countries
  • Aghion, Philippe, and Lasse Pedersen, Olivier Blanchard, 1994, “On the Speed of Transition in Central Europe,” NBER Working Paper No. 4736 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Resources).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Baker, Dean, Andrew Glyn, David Howell, and John Schmitt, 2002, “Labour Market Institutions and Unemployment: A Critical Assessment of the Case for Deregulation” (New York: MacArthur Foundation and the Center for Economic Policy Analysis of New School University).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Baldwin, Richard E., 1998, “Trade and Growth: Any Unfinished Business?” European Economic Review, Vol. 42, Nos. 3–5, pp. 695703.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Baldwin, Richard E., Rikard Forslid, Philippe Martin, Gianmarco Ottaviano, and Frederic Robert-Nicoud, 2003, Economic Geography and Public Policy (Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Baldwin, Richard, and Philippe Martin, 2003, “Agglomeration and Regional Growth,” CEPR Discussion Paper No. 3960 (London: Centre for Economic Policy Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bilsen, Valentijn, and Jozef Konings, 1996, “Job Creation, Job Destruction, and Growth of Newly Established Private Firms in Transition Economies: Survey Evidence from Bulgaria, Hungary, and Romania,” Working Paper No. 59 (Leuven, Belgium: Leuven Institute for Central and East European Studies).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bisogo, Marcelo, 2002, “Croatian Labor Market in Transition,” background paper for “Croatia: Economic Vulnerability and Welfare Study” No. 59 (unpublished; Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Blanchard, Olivier, 2000a, “The Economics of Unemployment. Shocks, Institutions, and Interactions,” Lionel Robbins Lectures (London: London School of Economics).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Blanchard, Olivier, 2000b, “Employment Protection, Sclerosis, and the Effect of Shocks on Unemployment,” Lionel Robbins Lectures, Lecture 3 (London: London School of Economics).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Blanchard, Olivier, 2002, “Designing Labor Market Institutions,” remarks at the conference “Beyond Transition,” Warsaw, Poland.

  • Blanchard, Olivier, 2004, “Explaining European Unemployment,” Research Summary, NBER Reporter (Summer). Available via the Internet: http://www.nberg.org/reporter/summer04/blanchard.html.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Blanchard, Olivier, and Pedro Portugal, 2004, “What Hides Behind an Unemployment Rate: Comparing Portuguese and U.S. Labor Markets,” American Economic Review (March), pp. 187207.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Blanchard, Olivier, and Justin Wolfers, 2000, “The Role of Shocks and Institutions in the Rise of European Unemployment: The Aggregate Evidence,” Harry Johnson Lecture, Economic Journal, No. 110 (March), pp. 133.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Blanchard, Olivier, and Justin Wolfers, and Michael Kremer, 1997, “Explaining European Unemployment,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 112, No. 4 (November), pp. 10911126.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Blanchard, Olivier, and Justin Wolfers, and Michael Kremer, and Lawrence Katz, 1999, “Wage Dynamics: Reconciling Theory and Evidence,” NBER Working Paper No. 6924 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Blanchflower, David, 2001, “Unemployment, Well-Being, and Wage Curves in Eastern and Central Europe,” Journal of the Japanese and International Economies, Vol. 15, pp. 364402.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Blanchflower, David, and Andrew Oswald, 1994, “The Wage Curve” (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press).

  • Boeri, Tito, 2001, “Transition with Labour Supply,” Discussion Paper (Bonn: Université Bocconi-IGIER; and London: Centre for Economic Policy Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Boeri, Tito, Giuseppe Nicoletti, and Stefano Scarpetta, 2000, “Regulation and Labour Market Performance,” Discussion Paper No. 2420 (London: Centre for Economic Policy Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Brücker, Herbert, and Parvati Trübswetter, 2004, “Do the Best Go West? An Analysis of the Self-Selection of Employed East-West Migrants in Germany,” Discussion Paper No. 986 (Bonn, Germany: Institute for Labor Studies, IZA).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Chadha, Bankim, Fabrizio Coricelli, and Kornélia Krajnyàk, 1993, “Economic Restructuring, Unemployment, and Growth in a Transition Economy,” IMF Working Paper 93/16 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Choueiri, Nada, 2005, “The Labor Market in Poland,” in Republic of Poland: Selected Issues, IMF Country Report No. 05/264 (Washington: International Monetary Fund), pp. 3150.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cseres-Gergely, Zsombor, 2002, “Residential Mobility, Migration, and Economic Incentives—The Case of Hungary in 1990–1999,” Budapest Working Papers on the Labour Market No. 7 (Budapest: University of Economics and Public Administration).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • CSO, Labor Force Survey (Budapest: Hungarian Central Statistical Office).

  • CSO, “Regulation and Labour Market Performance,” Survey on the Number of Employees and Earnings in the National Economy (Budapest: Hungarian Central Statistical Office).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Disney, Richard, 2000, “The Impact of Tax and Welfare Policies on Employment and Unemployment in OECD Countries,” IMF Working Paper No. 00/164 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • ECOSTAT, 2003, ECOSTAT Newsletter 9/2003, 30 September (Budapest: CSO ECOSTAT).Available via the Internet: http://www.ecostat.hu/hirlevel/hirlevel37.html.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Elhorst, Paul, 2000, “The Mystery of Regional Unemployment Differentials: A Survey of Theoretical and Empirical Explanations” IMF Working Paper No. 00/164 (unpublished; Goettingen, Germany).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Erbenova, Michaela, Vit Sorm, and Katherine Terrell, 1998, “Work Incentive and Other Effects of Social Assistance and Unemployment Benefit Policy in the Czech Republic,” Empirical Economics, No. 23, pp. 87120. (unpublished; Goettingen, Germany).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Estevão, Marcello, 2003, “Structural and Cyclical Labor Market Changes in Poland,” in Republic of Poland: Selected Issues, IMF Country Report No. 03/188 (Washington: International Monetary Fund), pp. 1443.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • European Training Foundation, 1999, “Employment and Labor Market in Bulgaria,” Working Document (Torino, Italy, August).

  • Faggio, Giulia, and Jozef Konings, 1998, “Gross Job Flows in Transition Countries: Results from Company Accounts Data for Bulgaria, Estonia, and Romania,” LICOS Centre for Transition Economics Discussion Paper No. 77 (Leuven, Belgium: Katholieke Universiteit Leuven).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Faggio, Giulia, and Jozef Konings,, 2001, “Job Creation, Job Destruction, and Employment Growth in Transition Countries in the 90’s,” LICOS Centre for Transition Economics Discussion Paper No. 242 (Leuven, Belgium: Katholieke Universiteit Leuven).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Farrell, Diana, 2004, “The Hidden Dangers of the Informal Economy,” McKinsey Quarterly, No. 3, pp. 2737 (New York).

  • Fazekas, Károly, 2000, “The Impact of Foreign Direct Investment Inflows on Regional Labor Markets in Hungary,” SOCO Project Paper No. 77c pp. 2737 (Vienna, Austria: Institute for Human Sciences).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fazekas, Kàroly, 2003, “Effects of Foreign Direct Investment on the Performance of Local Labour Markets: The Case of Hungary,” Budapest Working Paper No. 3 (Budapest, Hungary: University of Economics and Public Administration).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fazekas, Kàroly, 2004, Quarterly Labor Market Update (Budapest: Institute of Economics, January).

  • Fidrmuc, Jan, 2002, “Migration and Regional Adjustment to Asymmetric Shocks in Transition Economies,” Center for European Integration Studies (ZEI) (Bonn, Germany: University of Bonn).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fidrmuc, Jan, and Peter Huber, 2003, “On the Puzzle of Rising Regional Disparities and Falling Migration Rates During Transition,” Center for European Integration Studies (ZEI) (Bonn, Germany: University of Bonn).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fischer, Stanley, and Ratna Sahay, 2000, “The Transition Economies After Ten Years,” IMF Working Paper No. 00/30 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fortaleza, Alvaro, and Martín Rama, 2001, “Labor Market Rigidity and the Success of Economic Reforms Across More Than One Hundred Countries,” Vol. 1, WPS No. 2521 (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Francis, John, 2003, “The Declining Costs of International Trade and Unemployment,” Journal of International Trade and Development, Vol. 12, No. 4, pp. 33757.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Galuš,čák, Kamil, and Daniel Münich, 2004, “Regional Wage Adjustments and Unemployment: Estimating the Time-Varying Wage Curve,” Czech National Bank Working Papers (Prague, forthcoming).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Garibaldi, Pietro, Lubomir Dimitrov, and Gabriella Stoyanova, 2000, “The Bulgarian Labor Market: An Overview” (unpublished; Washington: World Bank, February).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • GKI, 2003, “Forecast of GKI Economic Research Co. on Developments in the Hungarian Economy in 2003” (Budapest: GKI Economic Research Co., 29 September). Available via the Internet: http://www.gki.hu/frame.php.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Grogan, Louise, and Luc Moers, 2001, “Growth Empirics with Institutional Measures for Transition Countries,” Economic Systems, No. 28 (Hamilton, Ontario, Canada: McMaster University), pp. 122.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ham, John C., Jan Svejnar, and Katherine Terrell, 1998, “Unemployment and the Social Safety Net During Transitions to a Market Economy: Evidence from the Czech and Slovak Republics,” American Economic Review, Vol. 88, No. 5, pp. 111742.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Helpman, Elhanan, 1997, “The Size of Regions,” in D. Pines, E. Sadka, and I. Zilcha, eds., Topics in Public Economics: Theoretical and Applied Analysis (Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Institute of Economics, 2002, “Croatian Economic Outlook—Quarterly,” No. 9 (Zagreb).

  • International Monetary Fund, 2003, World Economic Outlook (Washington: International Monetary Fund, April).

  • Johnson, Simon, Daniel Kaufmann, and Pablo Zoido-Lobaton, 1998, “Corruption, Public Finances, and the Unofficial Economy” (unpublished; Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Jurajda, štěán, 2005, “Czech Relative Wages and Returns to Schooling: Does the Short Supply of College Education Bite?” Czech Journal of Economics and Finance (Charles University, Prague), Vol. 55 (January), pp. 8395.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Jurajda, štěán, and Daniel Münich, 2002, “Understanding Czech Long-term Unemployment,” William Davidson Institute Working Paper No. 498 (Ann Arbor, Michigan: University of Michigan Business School).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Jurajda, štěán, and Daniel Münich, and Katherine Terrell, 2002, “What Drives the Speed of Job Reallocation During Episodes of Massive Adjustment?” Discussion Paper No. 601 (Bonn, Germany: IZA, October).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kaminski, Bartlomiej, and Michele Riboud, 2000, “Foreign Investment and Restructuring: The Evidence from Hungary,” Technical Paper No. 453 (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kertesi, Gábor, and János Köllő, 1999, “Unemployment, Wage Push, and the Labour Cost Competitiveness of Regions: The Case of Hungary, 1986–96,” Working Papers on the Labour Market No. 5 (Budapest: Institute of Economics, Hungarian Academy of Sciences [HAS]).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kertesi, Gábor, and János Köllő, 2003, “The Employment Effects of Nearly Doubling the Minimum Wage—The Case of Hungary,” Working Papers on the Labour Market No. 6 (Budapest: Institute of Economics, HAS).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Köllő, János, 2001, “The Patterns of Non-Employment in Hungary’s Least Developed Regions,” Working Papers on the Labour Market, No. 1 (Budapest: Institute of Economics, HAS).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Köllő, János, 2002a, “The Role of Commuting Costs in Maintaining Regional Unemployment Differentials—An Attempt at Estimation,” Working Papers on the Labour Market, No. 2 (Budapest: Institute of Economics, HAS).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Köllő, János, 2002b, “Wage-Setting Practices: Some Indirect Observations,” in Fazekas and Koltay, eds., The Hungarian Labor Market (Budapest: Institute of Economics and HAS, Hungarian Employment Foundation).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Köllő, János, and Mária Vincze, 1999, “Self-Employment, Unemployment and Wages: Regional Evidence from Hungary and Romania,” Working Papers on the Labour Market, No. 1 (Budapest: Institute of Economics, HAS).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Krajnyák, Kornélia, and Jeromino Zettelmeyer, 1998, “Competitiveness in Transition Economies: What Scope for Real Appreciation?” IMF Staff Papers, Vol. 45 (June), pp. 30962.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Krugman, Paul, and Anthony Venables, 1995, “Globalization and the Inequality of Nations,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 110, No. 4, pp. 85780.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lindley, J., R. Upward, and P. Wright, 2002, “Regional Mobility and Unemployment Transitions in the UK and Spain,” Research Paper Series, Globalization and Labour Markets Programme, No. 19 (Nottingham, United Kingdom: University of Nottingham).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lubyova, Martina, and Jan van Ours, 1998, “Work Incentives and Other Effects of the Transition to Social Assistance: Evidence from the Slovak Republic,” Empirical Economics, Vol. 23, pp. 12153.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • McCormick, Barry, 1997, “Regional Unemployment and Labour Mobility in the UK,” European Economic Review, Vol. 41, pp. 58189.

  • McHugh, Jimmy, 2002, “Wage Centralization, Union Bargaining, and Macroeconomic Performance,” IMF Working Paper No. 02/143 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Marin, Dalia, 2004, “A Nation of Poets and Thinkers—Less So With Eastern Enlargement? Austria and Germany,” CEPR Discussion Paper No. 4358 (London: Centre for Economic Policy Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Markov, Nikolay, Nasko Dochev, and Rummen Dobrinsky, 2002, “Labor Adjustment, Wage Formation, and Corporate Efficiency in Bulgarian Manufacturing” (Sofia: Centre for Economic and Strategic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Martin, John, and David Grubb, 2001, “What Works and For Whom: A Review of OECD Countries’ Experiences With Active Labor Market Policies,” IFAU Working Paper No. 14 (Uppsala, Sweden: The Institute for Labour Market Policy Evaluation).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ministry of Finance of the Slovak Republic, 2004, “Convergence Program for the Slovak Republic, Covering the Period 2004–2010” (May).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • MNB, Quarterly Inflation Report (Budapest: Hungarian National Bank).Available via the Internet: http://english.mnb.hu/modulei.asp?id=136.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Munich, Daniel, Jan Svejnar, and Katherine Terrell, 1998, “Worker-Firm Matching in Transition Economies,” William Davidson Institute Working Paper No. 107 (Ann Arbor, Michigan: University of Michigan Business School).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Murphy, Kevin M., Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W. Vishny, 1992, “The Transition to a Market Economy: Pitfalls of Partial Reform,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 107, No. 3, pp. 889906.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Nesporova, Alena, 2002, “Why Unemployment Remains So High in Central and Eastern Europe,” ILO Employment Paper No. 43 (Geneva: International Labor Office).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Newell, Andrew, and Francesco Pastore, 2000, “Regional Unemployment and Industrial Restructuring in Poland,” IZA Discussion Paper No. 194 (Bonn, Germany: IZA).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Nickell, Stephen, 1998, “Unemployment: Questions and Some Answers,” Economic Journal, Vol. 108, No. 448, pp. 80216.

  • OECD, 2002a, Employment Outlook (Paris).

  • OECD, 2002b, OECD Economic Surveys: Slovak Republic, Vol. 2002/11 (Paris, June).

  • OECD, 2003a, “Beyond Rhetoric: Adult Learning Policies and Practices” (Paris June).

  • OECD, 2003b, Economic Review—Hungary (Paris).

  • OECD, 2003c, Economic Review—Slovak Republic (Paris).

  • OECD, 2004a, Employment Outlook (Paris).

  • OECD, 2004b, Benefits and Wages: OECD Indicators (Paris).

  • Ott, Katarina, 2002, “The Underground Economy in Croatia” (unpublished; Zagreb: Institute of Public Finance).

  • Ours, Jan C. van, 2002, “The Locking-In Effect of Subsidized Jobs,” CEPR Discussion Paper Series No. 3489 (London: Centre for Economic Policy Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Pani, Marco, 2000, “Unemployment in Slovakia,” in Slovak Republic: Selected Issues and Statistical Appendix, IMF Staff Country Report No. 00/115 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Puga, Diego, 1999, “The Rise and Fall of Regional Inequalities,” European Economic Review, Vol. 43, pp. 30334.

  • Puga, Diego, 2001, “European Regional Policies in Light of Recent Locational Theories,” CEPR Discussion Paper No. 2767 (London: Centre for Economic Policy Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Raiser, Martin, Mark E. Schaffer, and Johannes Schuchardt, 2003, “Benchmarking Structural Change in Transition,” CEPR Discussion Paper No. 3820 (London: Centre for Economic Policy Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Riboud, Michele, Carolina Sánchez-Páramo, and Carlos Silva-Jáuregui, 2002, “Does Eurosclerosis Matter? Institutional Reform and Labor Market Performance in Central and Eastern European Countries in the 1990s,” World Bank Technical Paper No. 519 (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Rutkowski, Jan, 2002, “Why Is Unemployment High in Bulgaria?” (unpublished; Washington: World Bank, March).

  • Rutkowski, Jan, 2003, “Does Strict Employment Protection Discourage Job Creation? Evidence from Croatia” (unpublished; Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Schneider, Friedrich, 2002a, “The Size and Development of the Shadow Economies and Shadow Economy Labor Force of 22 Transition and 21 OECD Countries: What Do We Really Know?” (Zagreb: Institute of Public Finance).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Schneider, Friedrich, 2002b, “Unofficial Activities in Transition Countries: Ten Years of Experience” (Zagreb: Institute of Public Finance).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Schneider, Friedrich, and Dominik Enste, 2000, “Shadow Economies: Size, Causes, and Consequences,” Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 108, pp. 77114.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Schneider, Friedrich, and Günter Pöll, 1999, “Schattenwirtschaft,” Handbuch der Wirtschaftsethik (Gütersloh, Germany: Gütersloher Verlagshauz).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Selassie, Abebe, 2001, “Unemployment, Wage Flexibility, and the Minimum Wage in Poland: Some Evidence from Micro Data” (unpublished; Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Shleifer, Andrei, and Robert W. Vishny, 1993, “Corruption,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 103, pp. 599617.

  • Suedekum, Jens, 2003, “Increasing Returns and Spatial Unemployment Disparities” University of Goettingen Department of Economics Discussion Paper No. 117 (Goettingen, Germany).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Svejnar, Jan, 2002, “Labor Market Flexibility in Central and East Europe,” William Davidson Institute Working Paper No. 496 (Ann Arbor, Michigan: University of Michigan Business School).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Taheri, Javid, 2000, “On the Alternative Explanations of Persistence of Unemployment in the OECD Countries,” Applied Economics, No. 32, pp. 105157.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Tervu, Hannu, 2000, “Migration and Labour Market Adjustment: Empirical Evidence from Finland 1985–90,” International Review of Applied Economics, Vol. 14, No. 3, pp. 34360.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • World Bank, 2001, “Slovak Republic: Living Standards, Employment and Labor Market Study,” Report No. 22351-SK (Washington).

  • World Bank, 2002a, “Bulgaria: Poverty Assessment” (Washington).

  • World Bank, 2002b, “Bulgaria: Poverty Assessment” (unpublished; Washington, May).

  • World Bank, 2002c, “Transition: The First Ten Years. Analysis and Lessons from Eastern Europe and the Former Soviet Union” (Washington).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • World Bank, 2003, “Croatia: Country Economic Memorandum” (Washington).

  • World Bank, 2004, Doing Business in 2004 (Washington).

  • World Economic Forum, 2004, The Global Competitiveness Report 2002–2003 (London: Palgrave Macmillan).