II Balance Sheet Shocks and Their Transmission in Capital Account Crises
Author:
Mr. Brad Setser https://isni.org/isni/0000000404811396 International Monetary Fund

Search for other papers by Mr. Brad Setser in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
,
Mr. Ioannis Halikias
Search for other papers by Mr. Ioannis Halikias in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
,
Mr. Alexander Pitt
Search for other papers by Mr. Alexander Pitt in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
,
Mr. Christoph B. Rosenberg
Search for other papers by Mr. Christoph B. Rosenberg in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
,
Mr. Brett E. House
Search for other papers by Mr. Brett E. House in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
,
Mr. Jens Nystedt https://isni.org/isni/0000000404811396 International Monetary Fund

Search for other papers by Mr. Jens Nystedt in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
, and
Mr. Christian Keller
Search for other papers by Mr. Christian Keller in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close

Abstract

There is a growing recognition that the traditional financial programming approach may not fully explain some of the dynamics underlying modern-day capital account crises. Its flow-based analysis focuses on the gradual buildup of unsustainable fiscal and current account positions. The BSA, by contrast, focuses on shocks to stocks of assets and liabilities that can trigger large adjustments in (capital) flows. Such an approach can, therefore, be a useful complement to traditional flow analyses. Indeed, academics and policymakers have been paying increasing attention to the BSA’s further development as a result of the capital account crises of the 1990s. The IMF has been applying the insights from the BSA for some time and many of its elements have entered the IMF’s work on fiscal and external sustainability, liquidity and debt management, financial sector assessment, and so on.

There is a growing recognition that the traditional financial programming approach may not fully explain some of the dynamics underlying modern-day capital account crises. Its flow-based analysis focuses on the gradual buildup of unsustainable fiscal and current account positions. The BSA, by contrast, focuses on shocks to stocks of assets and liabilities that can trigger large adjustments in (capital) flows. Such an approach can, therefore, be a useful complement to traditional flow analyses. Indeed, academics and policymakers have been paying increasing attention to the BSA’s further development as a result of the capital account crises of the 1990s. The IMF has been applying the insights from the BSA for some time and many of its elements have entered the IMF’s work on fiscal and external sustainability, liquidity and debt management, financial sector assessment, and so on.

Balance Sheet Concepts

An economy can be viewed as a stylized system of the balance sheets of all its agents. Unlike the more traditional analysis of an economy that looks at the flows occurring over a defined period of time—such as the annual output, fiscal balance, current account balance, or investment flows—a balance sheet analysis looks at stocks of assets and liabilities—such as debt, foreign reserves, loans outstanding, and inventory at a certain point in time. Obviously, the two approaches are interrelated, as the difference in a stock variable at two dates is related to the flow in the period between them.2

As a first step, one may identify an economy’s main sectoral balance sheets: the government sector (including the central bank), the private financial sector (mainly banks), and the nonfinancial sector (corporations and households).3 These sectors have claims on and liabilities to each other, and to external (nonresident) entities. When consolidating the sectoral balance sheets into the country’s balance sheet, the assets and liabilities held between residents net out, leaving the country’s external balance vis-à-vis the rest of the world (nonresidents).4 Figure 2.1 shows a stylized system of such accounts, which excludes nonfinancial assets and liabilities. It illustrates how one sector’s liability is by definition another sector’s asset, and vice versa.

Figure 2.1.
Figure 2.1.

Sectoral Balance Sheets and Their Main Interlinkages

Sectoral balance sheets provide important information that remains hidden in the consolidated country balance sheet. A country’s balance sheet can show the potential scale of vulnerability to reversals in external financing flows, but it is often inadequate for examining the genesis of such reversals. Weaknesses in certain sectoral balance sheets may contribute to the creation of a country-wide balance of payments crisis, yet they may not appear in a country’s aggregate balance sheet. An important example is foreign currency debt between residents, which is netted out of a country’s aggregated balance sheet. Nevertheless, if the government is unable to roll over its hard currency debts to residents and must draw on its reserves to honor its debts, such debts can trigger an external balance of payments crisis. The risk that difficulties rolling over domestic debts can spill over into a balance of payments crisis is particularly acute in a world where capital accounts have been liberalized. Such risks are enhanced if difficulties in one sector can cascade into healthy sectors as a result of financial interlinkages.

Four general types of risks are worth highlighting when assessing balance sheet weaknesses: maturity, currency, capital structure, and solvency. Maturity and currency mismatches create exposure to particular sources of risk, including market risks such as a change in interest rates or exchange rates, while capital structure mismatches reduce a country’s ability to bear these as well as a range of other risks.5 All of these mismatches create vulnerabilities that can lead directly to solvency risk, although solvency risk can also arise from other sources.6 The interaction of these risks can be best understood when examining how they have come to bear in recent emerging market financial crises.

The Anatomy of Recent Balance Sheet Crises

Capital account crises typically occur as creditors suddenly lose confidence in the health of the balance sheets of one of a country’s main sectors—the banking system, the corporate sector, or the government. This confidence loss can prompt sudden and large-scale portfolio adjustments, such as massive withdrawals of bank deposits, panic sales of securities, or abrupt halts of debt rollovers. As the exchange rate, interest rates, and other asset prices adjust, the balance sheets of an entire sector—which may be largely solvent in the absence of these adverse events—can sharply deteriorate. In an integrated financial system and with an open capital account, concerns about asset quality on domestic balance sheets can provoke creditors to shift toward (safer) foreign assets. This will often result in capital outflows, which exert further pressure on the exchange rate or official reserves and ultimately result in a balance of payments crisis. The mechanisms underlying such balance sheet crises, which are illustrated in Figure 2.2, are discussed in more detail below.

Figure 2.2.
Figure 2.2.

Anatomy of a Balance Sheet Crisis

The initial shock to a balance sheet may take various forms, its impact depending on the existing mismatches on the balance sheet. Several patterns can be detected in capital account crises of the last decade:

  • A currency mismatch—a predominance of assets denominated in domestic currency over liabilities denominated in foreign currency—leaves a balance sheet vulnerable to a depreciation of the domestic currency (exchange rate shock).

  • A maturity mismatch—long-term, illiquid assets mismatched against short-term liabilities expose a balance sheet to risks related both to rollover and to interest rates: if liquid assets do not cover maturing debts, a balance sheet is vulnerable to a rollover risk, because emerging market economies can find themselves shut out of capital markets altogether. Furthermore, a sharp increase in interest rates (interest rate shock) can dramatically increase the cost of rolling over short-term liabilities, leading to a rapid increase in debt service.

  • Other market risks include any sharp drop in the price of assets such as government bonds, real estate, or equities, to which the balance sheets of a certain sector may be particularly exposed.

Any of the above shocks can bring about a deterioration in the value of a sector’s assets compared with its liabilities and hence to a reduction of its net worth; in the extreme case this net worth may turn negative and the sector becomes insolvent. The greater a balance sheet’s capital structure mismatch—too much debt relative to equity—the smaller its buffer against such an event.

Strong balance sheets protect against real as well as financial shocks. Many shocks originate in the real economy. For example, a collapse in the demand for a country’s main commodity or other major export product will lead to a deterioration in corporate earnings or government revenue. This will prompt a reassessment of these sectors’ sustainability and thus a reevaluation of the market value of their debt and other assets. Such real shocks are particularly dangerous when combined with financial vulnerabilities, as a real shock is often correlated with reduced market access. The impact of the commodity price shock of 1998, for example, was magnified in countries such as Russia, where maturity mismatches left balance sheets vulnerable to rollover risk and interest rate shocks.

Maturity and currency mismatches are sometimes hidden in indexed or floating rate debt instruments, making these mismatches less evident. In some emerging market economies (e.g., Brazil) liabilities may be formally denominated in local currency, but indexed to the exchange rate. Similarly, the nominal maturity of an asset may be long, but the interest rate it bears may be floating. Such indexation often creates the same mismatches as if the debt were denominated in foreign currency or as if the maturity were as short as the frequency of the interest rate adjustments.

Off-balance-sheet activities can substantially alter the overall risk exposure. Financial transactions such as forwards, futures, swaps, and other derivatives are not recorded on balance sheets, but imply predetermined or contingent future flows that will eventually affect them. Such transactions can be used to effectively reduce the risk created by balance sheet mismatches: for example, corporations with a foreign currency mismatch may enter into foreign currency forward contracts to reduce their exposure to exchange rate risk. By the same token, off-balance-sheet activities increase risk exposure when they are not used to hedge (taking a position that is negatively correlated to an existing balance sheet risk), but to speculate, or, in the particular case of monetary authorities, to support the domestic currency against market pressures.

Balance sheet problems in one sector can spill over into other sectors, often snowballing in the process. Balance sheet crises can originate in the corporate sector (as in some Asian countries in 1997–98) or the fiscal sector (as in Russia in 1998, Turkey in 2001, and, more recently, in some Latin American countries), with the banking sector playing a key transmission role in all these episodes. If a shock causes the corporate sector or the government to be unable to meet its liabilities, another sector, typically the banking sector, loses its claims. By the same token, if banks tighten their lending to prevent their asset portfolio from deteriorating, this further complicates the situation of a corporate sector or a government in dire need of fresh financing or a debt rollover. Because of these repercussions, balance sheet problems tend to snowball as they spill from one sector into another.

A loss of confidence in the banking system often not only triggers a run on deposits, but also a flight from the currency. The authorities may expand liquidity or lower interest rates to support the ailing banking system, while depositors may seek to protect their savings by switching into foreign currency assets. Both create pressure on the exchange rate. A depreciating exchange rate, however, further weakens the asset side of a banking sector that has a currency mismatch on its balance sheet. Thus, banking and currency crises may reinforce each other, creating the “twin crises” frequently observed in past cases.

Although a crisis may not originate in the government’s balance sheet, it is likely to spread to it, partly as a result of contingent liabilities. For instance, the banking system’s integrity is often explicitly or implicitly guaranteed by the government. In the event of a crisis, such contingent (off-balance-sheet) commitments become definite (balance sheet) liabilities, further adding to the deterioration of the government’s balance sheet and the fiscal pressures that are created by the macroeconomic disruptions resulting from the crisis. Contingent commitments may even exist to bail out corporations, especially when governments are involved in their investment and borrowing decisions. Furthermore, monetary authorities may be engaged in forward contracts and other off-balance-sheet transactions, which can entail large contingent drains on their foreign currency assets.

The interaction between financial balance sheets also magnifies the negative impact of a shock on real output levels. Autonomous investment cuts by corporations to restore the financial health of their balance sheets are usually compounded by a forced reduction in credit from distressed banks and lower consumption by households that experience a negative wealth effect. All this may contribute to a sharp decline in aggregate demand.

Operationalizing the Balance Sheet Approach

The IMF has been using insights based on balance sheet concepts in its surveillance work for some time. While this approach can also provide insights on crisis management and the design of IMF-supported programs, much of its recent application in the IMF has focused on vulnerability analysis. There is, for example, increased emphasis on the adequacy of official reserves in relation to short-term debt, monetary aggregates, and other stock variables; a sharpened focus on dollarization risks; and enhanced efforts at promoting better public liability management. Other important work that uses balance-sheet-related concepts includes the IMF’s framework for debt sustainability analysis (DSA) and the Financial Sector Assessment Program (FSAP). Over the past few years, a number of country teams have applied the BSA to support their policy advice in the context of the annual Article IV consultations. Recent examples include Bulgaria, Colombia, Latvia, Lebanon, Peru, Thailand, and Turkey.

Efforts to incorporate the BSA into the IMF’s work have been supported by statistical and transparency initiatives. These have improved the availability of some key balance sheet stock data and the accuracy of these data. In particular, the requirements of the Special Data Dissemination Standard (SDDS) have improved the dissemination of data and metadata on public and external debt, international reserves and foreign currency liquidity, international investment positions, and analytical accounts of the banking sector.7 The IMF’s Coordinated Portfolio Investment Survey has improved the availability and comparability of statistics on countries’ portfolio investment positions. An interagency task force chaired by the IMF has also developed a new guide on the measuring and monitoring of external debt.8 The IMF’s Government Finance Statistics Manual 2001 supports the balance sheet approach through a statistical framework that systematically links flows and stocks and introduces the concept of a government balance sheet.

A simple matrix presentation of sectoral asset and liability positions can serve as the basis for a sectoral balance sheet analysis. There is, of course, no single well-established way of presenting and analyzing sectoral balance sheet data, and, obviously, more complex ways of modeling are possible, for example, by explicitly incorporating measures of volatility. For an outline of some operational aspects of the balance sheet approach, see Box 2.1.

A number of caveats regarding the usefulness of the BSA for vulnerability analysis are in order. While the application of the approach in this paper holds much promise, it also suffers from a number of shortcomings that will have to be overcome over time:

  • First, as distinct from early warning systems, the BSA cannot be easily reduced to a small set of indicators that quantify vulnerabilities in a manner that is readily amenable to cross-country comparisons. Rather, the approach is better thought of as a conceptual framework for a fuller assessment of vulnerabilities and related policy options, in conjunction with other relevant country-specific factors.

  • Second, by definition, the BSA does not take into account off-balance-sheet transactions that have become increasingly important over time. As will be demonstrated in some of the country case studies, such transactions can be used to hedge balance sheet exposures, but have at times exacerbated them.

  • Third, a full assessment of underlying risks needs to factor in the probability distribution of key relevant shocks. For instance, under a fixed exchange rate regime, a situation of significant misalignment would raise the level of concern relating to any vulnerabilities identified by the BSA and sharpen the urgency of needed policy interventions.

  • Finally, a full assessment of sectoral balance sheets on welfare grounds needs to take explicitly into account the relevant trade-offs between reducing vulnerability (along the lines suggested by the BSA) and minimizing financial cost. Such an approach is clearly required, for instance, when evaluating financial system liquidity, currency and maturity composition of external debt, and optimal reserve accumulation.

The Balance Sheet Approach in Practice

The aim of the balance sheet approach (BSA) is to provide a comprehensive assessment of currency and maturity mismatches across different sectors of an economy. The composition and size of assets and liabilities of an economy’s main sectors provide information about the economy’s vulnerability to crisis and the channels by which one sector’s strengths or weaknesses could be transmitted to other sectors.

The operational foundation of the BSA is a matrix (see below) summarizing the asset and liability positions of the main sectors of the economy. Ideally, the analysis starts with a compilation of the data needed to fill the cells of this matrix for the public (including public enterprises), private financial, and private nonfinancial sectors vis-à-vis each other as well as the rest of the world. Data for the first two sectors are often readily available, while data for the nonfinancial private sector are usually harder to obtain. Information on the international investment position or external data sources (such as the Bank for International Settlements or the Special Data Dissemination Standard) can help in compiling the external position and deriving (as a residual) some of the unknown data elsewhere in the matrix. Data limitations notwithstanding, the insights from even a partial analysis can be useful. Where data availability permits, the BSA can be augmented by including off-balance-sheet items, such as contingent claims or derivatives. A higher degree of sectoral disaggregation and a breakdown by instrument could also be useful, where data permit. Further, linkages across economies could be examined to assess possible routes for contagion.

The data in the matrix can then be used to quantify sectoral mismatches in the short and the medium term. From a vulnerability viewpoint, the most important classes of assets and liabilities would be those denominated in foreign currency, and their position vis-à-vis the rest of the world. In a second stage, there is the possibility of conducting stress tests, for example, by simulating a change in market valuations of sectoral assets. One could also simulate a depreciation of the domestic currency. However, since the main point of the BSA is to highlight the coverage of foreign-currency-denominated liabilities by corresponding assets, the discrepancy between these two is already an indicator of the stress that an economy would be exposed to in the event of a depreciation.

Intersectoral Asset and Liability Position

article image
2

The change in stock is a combination of changes in valuation of the existing stock of assets and liabilities, and net additions to the stock from flows during the preceding period.

3

For the purposes of the following analysis, it is most important to distinguish assets that in the event of a crisis are under the control of the country authorities from those that are controlled by the private sector. To simplify the presentation, the separation of the government and the central bank is therefore not highlighted. The distinction between monetary and fiscal authorities—part of the internationally accepted statistical guidelines—is, of course, important for many other purposes, not least to reflect central bank independence and also the IMF’s lending to a country’s monetary as opposed to its fiscal authorities. In general, the statistical format used here can be adjusted to that of the System of National Accounts 1993—with flexibility in the sectorization of an economy and taking into account country circumstances.

4

In official balance of payments statistics, the balance sheet of the stock of external financial assets and liabilities, broken down in four sectors, is referred to as the international investment position (see International Monetary Fund, 1993).

5

Pettis (2001) and others whose analyses are grounded in corporate finance use the term “capital structure” to refer to the maturity and currency composition of an entity’s debts, as well as the debt to equity ratio. Because maturity and currency risk are of particular importance for countries, this paper isolates these sources of risk. This paper uses the term capital structure only to refer to the balance between debt and equity, not to the currency and maturity composition of debt.

6

This is not an exhaustive list of the risks to a balance sheet. Moreover, there are other possible ways of breaking down various types of balance sheet risks than those discussed in this paper: for example, one could identify rollover risks, market risks (which would include both currency and interest rate risk), credit risk, operational risk, and solvency risks. The categorization laid out here has the advantage of highlighting the underlying mismatches that create sources of vulnerability from a debtor’s perspective.

7

See also “Data Provision to the Fund for Surveillance Purposes” (International Monetary Fund, 2002a).

  • Collapse
  • Expand
  • Aghion, Philippe, Philippe Bacchetta, and Abhijit Banerjee, 2000, “A Simple Model of Monetary Policy and Currency Crises,” European Economic Review, Vol. 44 (May), pp. 72838.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Aghion, Philippe, Philippe Bacchetta, and Abhijit Banerjee, 2001a, “Currency Crises and Monetary Policy in an Economy with Credit Constraints,” European Economic Review, Vol. 45 (June), pp. 112150.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Aghion, Philippe, Philippe Bacchetta, and Abhijit Banerjee, 2001b, “A Corporate Balance Sheet Approach to Currency Crises,” Discussion Paper No. 3092 (London: Centre for Economic Policy Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Allen, Mark, Christoph B. Rosenberg, Christian Keller, Brad Setser, and Nouriel Roubini, 2002, “A Balance Sheet Approach to Financial Crisis,” IMF Working Paper No. 02/210 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Baliño, Tomás J.T., Adam Bennett, and Eduardo Borensztein, 1999, Monetary Policy in Dollarized Economies, IMF Occasional Paper No. 171 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Borensztein, Eduardo, and Paolo Mauro, 2002, “Reviving the Case for GDP-Indexed Bonds,” IMF Policy Discussion Paper No. 02/10 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Borensztein, Eduardo, Marcos Chamon, Olivier Jeanne, Paulo Mauro, and Jeromin Zettelmeyer, 2004, Sovereign Debt Structure for Crisis Prevention, IMF Occasional Paper No. 237 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Burnside, Craig, Martin Eichenbaum, and Sergio Rebelo, 1998, “Prospective Deficits and the Asian Currency Crisis,” NBER Working Paper No. 6758 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bussière, Matthieu, and Christian Mulder, 1999, “External Vulnerability in Emerging Market Economies: How High Liquidity Can Offset Weak Fundamentals and the Effects of Contagion,” IMF Working Paper No. 99/88 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Caballero, Ricardo J., and Arvind Krishnamurthy, 2000, “Dollarization of Liabilities: Underinsurance and Domestic Financial Underdevelopment,” NBER Working Paper No. 7792 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Calvo, Guillermo, 1998, “Capital Flows and Capital-Market Crises: The Simple Economics of Sudden Stops,” Journal of Applied Economics, Vol. 1 (November), pp. 3554.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Calvo, Guillermo, and Carmen M. Reinhart, 2000, “When Capital Inflows Suddenly Stop: Consequences and Policy Options,” in Reforming the International Monetary and Financial System, ed. by Peter B. Kenen and Alexander K. Swoboda (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Calvo, Guillermo, and Carmen M. Reinhart, 2002, “Fear of Floating,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 117, No. 2 (May), pp. 379408.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Calvo, Guillermo, Alejandro Izquierdo, and Luis-Fernando Mejía, 2004, “On the Empirics of Sudden Stops: The Relevance of Balance-Sheet Effects,” NBER Working Paper No. 10520 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cavallo, Michele, Kate Kisselev, Fabrizio Perri, and Nouriel Roubini, 2002, “Exchange Rate Overshooting and the Costs of Floating” (unpublished; New York: New York University).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Céspedes, Luis Felipe, Roberto Chang, and Andrés Velasco, 2000, “Balance Sheets and Exchange Rate Policy,” NBER Working Paper No. 7840 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Chang, Roberto, and Andrés Velasco, 1999, “Liquidity Crises in Emerging Markets: Theory and Policy,” NBER WorkingPaperNo. 7272 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cole, Harold L., and Patrick J. Kehoe, 1996, “A Self-Fulfilling Model of Mexico’s 1994–1995 Debt Crisis,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 41 (November), pp. 30930.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Collyns, Charles, and G. Russell Kincaid, eds. 2003, Managing Financial Crises: Recent Experience and Lessons for Latin America, IMF Occasional Paper No. 217 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Corsetti, Giancarlo, Paolo Pesenti, and Nouriel Roubini, 1999a, “What Caused the Asian Currency and Financial Crisis?Japan and the World Economy, Vol. 11 (October), pp. 30573.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Corsetti, Giancarlo, Paolo Pesenti, and Nouriel Roubini, 1999b, “Paper Tigers? A Model of the Asian Crisis,” European Economic Review, Vol. 43 (June), pp. 121136.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Corsetti, Giancarlo, Amil Dasgupta, Stephen Morris, and Hyun Song Shin 2004, “Does One Soros Make a Difference? A Theory of Currency Crises with Large and Small Traders,” Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 71 (January), pp. 87113.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Daseking, Christina, Atish Ghosh, Timothy Lane, and Alun Thomas, 2004, Lessons from the Crisis in Argentina, IMF Occasional Paper No. 236 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • De Nicoló, Gianni, Patrick Honohan, and Alain Ize, 2003, “Dollarization of the Banking System: Good or Bad?IMF Working Paper No. 03/146 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Diamond, Douglas, and Philip Dybvig, 1983, “Bank Runs, Deposit Insurance, and Liquidity,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 91 (June), pp. 40119.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Diamond, Douglas W., and Raghuram G. Rajan, 2000, “Banks, Short Term Debt and Financial Crises: Theory, Policy Implications and Applications,” NBER Working Paper No. 7764 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Drazen, Allan, and Paul R. Masson, 1994, “Credibility of Policies Versus Credibility of Policymakers,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 109 (August), pp. 73554.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dornbusch, Rudiger, 2001, “A Primer on Emerging Market Crises,” NBER Working Paper No. 8326 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Edwards, Sebastian, 2001, “Dollarization: Myths and Realities,” Journal of Policy Modeling, Vol. 23 (April), pp. 24965.

  • Eichengreen, Barry, Ricardo Hausmann, and Ugo Panizza, 2003, “Currency Mismatches, Debt Intolerance and Original Sin: Why They Are Not the Same and Why It Matters,” NBER Working Paper No. 10036 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Flood, Robert P., and Peter M. Garber, 1984, “Collapsing Exchange-Rate Regimes: Some Linear Examples,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 17 (August), pp. 113.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gapen, Michael T., Dale F. Gray, Cheng Hoon Lim, and Yingbin Xiao, 2004, “The Contingent Claims Approach to Corporate Vulnerability Analysis: Estimating Default Risk and Economy-Wide Risk Transfer,” IMF Working Paper No. 04/121 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Garcia, Marcio, and Roberto Rigobon, 2004, “A Risk Management Approach to Emerging Market’s Sovereign Debt Sustainability with an Application to Brazilian Data,” NBER Working Paper No. 10336 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gertler, Mark, Simon Gilchrist, and Fabio Natalucci, 2003, “External Constraints on Monetary Policy and the Financial Accelerator,” NBER Working Paper No. 10128 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Goldstein, Morris, and Philip Turner, 2004, Controlling Currency Mismatches in Emerging Markets (Washington: Institute for International Economics).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gulde, Anne-Marie, David Hoelscher, Alain Ize, Alfredo Leone, David Marston, and Marina Moretti, 2003, “Dealing with Banking Crises in Dollarized Economies,” in Managing Financial Crises: Recent Experience and Lessons from Latin America, ed. Collyns Charles Kincaid, G. Russell IMF Occasional Paper No. 217 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hagan, Sean, Eliot Kalter, and Rhoda Weeks-Brown, 2003, “Corporate Debt Restructuring in the Wake of Economic Crisis,” in Managing Financial Crises: Recent Experience and Lessons from Latin America, ed. Collyns Charles Kincaid, G. Russell IMF Occasional Paper No. 217 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Havrylyshyn, Oleh, and Christian Beddies, 2003, “Dollarization in the Former Soviet Union: From Hysteria to Hysteresis,” Contemporary Economic Studies, Vol. 45, No. 3, pp. 32957.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, 1993, Balance of Payments Manual, 5th ed. (Washington).

  • International Monetary Fund, 2002a, “Data Provision to the Fund for Surveil-lance Purposes,” available at www.imf.org/external/np/sta/data/prov/2002/042602.htm.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, 2002b, “Assessing Sustainability,” available at www.imf.org/external/np/pdr/sus/2002/eng/052802.htm.

  • International Monetary Fund, 2003a, World Economic Outlook, September, World Economic and Financial Surveys (Washington).

  • International Monetary Fund, 2003b, External Debt Statistics: Guide for Compilers and Users (Washington).

  • International Monetary Fund, 2003c, “Slovak Republic: 2003 Article IV Consultation—Staff Report, Public Information Notice on the Executive Board Discussion; and Statement by the Executive Director for the Slovak Republic,” IMF Country Report No. 03/234 (Washington).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Jeanne, Olivier, and Charles Wyplosz, 2001, “The International Lender of Last Resort: How Large Is Large Enough?NBER Working Paper No. 8381 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • J.P. Morgan, 2002, Guide to Local Markets (New York).

  • Kaminsky, Graciela and Carmen Reinhart, 1999, “The Twin Crises: The Causes of Banking and Balance-of-Payments Problems,” American Economic Review, Vol. 89 (June), pp. 473500.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kester, Anne Y., 2001, International Reserves and Foreign Currency Liquidity: Guidelines for a Data Template (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Krugman, Paul 1979, “A Model of Balance-of-Payments Crises,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 11, No. 3 (August), pp. 31125.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Krugman, Paul 1998, “Curfews on Capital Flight: What Are the Options?available at http://web.mit.edu/krugman/www/curfews.html.

  • Krugman, Paul 1999, “Balance Sheets, the Transfer Problem, and Financial Crises,” in International Finance and Financial Crises: Essays in Honor of Robert P. Flood, Jr., ed. Isard, Peter Razin, Assaf Rose Andrew K. (Boston: Kluwer Academic; Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lagos, Martin 2002, “The Argentine Banking Crisis 2001–2002,” Report prepared for the Argentine Bankers Association.

  • Lindgren, Carl-Johan Tomás J.T. Baliño, Charles Enoch, Anne-Marie Gulde, Marc Quintyn, and Leslie Teo, 1999, Financial Sector Crisis and Restructuring—Lessons from Asia, IMF Occasional Paper No. 188 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Manasse, Paolo Nouriel Roubini, and Axel Schimmelpfennig, 2003, “Predicting Sovereign Debt Crises,” IMF Working Paper No. 03/221 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Masson, Paul R., 1999, “Multiple Equilibria, Contagion, and the Emerging Market Crises,” IMF Working Paper No. 99/164 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mongardini, Joannes, and Johannes Mueller, 2000, “Ratchet Effects in Currency Substitution: An Application to the Kyrgyz Republic,” IMF Staff Papers, Vol. 47, No. 2 (December), pp. 21837.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Morris, Stephen, and Hyun Song Shin, 2003, “Global Games: Theory and Applications,” in Advances in Economics and Econometrics: Theory and Applications, Eighth World Congress, Vol. 1., ed. Dewatripont, Mathias Hansen, Lars Peter Turnovsky Stephen (Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mulder, Christian B., Roberto Perrelli, and Manuel Rocha, 2002, “The Role of Corporate, Legal and Macroeconomic Balance Sheet Indicators in Crisis Detection and Prevention,” IMF Working Paper No. 02/59 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Obstfeld, Maurice, 1994, “The Logic of Currency Crises,” Cahiers Économiques et Monétaires (Bank of France), Vol. 43, pp. 189213.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Oomes, Nienke, 2003, “Network Externalities and Dollarization Hysteresis: The Case of Russia,” IMF Working Paper No. 03/96 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Pettis, Michael, 2001, The Volatility Machine: Emerging Economies and the Threat of Their Financial Collapse (New York: Oxford University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Reinhart, Carmen M., Kenneth S. Rogoff, and Miguel A. Savastano, 2003a, “Debt Intolerance,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: 1 (Brookings Institution), pp. 174.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Reinhart, Carmen M., Kenneth S. Rogoff, and Miguel A. Savastano, 2003b, “Addicted to Dollars,” NBER Working Paper No. 10015 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Rodrik, Dani, and Andrés Velasco, 1999, “Short-Term Capital Flows,” NBER Working Paper No. 7364 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Roubini, Nouriel, 2001, “Should Argentina Dollarize or Float? The Pros and Cons of Alternative Exchange Rate Regimes and their Implications for Domestic and Foreign Debt Restructuring Reduction” (unpublished; New York: Stern School of Business, New York University).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Sachs, Jeffrey, and Steven Radelet, 1998, “The Onset of the East Asian Financial Crisis,” NBER Working Paper No. 6680 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Schneider, Martin, and Aaron Tornell, 2000, “Balance Sheet Effects, Bailout Guarantees and Financial Crises,” NBER Working Paper No. 8060 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Zettelmeyer, Jeromin, and Olivier D. Jeanne, 2002, “‘Original Sin,’ Balance Sheet Crises, and the Roles of International Lending,” IMF Working Paper No. 02/234 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation