CHAPTER 3. Effects of African Trade Arrangements
Author:
Mr. Sanjeev Gupta
Search for other papers by Mr. Sanjeev Gupta in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
and
Yongzheng Yang https://isni.org/isni/0000000404811396 International Monetary Fund

Search for other papers by Yongzheng Yang in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close

Abstract

Time-series data show that the impact of the RTAs on intra-African trade seems to have been small or insignificant. As a share of the continent’s global trade, intra-African trade declined over much of the 1970s before it recovered in the 1980s and the first half of the 1990s. It was not until the early 1990s that intra-African trade recovered to its early 1970s levels (Figure 2). Since the mid-1990s, however, it has stagnated at about 10 percent of total African trade despite intensified efforts to integrate regionally. Trade among the countries in the major RTAs (SADC, COMESA, ECOWAS, WAEMU, and CEMAC) has also grown erratically relative to their trade with the rest of the world, often showing no obvious trend over time—except perhaps WAEMU, whose intraregional trade has increased in recent years because of the improved performance of the CU (Table 3). For many RTAs, intra-arrangement trade as a share of their total external trade remains below intra-African trade as a share of total African external trade.

A. Have RTAs Helped Increase Intraregional Trade?

Time-series data show that the impact of the RTAs on intra-African trade seems to have been small or insignificant. As a share of the continent’s global trade, intra-African trade declined over much of the 1970s before it recovered in the 1980s and the first half of the 1990s. It was not until the early 1990s that intra-African trade recovered to its early 1970s levels (Figure 2). Since the mid-1990s, however, it has stagnated at about 10 percent of total African trade despite intensified efforts to integrate regionally. Trade among the countries in the major RTAs (SADC, COMESA, ECOWAS, WAEMU, and CEMAC) has also grown erratically relative to their trade with the rest of the world, often showing no obvious trend over time—except perhaps WAEMU, whose intraregional trade has increased in recent years because of the improved performance of the CU (Table 3). For many RTAs, intra-arrangement trade as a share of their total external trade remains below intra-African trade as a share of total African external trade.

Figure 2.
Figure 2.

Intra-African Trade in Total African Trade, 1970–2003

(In percent)

Source: IMF, Direction of Trade Statistics.
Table 3.

Intra-Arrangement Trade in Africa

(Percent of total trade)

article image
Source: IMF, Direction of Trade Statistics, various years.

Trade ties within Africa look much stronger when they are normalized with Africa’s share in world trade (Figure 3). Although intraregional trade in Africa is lower than in other parts of the world, trade intensity is considerably higher among African countries than between African countries and a typical country outside the continent.16 This regional concentration in trade is largely due to Africa’s marginalization in the world market (Figure 4) rather than to the performance of intraregional trade.

Figure 3.
Figure 3.

Intraregional Trade Intensity in Africa, 1970–2003

Source: IMF, Direction of Trade Statistics, various years.
Figure 4.
Figure 4.

Africa’s Share in World Trade, 1970–2003

(In percent)

Source: IMF, Direction of Trade Statistics, various years.

The econometric evidence of the effectiveness of RTAs in promoting intra-African trade is mixed. The slow long-term growth of trade within Africa over the past few decades could result from something other than the ineffectiveness of the RTAs. The econometric technique commonly used to isolate the RTA effects on intraregional trade from those of other factors is the gravity model.17 Using this technique, Elbadawi (1997) finds that, during 1980–84, the presence of African RTAs increased intraregional imports by about 31 percent on average (the effect ranged from nonexistent to substantial) without causing trade diversion. However, these arrangements performed worse in the second half of the 1980s—most of them led to substantial trade diversion and even reductions in intra-arrangement and external overall trade. Carrere (2004) offers a more positive assessment of the African RTAs. She finds that during 1962–96 RTAs generated a significant increase in intra-RTA trade, although initially often through trade diversion. She also finds that CUs in the two CFA franc zone arrangements (CEMAC and WAEMU) have reinforced the positive effect of the corresponding trade agreements on intraregional trade while dampening their trade diversion effect. Other studies (Kasekende and Ng’eno, 1995; Lyakurwa, 1996; Robson, 1998) conclude that African RTAs have little or no effect on intraregional trade.

Thus, the RTAs may have had a positive but uneven effect on intraregional trade, although, over the long run, the effect seems to have been small or insignificant. The RTAs also appear to have caused some trade diversion, which may explain part of the decline over time in Africa’s share in world trade. Given the small share of intraregional trade in Africa’s total trade, the direct contribution of any trade diversion to overall trade performance is likely to be limited; any significant impact would have to come from the overall trade policy environment that RTAs have helped to create. It is difficult to establish that RTAs have resulted in a worse trade regime than there would have been otherwise.

The econometric results should be interpreted with caution. The greatest difficulty in interpreting these results is to identify a counterfactual with which the actual outcome can be compared. The implicitly assumed counterfactual in the gravity model is an outcome determined by control variables. As O’Connell (1997) points out, however, trade policies (including those governing RTAs) in Africa are often endogenous: they are largely influenced by macroeconomic variables (e.g., the balance of payments and the exchange rate) and, in turn, affect countries’ macroeconomic policy positions. Apart from the endogeneity problem, specification errors in the gravity model could lead to large margins of error in capturing the residual effect of RTAs. This problem may be compounded by the inaccuracy of African trade data.18

B. Have RTAs Helped Improve Regional Competitiveness?

RTAs do not yet seem to have had a significant impact on Africa’s export performance in the world market. The continent’s share in global trade has declined from about 4 percent in the 1970s to about 2 percent at present. The trend is similar when oil exports are excluded. Perhaps the clearest sign of Africa’s weak competitiveness is its poor performance in manufactured exports. During 1970–2003, Africa’s share in global manufactured exports (about 0.5 percent) hardly changed. Its exports of textiles and clothing, often the spearhead of export growth as countries industrialize, also failed to gain global market share. Several studies (Foroutan and Pritchett, 1993; Coe and Hoffmaister, 1999; Rodrik, 1999; Subramanian and Tamirisa, 2003) find that the declining share of Africa’s products in global trade can be explained largely by its income growth, population size, geography, and economic policy.19 This evidence supports the argument that Africa’s marginalization in world trade cannot be attributed to external forces (Ng and Yeats, 2000).

A further analysis of Africa’s non-oil export growth indicates that Africa’s competitiveness has declined over the past three decades (Table 4). Results from the constant market share (CMS) analysis show that, during 1970–80, declining competitiveness, together with an unfavorable export composition, was the dominant contributor to the continent’s poor non-oil export performance.20 This finding is consistent with that by Ng and Yeats (2002), who argue that Africa must diversify away from traditional exports or continue to suffer from a secular decline in the terms of trade and slow growth of demand for these exports. Africa’s competitiveness declined sharply during the 1980s before this deterioration slowed in the 1990s. Of course, the CMS analysis cannot reveal the causes of Africa’s declining export competitiveness, but it does show that RTAs have not been able to halt this decline.

Table 4.

Decomposition of African Non-Oil Export Growth, 1970–2000

article image
Source: IMF staff estimates based on UN COMTRADE data, extracted from the World Bank World Integrated Trade Solution (WITS) database.

There is little econometric research linking African export competitiveness with RTAs. However, available evidence on the relationship between African exports/trade liberalization and productivity growth helps shed some light on the impact of African RTAs on export competitiveness. Based on firm-level panel data from three African economies (Ghana, Kenya, and Ethiopia), Mengistae and Pattillo (2004) find that exporting manufacturers have a total factor productivity premium of 11–28 percent. Jonsson and Subramanian (2000) find that trade liberalization has contributed significantly to growth through higher productivity in South Africa. To the extent that RTAs have not been effective in promoting overall African exports, it is unlikely that they have increased Africa’s export competitiveness (through productivity gains) vis-à-vis the rest of the world. Indeed, the RTAs may have reduced Africa’s international competitiveness because they divert trade toward RTA partners. In many ways, the effects of African RTAs are similar to those of an import substitution policy (albeit on a regional, rather than a national, scale), which protects local industries and reduces incentives to export to world markets. In fact, the primary motive for the establishment of the early (and not so early) African RTAs was industrialization through regional import substitution (Foroutan, 1993; Oyejide, 1997; François and Subramanian, 1998).

Africa’s poor record in attracting FDI also seems to indicate that RTAs have not significantly improved the region’s competitiveness. One rationale for the premise that RTAs would increase Africa’s external competitiveness was that enlarged regional markets would generate higher returns to capital and hence attract more FDI, which would then increase the region’s ability to export. At the aggregate level, FDI inflows in Africa as a percentage of total low- and middle-income country FDI have declined sharply over time (Figure 5). In addition, the inflows are heavily skewed toward the mining industries (including the petroleum industry) and highly concentrated in just a few countries (e.g., South Africa, Nigeria, and Angola). FDI from South Africa to other countries in the region is, however, more diversified across industries. Elbadawi and Mwega (1998) find that, unlike some trade agreements in other parts of the world (e.g., the Association of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN)), African RTAs other than the SADC did not significantly increase FDI. However, an earlier study by de Melo, Panagariya, and Rodrik (1993) finds significant investment effects for the Central African Customs and Economic Union (UDEAC), predecessor of the Central African Economic and Monetary Community (CEMAC), and the West Africa Economic Community (CEAO), predecessor of WAEMU. Nevertheless, if investment increases under an RTA because of higher returns from activities related to trade diversion, then the investment will have been diverted from more productive uses.21

Figure 5.
Figure 5.

Foreign Direct Investment: Net Inflows in Africa, 1970–2001

(In percent of the low- and middle-income countries, total)

Source: World Bank, World Development Finance, various years.

C. Have RTAs Benefited Africa?

Even if RTAs have increased intra-Africa trade, they may not have improved welfare. The conventional approach to the analysis of the impact on economic welfare of regional trade arrangements is based on Viner’s concepts of the trade creation and trade diversion effects of CUs. If African RTAs have not significantly increased intraregional trade over extraregional trade, then they are unlikely to have led to any trade creation or trade diversion. Nevertheless, real resource costs are involved in negotiating and implementing these arrangements, irrespective of the outcome. If the regional arrangements have also diverted attention away from unilateral and multilateral trade liberalization and other domestic reform agendas, then the cost could be larger.22

The available econometric results suggest that RTAs are unlikely to have increased Africa’s overall trade or its economic welfare. Take the example of the relatively positive assessment by Carrere (2004), which shows that the SADC increased intraregional trade by two and a half times and reduced extraregional trade by only 35 percent during 1962–96.23 Since intra-SADC trade was less than one-tenth of total SADC external trade, this implies that total SADC trade (intra-SADC plus SADC external) declined by about 7 percent as a result of this regional arrangement. In fact, even if trade creation exactly offsets trade diversion (and assuming domestic production does not change), the arrangement must have reduced welfare—the loss of tariff revenue from intraregional trade is greater than consumer benefits.24

Of course, RTAs may have some dynamic effects that could, in theory, dominate the static welfare effects outlined above. Such benefits could result from increased competition and learning by doing. They could also come from the increased imports of capital goods, which may embody more advanced technology. But if African RTAs have not been able to increase the region’s overall trade and have often led to fewer imports from the rest of the world, it is unlikely that they have yielded any dynamic gains. A study cited earlier (de Melo, Panagariya, and Rodrik, 1993) finds no growth effects for the UDEAC or CEAO. Robson (1998) draws the broader conclusion that most RTAs in Africa have contributed little or nothing to economic development.

D. Have RTAs Achieved Their Noneconomic Objectives?

Like RTAs in other parts of the world, African arrangements also have several noneconomic objectives, of which the most important is conflict prevention and resolution. It is widely believed that close trade ties would make conflicts between countries economically more costly and hence less likely to happen. If conflicts do arise, the incentives for external intervention are stronger because the stakes are higher. Close trade ties, however, do not always reduce risks of conflict. In fact, they can aggravate tensions between countries if they lead to an uneven (real or perceived) distribution of benefits (and losses) arising from RTAs (World Bank, 2000). For instance, trade integration among members of the Eastern African Community (Kenya, Tanzania, and Uganda) led to the concentration of manufacturing activities in Kenya and eventually caused the demise of the EAC. On balance, however, anecdotal evidence seems to suggest that more recent RTAs that are part of deeper regional integration arrangements (e.g., the EU and the African Union) may have contributed to regional stability and security. One prominent African example often cited as a success is the intervention by ECOWAS in the civil conflicts in Sierra Leone, where ECOWAS troops, together with UN and British troops, played an important role in disarming the rebels against the government and eventually led to peaceful democratic elections in 2003.

However, the role of RTAs in preventing and resolving conflicts in Africa should not be exaggerated. First, even if closer trade ties do increase incentives for regional intervention in the event of a conflict, RTAs that do not increase intraregional trade will not make such intervention more likely. In fact, in Africa, regional cooperation arrangements that address the management of cross-border resource issues (such as water) are more effective in reducing military conflicts than trade-based RTAs (World Bank, 2004). Second, effective regional intervention requires regional arrangements that go beyond trade. This finding suggests that some regional political and cooperation arrangements can be just as effective as trade arrangements in preventing and resolving conflict. Furthermore, regional intervention may not be effective without the broad support of the wider international community. An RTA that diverts trade away from the rest of the world could hardly help attract attention from the rest of the world.

Another largely noneconomic objective of African RTAs is to increase regional bargaining power in multilateral and other forums for trade negotiations. Collective efforts would increase Africa’s bargaining power only if the African countries formed a common position, in terms of both what concessions they seek from their trading partners and what they are willing to offer to them. In many areas, African countries do have a common position, such as greater market access in industrial countries. Another common interest is to make the Doha Round more development-oriented. However, when it comes to specific trade issues, African countries do not always have a common interest or position. For example, African countries have not presented a common tariff offer during the Doha Round negotiations. Another such example is quota restrictions on textile imports in the United States and the EU. For cotton-exporting countries in Western Africa (i.e., Benin, Burkina Faso, Chad, and Mali), the removal of textile quotas would increase world demand for their cotton, a vital industry for their economies. In contrast, some other African countries—Kenya, Lesotho, Madagascar, Mauritius, Namibia, South Africa, and Swaziland—are expected to lose from the removal of the quotas. So far in the WTO, Mauritius and Madagascar have aligned themselves with some other developing countries that are expected to lose from the quota removal in an effort to extend the quota restrictions, against the interests of the cotton-exporting African countries.

16
The trade intensity index used here is the same as the one used by Frankel, Stein, and Wei (1997) and similar to the one developed by Drysdale and Garnaut (1982):
I=TITA/TATW,
where I is the trade intensity index, TI is intraregional trade, TA is the region’s total (global) trade, and TW is world trade. If the index is lower (higher) than unity, intraregional trade is less (more) intense than extraregional trade.
17

The typical gravity model for testing the trade effect of RTAs has the following general specification:

Xijt = α + βjt Cijt + δjt Sijt + μ,

where Xijt stands for exports from country i to country j in time t; Cijt represents a set of variables that control for the effect on bilateral trade; Dijt is a set of (binary) dummy variables that are designed to capture the incremental effect of the RTAs in question; μ is the error term; and α, β, and δ are coefficients to be estimated. A less widely used approach is to estimate the trade diversion and trade creation effects using quantity and price data at the detailed commodity level, together with demand and supply elasticities that are needed in partial equilibrium analysis. See, for example, Krueger (1999c), Clausing (2001), and Romalis (2004).

18

Yeats (1998) provides a detailed discussion of the deficiencies of African trade data, which, as reported to the United Nations (UN) COMTRADE system, are often incomplete, out of date, missing, or even contradictory. On the other hand, data reported in the IMF’s Direction of Trade Statistics on Africa are up-to-date but contain data on aggregate trade only.

19

Subramanian and Tamirisa (2003) also find that francophone Africa, in particular, is an undertrader and that its undertrading, especially with industrial countries, has increased over time. The authors suggest that trade-related costs and the currency arrangements in the CFA zone may be responsible.

20

The CMS analysis decomposes a country’s export growth into four components that are attributed to (1) global market growth, (2) the effect of export composition, (3) the effect of market distribution, and (4) changes in the country’s competitiveness (the residual). The analysis here identifies four regions (Africa, the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) countries, the EU, and the rest of the world) and uses commodity data at the Standard International Trade Classification (SITC) (Rev. 1) one-digit level. For details of the CMS model, see Leamer and Stern (1970).

21

Krueger (1999b) explains this possibility in the context of FTA rules of origin that tend to be “protectionist.” An exporter selling within an FTA could switch the sourcing of inputs to a higher-cost partner country from a lower-cost country outside the FTA because it has to meet the rules of origin in order to gain duty-free entry of final goods exports to the partner country. Similarly, an investor could be induced to invest in a factory within an FTA that would otherwise not be viable.

22

The counterfactual for evaluating the effect of RTAs is difficult to establish. One could compare the observed outcome with an equilibrium extrapolated from the trend prior to the establishment of the arrangement, or with an equilibrium in which a different outcome might have emerged as a result of an alternative path of multilateral or unilateral liberalization.

23

It is not clear whether and to what extent the increase in intra-SADC trade resulted from South Africa’s accession to the SADC.

24

Popular press and academic analysis often equate net trade creation (increase in intraregional trade plus decrease in extraregional trade) with net welfare creation. Obviously, even if net trade creation is positive, there could be a net welfare loss depending on the cost structure of domestic production and the level of the external tariffs against nonmember countries. The ultimate criterion for judging the welfare effect of a regional arrangement is whether consumer gains outweigh government revenue and producer losses.

  • Collapse
  • Expand
  • Figure 2.

    Intra-African Trade in Total African Trade, 1970–2003

    (In percent)

  • Figure 3.

    Intraregional Trade Intensity in Africa, 1970–2003

  • Figure 4.

    Africa’s Share in World Trade, 1970–2003

    (In percent)

  • Figure 5.

    Foreign Direct Investment: Net Inflows in Africa, 1970–2001

    (In percent of the low- and middle-income countries, total)

  • African Development Bank, 2000, African Development Report 2000 (Abidjan).

  • Agbeyegbe, Terence, Janet G. Stotsky, and Asegedech WoldeMariam, 2004, “Trade Liberalization, Exchange Rate Changes, and Tax Revenue in SubSaharan Africa,” IMF Working Paper 04/178 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Alexandraki, Katerina, and Hans Peter Lankes, 2004, “The Impact of Preference Erosion on Middle-Income Developing Countries,” IMF Working Paper 04/169 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ancharaz, Vinaye, 2003, “Determinants of Trade Policy Reform in Sub-Saharan Africa,” Journal of African Economies, Vol. 12, No. 3, pp. 41743.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Arora, Vivek, and Athanasios Vamvakidis, 2004, “How Much Do Trading Partners Matter for Economic Growth?IMF Working Paper 04/26 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Baldwin, Richard E., 2003, “Openness and Growth: What Is the Empirical Relationship?NBER Working Paper No. 9578 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Baldwin, Richard E., and Anthony Venables, 1996Regional Economic Integration” in Handbook of International Economics, Vol. 3, ed. by Gene M. Grossman and Kenneth Rogoff (Amsterdam: North Holland), pp. 15971644.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Baunsgaard, Thomas, Anne-Marie Geourjon, Michael Keen, Jesus Seade, 2003, “Liberalizing Trade and Safeguarding Public Revenues,” note prepared for the WTO (WT/TF/COH/14), January.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Baunsgaard, Thomas, and Michael Keen, 2005, “Trade Revenue and (or?) Trade Liberalization,” IMF Working Paper 05/112 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Berg, Andrew, and Anne O. Krueger, 2003, “Trade, Growth, and Poverty: A Selective Survey,” IMF Working Paper 03/30 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bhagwati, Jagdish, and Arvind Panagariya, 1996, The Economics of Preferential Trading Arrangements (Washington: American Enterprise Institute).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Carrere, Celine, 2004, “African Regional Agreements: Impact on Trade With or Without Currency Unions,” Journal of African Economies, Vol. 13, No. 2, pp. 199239.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Clausing, Kimberly A., 2001, “Trade Creation and Trade Diversion in the Canada-United States Free Trade Agreement,” Canadian Journal of Economics, Vol. 34, No. 3, pp. 67796.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Coe, David T., and Alexander W. Hoffmaister, 1999, “North-South Trade: Is Africa Unusual?Journal of African Economies, Vol. 8, No. 2, pp. 22856.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Collier, Paul, 1991, “Africa’s External Economic Relations: 1960–90,” African Affairs, Vol. 90, No. 360, pp. 33956.

  • COMESA Secretariat, 2001, Annual Report, Ref.COM/TCM/CT/NTB/1/3 and COM/TCM/NTB/1/4 (Lusaka, Zambia).

  • De Melo, Jaime, Arvind Panagariya, and Dani Rodrik, 1993, “The New Regionalism: A Country Perspective,” in New Dimensions in Regional Integration, ed. by Jaime de Melo and Arvind Panagariya (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dollar, David, and Aart Kraay, 2001, “Trade, Growth, and Poverty,” Policy Research Working Paper Series 2615 (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Drysdale, Peter, and Ross Garnaut, 1982, “Trade Intensities and the Analysis of Bilateral Trade Flows in a Many-Country World,” Hitotsubashi Journal of Economics, Vol. 22, pp. 6284.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ebrill, Liam, Janet Stotsky, and Reint Gropp, 1999, Revenue Implications of Trade Liberalization, Occasional Paper No. 180 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Elbadawi, Ibrahim A., 1997, “The Impact of Regional Trade and Monetary Schemes on Intra-Sub-Saharan Africa Trade,” in Regional Integration and Trade Liberalization in Sub-Saharan Africa, ed. by Ademola Oyejide, Ibrahim Elbadawi, and Paul Collier (London: Macmillan Press Ltd.).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Elbadawi, Ibrahim A., and Francis M. Mwega, 1998, “Regional Integration, Trade, and Foreign Direct Investment in Sub-Saharan Africa,” in Trade Reform and Regional Integration in Africa, ed. by Zubair Iqbal and Moshin S. Khan (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Flatters, Frank, 2002, “SADC Rules of Origin: Undermining Regional Free Trade.” Available via the Internet: http://qed.econ.queensu.ca/faculty/flatters/main/writings.html.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Flatters, Frank, and Robert Kirk, 2004, “Rules of Origin as Tools of Development? Some Lessons from SADC,” Trade Policy and Economic Development (Arlington, Virginia: The Services Group (TSG)).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Foroutan, Faezeh, 1993, “Regional Integration in Sub-Saharan Africa: Past Experience and Future Prospects,” in New Dimensions in Regional Integration, ed. by James de Melo and Arvind Panagariya (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Foroutan, Faezeh, and Lant Pritchett, 1993, “Intra-Sub-Saharan African Trade: Is It Too Little?Journal of African Economies, Vol. 2 (May), pp. 74105.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • François, Christian A., and Arvind Subramanian, 1998, “Beyond Trade: Regional Trade Arrangements as a Window on Globalization,” in Trade Reform and Regional Integration in Africa, ed. by Zubair Iqbal and Mohsin S. Khan (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Frankel, Jeffrey A., Ernesto Stein, and Shang-Jin Wei, 1997, Regional Trading Blocs in the World Economic System (Washington: Institute for International Economics).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Herin, Jan, 1986, “Rules of Origin and Differences Between Tariff Levels in EFTA and in the EU,” EFTA Occasional Paper No. 13 (Geneva: European Free Trade Association).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hinkle, Lawrence E., and Maurice Schiff, 2004, “Economic Partnership Between Sub-Saharan Africa and the EU: A Development Perspective,” The World Economy, Vol. 27, No. 9, pp. 132133.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hummel, David, 2001, “Time as a Trade Barrier” (West Lafayette, Indiana: Purdue University).

  • Jebuni, Charles D., 1997, “Trade Liberalization and Regional Integration in Africa,” in Regional Integration and Trade Liberalization in Sub-Saharan Africa, ed. by Ademola Oyejide, Ibrahim Elbadawi, and Paul Collier (London: Macmillan Press Ltd.).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Jonsson, Gunnar, and Arvind Subramanian, 2000, “Dynamic Gains from Trade Evidence from South Africa,” IMF Working Paper 00/45 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kasekende, L., and N. Ng’eno, 1995, Regional Integration and Economic Liberalization in East and Southern Africa (Nairobi: African Economic Research Consortium).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Keen, Michael, and Jenny Ligthart, 2001, “Coordinating Tariff Reductions and Domestic Tax Reform,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 56, pp. 40725.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Keen, Michael, and Alejandro Simone, 2004, “Tax Policy In Developing Countries: Some Lessons from the 1990s and Some Challenges Ahead,” in Helping Countries Develop: The Role of Fiscal Policy, ed. by Sanjeev Gupta, Benedict Clements, and Gabriela Inchauste (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Khandelwal, Padamja, 2004, “COMESA and SADC: Prospects and Challenges for Regional Integration,” IMF Working Paper 04/227 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Khattry, Barsha, and Mohan Rao, 2002, “Fiscal Faux Pas? An Analysis of the Revenue Implications of Trade Liberalization,” World Development, Vol. 30, pp. 143144.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kowalski P., 2004, Impact of Changes in Tariffs on Developing Countries’ Government Revenue, TD/TC/WP(2004)29/Rev1, work in progress (Paris: Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Krishna, Kala, and Anne O. Krueger, 1995, “Implementing Free Trade Areas: Rules of Origin and Hidden Protection,” NBER Working Paper No. 4983 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kritzinger-van Niekerk, Lolette, and Emmanuel Pinto Moreira 2002, “Regional Integration in Southern Africa: Overview of Recent Developments,” Discussion Paper (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Krueger, Anne O., 1999a, “Are Preferential Trading Arrangements Trade-Liberalizing or Protectionist?Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 13, No. 4, pp. 10524.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Krueger, Anne O., 1999b, “Free Trade Agreements as Protectionist Devices: Rules of Origin,” NBER Working Paper No. 4352 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Krueger, Anne O., 1999c, “Trade Creation and Trade Diversion under NAFTA,” NBER Working Paper No. 7429 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Leamer, Edward, and Robert Stern, 1970, Quantitative International Economics (Boston: Allyn and Bacon).

  • Lyakurwa, W. M., 1996, “Trade and Investment Integration in Sub-Saharan Africa,” paper presented at a FONDAD Conference on Regional Integration in Africa, The Hague.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mengistae, Taye, and Catherine Pattillo, 2004, “Export Orientation and Productivity in Sub-Saharan Africa,” IMF Staff Papers, Vol. 51, No. 2, pp. 32753.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ng, Francis, and Alexander Yeats, 2000, “On the Recent Trade Performance of Sub-Saharan African Countries: Cause for Hope or More of the Same?Africa Region Working Paper Series No. 26, June (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ng, Francis, and Alexander Yeats, 2002, “What Can Africa Expect from Its Traditional Exports?Africa Region Working Paper Series No. 26, February (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • O’Connell, Stephen A., 1997, “Macroeconomic Harmonization, Trade Reform, and Regional Trade in Sub-Saharan Africa,” in Regional Integration and Trade Liberalization in Sub-Saharan Africa, ed. by Ademola Oyejide, Ibrahim Elbadawi, and Paul Collier (London: Macmillan Press Ltd.).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Oyejide, T. Ademola, 1997, “Regional Integration and Trade Liberalization in Sub-Saharan Africa,” Special Paper No. 28 (Nairobi: African Economic Research Consortium).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Panagariya, Arvind, 2000, “Preferential Trade Liberalization: The Traditional Theory and New Developments,” Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 38 (June), pp. 287331.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Panagariya, Arvind, 2002, “EU Preferential Trade Arrangements and Developing Countries,” World Economy, Vol. 25, No. 10, pp. 141532.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Panagariya, Arvind, 2004, “Miracles and Debacles: In Defense of Trade Openness,” World Economy, Vol. 27, No. 8, pp. 114971.

  • Robson, P., 1998, Economic Integration in Africa (London: Allen and Unwin).

  • Rodriguez, Francisco, and Dani Rodrik, 2001, “Trade Policy and Economic Growth: A Skeptic’s Guide to the Cross-National Evidence,” in NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2000, ed. by Ben Nernanke and Kenneth Rogoff (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Rodrik, Dani, 1999, The New Global Economy and Developing Countries: Making Openness Work (London: Overseas Development Institute).

  • Romalis, Johan, 2004, “NAFTA’s and CUSFTA’s Impact on International Trade” (Chicago: University of Chicago).

  • Sachs, Jeffrey, and Andrew Warner, 1995, “Economic Reform and the Process of Global Integration,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: 1, Brookings Institution.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Schiff, Maurice, and L. Alan Winters, 2003, Regional Integration and Development (Washington: World Bank and Oxford University Press).

  • Subramanian, Arvind, 2003, “Financing of Losses from Preference Erosion,” note prepared for the WTO (WT/TF/COH/14), January.

  • Subramanian, Arvind, Enrique Gelbard, Richard Harmsen, Katrin Elborgh-Woytek and Piroska Nagy, 2000, Trade and Trade Policy in Eastern and Southern Africa, Occasional Paper No. 196 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Subramanian, Arvind, and Natalia Tamirisa, 2003, “Is Africa Integrated in the Global Economy?IMF Staff Papers, Vol. 50, No. 3, pp. 35272.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • United Nations Economic Commission for Africa (ECA), 2004, Assessing Regional Integration in Africa (Addis Ababa, Ethiopia).

  • United States Department of Agriculture, 2001, Agricultural Policy Reform in the WTO: The Road Ahead, Economic Research Service (Washington).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Vamvakidis, Athanasios, 1998, “Regional Trade Agreements Versus Broad Liberalization: Which Path Leads to Faster Growth? Time Series Evidence,” IMF Working Paper 98/40 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • World Bank, 2000, Trade Blocs (Washington: World Bank).

  • World Bank, 2001, “Memorandum of the President of the International Development Association to the Executive Directors on a Regional Integration Assistance Strategy for West Africa,” July 11 (Washington).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • World Bank, 2003a, “Africa Regional Trade Progress Note,” June (Washington).

  • World Bank, 2003b, “Memorandum of the President of the International Development Association to the Executive Directors on a Regional Integration Assistance Strategy for Central Africa,” January 10 (Washington).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • World Bank, 2003c, “Regional Trade Integration in East Africa—Revenue Impacts of the Planned Customs Union,” December (Washington).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • World Bank, 2004, Global Economic Prospects 2005 (Washington: World Bank).

  • Yeats, Alexander J., 1998, “What Can Be Expected from African Regional Trade Agreements: Some Empirical Evidence,” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 2004 (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation