IV New Evidence on the Effect of Exchange Rate Volatility on Trade
Author:
Mr. Peter B. Clark
Search for other papers by Mr. Peter B. Clark in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
,
Shang-Jin Wei https://isni.org/isni/0000000404811396 International Monetary Fund

Search for other papers by Shang-Jin Wei in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
,
Ms. Natalia T. Tamirisa
Search for other papers by Ms. Natalia T. Tamirisa in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
,
Mr. Azim M Sadikov
Search for other papers by Mr. Azim M Sadikov in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
, and
Mr. Li Zeng
Search for other papers by Mr. Li Zeng in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close

Abstract

The effect of exchange rate volatility on trade flows was examined by a 1984 IMF study on G-7 countries. Over the past two decades, many developments in the world economy, such as the currency crises in the 1990s and increasing cross-border capital flows, may have exacerbated exchange rate volatility, while others, such as a deepening of the market in foreign exchange hedging instruments, may have reduced the impact of volatility on trade flows. Using recent advances in the economic theories on trade and in statistical methodologies, this paper revisits this important issue by taking into account these new developments and examining their effects on developing and transition economies, as well as on developed countries.

As discussed in Section II, theoretical models do not point unambiguously to a negative effect of exchange rate volatility on trade. Moreover, empirical analysis in the existing literature has not uncovered a strong causal impact that is consistently negative. In the empirical analysis reported in this section, there is no obvious negative relationship between aggregate exchange rate volatility and aggregate trade. Turning to bilateral trade, there is some evidence that exchange rate volatility tends to reduce trade. This negative effect, however, is not robust to alternative ways of controlling for factors that could affect trade. The key findings of this empirical analysis are summarized below, and the appendix describes the statistical results in more detail.

The objective of the empirical analysis is to examine the role of exchange rate volatility in trade in a comprehensive manner. Compared to the existing academic literature and the 1984 IMF paper on the topic, the contribution of this analysis lies in exploring the effect of exchange rate volatility on trade along several dimensions:

  • by the type of exchange rate volatility: examining a range of different exchange rate volatility measures—short- and long-run, real and nominal, official, IFS based and parallel market based, and conditional and unconditional;

  • by country group: testing if the impact of exchange rate volatility differs across country groupings, including industrial and developing countries; and

  • by the type of trade: examining the impact not only on aggregate but also on sectoral trade, which allows one to test if the effect of exchange rate volatility varies in direction and magnitude across different types of goods. The role of exchange rate volatility has not yet been explored extensively using disaggregated trade data.

In addition to the disaggregation of the volatility effect, tests were conducted to determine its robustness to alternative ways of controlling for joint causality between trade and exchange rates and for trade-related factors other than exchange rate volatility. Finally, while the focus is on exchange rate volatility, this provides an opportunity to revisit a related topic, the role of a common currency in enhancing trade flows, and to explore the robustness of the finding by Rose (2002) that this positive effect is very large.

Aggregate Volatility and Aggregate Trade—A First Look

It is instructive to look at the time paths of world trade and exchange rate volatility and examine if there is any obvious negative association between the two. Figure 4.1 shows the evolution of world trade since 1970 together with the average real effective volatility for all countries in the sample. There is a clear bulge in exchange rate volatility from 1989 to 1993, which reflects the large fluctuations in the currencies of a number of transition economies during this period in the aftermath of the breakup of the Soviet Union.20 If one excludes transition economies from the measure of world currency volatility, the bulge disappears. What then appears is an upward trend in average volatility from the early 1970s through the end of the 1980s, but a general moderation in the overall level of currency volatility since then.

Figure 4.1.
Figure 4.1.

Effective Volatility of the Real Exchange Rate and World Trade

1 Volatility is measured as the unweighted average of the real exchange rate volatility of the countries in the sample (left scale, in percent).2 World trade is measured as the average of the volume of world exports and imports in billions of 1995 U.S. dollars (right scale).

In comparison, world trade has increased steadily since 1970, and the growth rate is much more smooth than that of exchange rate volatility. Looking at the movement of world trade and aggregate volatility over time, there does not appear to be any clear relationship between them. Therefore, at the aggregate level there is no evidence of a negative effect of real exchange rate volatility on trade.

It may be useful to examine the relationship between the two by breaking down the sample by major country groups (Figure 4.2) and developing countries by geographic region (Figure 4.3) and by type of export (Figure 4.4). In some of the sub-samples and for some of the years, there appears to be a negative association between exchange rate volatility and the level of trade in certain country groupings. This is most evident in the case of transition economies in 1990–94 (lower left graph of Figure 4.2), the Asian crisis in 1997–98 (upper right graph of Figure 4.3), and economies exporting non-fuel primary products in the early 1980s (lower graph of Figure 4.4). This negative association may not reflect a causal relationship, however, but rather a manifestation of the effects of a common set of factors that both raise currency volatility and reduce trade. For example, the Asian crisis led to a large decline in the imports of the affected countries and major movements in their exchange rates, but the fall in domestic demand was the most important factor reducing import volumes—not currency volatility. Similarly, the breakup of the Soviet Union caused widespread dislocations in many transition economies, resulting in substantial falls in output and trade and huge changes in many exchange rates that were part and parcel of the transition process.

Figure 4.2.
Figure 4.2.

Effective Volatility of the Real Exchange Rate and Trade by Major Country Groups1

1 Trade is in billions of 1995 U.S. dollars; volatility is average of real exchange rate volatility.
Figure 4.3.
Figure 4.3.

Effective Volatility of the Real Exchange Rate and Trade of Developing Countries by Region1

1Trade is in billions of 1995 U.S. dollars; volatility is average of real exchange rate volatility.
Figure 4.4.
Figure 4.4.

Effective Volatility of the Real Exchange Rate and Trade of Developing Countries by Type of Export1

1 Trade is in billions of 1995 U.S. dollars; volatility is average of real exchange rate volatility.

In order to estimate the specific impact of exchange rate volatility on trade flows, it is necessary to take account of the separate effects of a myriad of factors that determine the level of exports and imports. The following moves away from aggregate trade and discusses a methodology that exploits the much richer variations in the data on bilateral trade and bilateral exchange rates, which in turn permit the identification of the distinct contribution of volatility on trade.

The Conceptual Framework for Analyzing the Volatility Effect in Trade

To investigate the effect of exchange rate volatility on trade, there are several building blocks to consider. First, there are factors other than exchange rate volatility that affect trade, and it is important to account for them in a way that is consistent with economic theory. Otherwise, one runs the risk of misattributing the effect of these other factors to exchange rate volatility. Second, the measure of exchange rate volatility should be conceptually reasonable. Third, it may be useful to allow exchange rate volatility to have different effects on different types of trade or trade in different country groupings. These building blocks are explained in turn.

As part of the first building block, one must account for the determinants of trade patterns other than exchange rate volatility in a modified gravity model. This model relates trade between a given pair of countries to characteristics of each of the two countries and the characteristics of their relationship to each other. The characteristics that are most important—to which the model owes its name—are the economic mass (i.e., GDP) and the distance between the countries. In addition, the empirical specifications of the gravity model typically control for other factors that augment or reduce trade, such as land areas, cultural similarity, geographical position, historical links, and preferential trading arrangements, all of which tend to affect the transaction costs relevant for bilateral trade and which have been found to be statistically significant determinants of trade in various empirical applications. Typically, the model also controls for the level of economic development, which is expected to have a positive effect on trade because the more developed countries tend to specialize and trade more (e.g., Frankel and Wei, 1993). The gravity model has been empirically successful in terms of its ability to explain a large part of the variations in the observed trade patterns. It also has the merit of being grounded in international trade theories, ranging from those based on country differences in factor endowments or technology to models of increasing returns to scale and monopolistic competition.

A relatively recent development in the theoretical foundation of the gravity model emphasizes “remoteness” or “multilateral resistance” effects. These effects were proposed by Anderson and van Wincoop (2003) and are defined as a function of unobservable equilibrium price indices that depend on bilateral trade barriers and income shares of all the trading partners. In other words, the multilateral resistance effects are catch-all expressions that summarize the effects on a given bilateral trade from differential, possibly unobserved, trade costs between this country pair and all other trading partners. The gravity equation can then be interpreted as indicating that bilateral trade depends on the bilateral trade barrier between the two countries in question, relative to the two countries’ multilateral resistance indices: for a given bilateral trade barrier between the two countries, higher barriers between them and their other trading partners would reduce the relative price of goods traded between them, thus raising bilateral trade. In empirical applications, the multilateral resistance indices can be conveniently proxied by country effects (fixed or time varying). Also included are time effects in the model to control for time-specific factors, such as world business cycles, global shocks, etc.

The second building block is the measure of exchange rate volatility. The focus of the benchmark model is on the long-run measure of IFS-based real exchange rate volatility. Its value in any given year, t, is calculated as the standard deviation of the first-difference of the monthly natural logarithm of the bilateral real exchange rate in the five years preceding year t, which is a conventional measure most commonly used in the current literature on the subject. To check the robustness of results, alternative—yet analogously calculated—measures of exchange rate volatility are examined: long-run IFS-based nominal exchange rate volatility; short-run, contemporaneous IFS-based real and nominal exchange rate volatility; and the short-and long-run volatility of real parallel market rates using data from Reinhart and Rogoff (2002). Also considered as an additional robustness analysis are the conditional volatilities of real exchange rates, which are estimated using a GARCH (1, 1) model. To ensure the stationarity of the GARCH model, countries with hyperinflation episodes, extreme exchange rate fluctuations, and/or incomplete data are excluded, focusing the estimation on 124 industrial, developing, emerging, and transition economies.

The third building block for the model is the consideration of different country groups and different types of trade. An analysis of the exchange rate volatility effect was conducted separately for industrial countries and developing countries. The separate effects of exchange rate volatility are allowed for, depending on the type of product trade—differentiated or homogeneous. The classification of products into differentiated and homogenous varieties follows the strategy in Rauch (1999). Conceptually, Rauch first identifies two types of homogenous products: those traded on an organized exchange (commodities) and those whose prices are reported regularly in a professional trade publication (referenced price products). All other products are then defined as differentiated products.

What the Data Tell Us

The gravity model performs well empirically, yielding precise and generally reasonable estimates. The coefficient on distance is negative and statistically significant, while the coefficient on the economic mass is positive and statistically significant. Most other control variables are also mostly significant and have the expected signs.

Does Exchange Rate Volatility Hamper Trade?

As a benchmark specification using country and time-fixed effects, one finds that the long-run real exchange rate volatility has a statistically significant negative effect on trade (Table 4.1, column 1, row 1). If exchange rate volatility were to rise by one standard deviation (from 0.12 to 0.15, for example, in the sample), trade would fall by about 7 percent (Table 4.1, column 2, row 1).21 This effect is comparable to the estimates found by previous studies, e.g., Rose (2000) and Tenreyro (2003).

Table 4.1.

Effect of Long-Run Real Exchange Rate Volatility on Aggregate Trade1

article image

Standard errors are in parentheses. An asterisk denotes significance at the 90 percent level or higher. For details, see Appendix Tables A9 and A10.

Is the Negative Effect on Trade Robust to Alternative Ways of Controlling for Factors Other Than Bilateral Exchange Rate Volatility?

The answer is no. On the one hand, a negative effect is still observed when controlling for unobservable cultural, economic, historical, geographical, and other factors specific to a given pair of countries rather than individual countries (Table 4.1, column 1, row 2). On the other hand, no negative effect is found when country-specific effects are allowed to vary over time, as appears justified theoretically, given the dynamic nature of multilateral resistance. Indeed, in some cases this specification could even result in a positive coefficient (Table 4.1, column 1, row 3). While this does not necessarily imply that volatility promotes trade, it suggests that the finding of a negative effect of exchange rate volatility on trade is not robust.

A note of caution is in order here. Recent developments in the theoretical foundation of a gravity specification suggest that it is important to include time-varying country-fixed effects in order to fully absorb the multilateral resistance effects. Otherwise, one might misattribute to exchange rate volatility those effects on bilateral trade that should have been attributed to other factors. At the same time, it should be noted that part of the forces underlining bilateral exchange rate volatility is time varying and country specific. The inclusion of the time-varying, country-fixed effects could also overcorrect. For example, an unexpected increase in one country’s money supply could raise all the bilateral exchange rate volatility involving that country. Even if this increase in volatility depresses all bilateral trade involving that country, a specification that controls for the country’s time-varying fixed effects would not be able to reveal a negative effect of exchange rate volatility on trade. This qualification should be kept in mind in interpreting the result.

Sorting Out Causality

To the extent that countries implement policies aimed at lowering exchange rate volatility in order to increase bilateral trade, the model considered so far would suffer from an endogeneity bias. Two instrumental variable approaches are used to control for this possibility: that proposed by Frankel and Wei (1993), whereby the volatility in the relative quantity of money is used as an instrumental variable for exchange rate volatility; and that implemented by Tenreyro (2003), which relates the exchange rate volatility to the propensity of countries to adopt a common currency anchor. Neither of these approaches is perfect, and each has its advantages: the Frankel-Wei approach appeals to the monetary theory of exchange rate determination and is simple and easy to implement, while the Tenreyro approach appeals to the optimal currency framework, as described in Alesina, Barro, and Tenreyro (2002). There is no significant effect of exchange rate volatility on trade in the models with country-pair and time-varying country effects (Table 4.1, column 3, row 2 and column 3, row 3). The negative volatility effect found in the model with constant country effects, however, survives (Table 4.1, column 3, row 1).

Does the Conclusion Change When Alternative Measures of Volatility Are Employed?

The short answer is no. Table 4.2 reports results from the same regression, which includes our standard long-run measure together with all three alternative measures of exchange rate volatility (as differences from the long-run real IFS-based measure). The short-run volatility in the real exchange rate appears to discourage trade, albeit to a smaller extent than the long-run volatility. The volatility in the parallel market exchange rates has a similar effect on trade as the volatility in the IFS-reported exchange rates, but only in the long run. As shown in Appendix Tables A11 and A12, the volatilities of the nominal and real exchange rates are highly correlated and thus have similar effects on trade. In addition, conditioning the measure of exchange rate volatility on historical information using the GARCH approach, instead of the simple statistical measure of volatility, also preserves the negative relationship with trade. As in Table 4.1, when time-varying country fixed effects are controlled for, there is no longer evidence of a negative and significant association between volatility and trade.

Table 4.2.

Alternative Measures of Exchange Rate Volatility1

article image

Standard errors are indicated in parentheses. An asterisk denotes significance at the 90 percent level or higher. For details, refer to Appendix Tables A11, A12, and A13.

In excess of long-run real official exchange rate volatility.

Does Exchange Rate Volatility Have a Different Effect on Trade in Differentiated or Homogeneous Products?

Recent developments in the economics of trade suggest that a given increase in transaction costs (of which exchange rate volatility is a component) could have a larger, negative effect on trade in differentiated products than on trade in homogenous products. But, as with aggregate trade, the estimation results show that this theoretical prior is not robust. When country and time effects are controlled for separately, exchange rate volatility indeed has a negative effect on trade in differentiated products, but not on trade in homogenous products (Table 4.3, column 1). When, however, time-varying country fixed effects are included (Table 4.3, column 3), the conclusion is overturned, as in the aggregate trade model.

Table 4.3.

Effect of Exchange Rate Volatility on Trade in Different Types of Products1

article image

Standard errors are indicated in parentheses. An asterisk denotes significance at the 90 percent level or higher. For details, refer to Appendix Table A14.

Do Members in Currency Unions Trade More?

The core results confirm the finding of Rose (2000) that common currency arrangements triple trade. Apparently, the trade-enhancing benefits of currency unions exceed by far gains from a reduction in exchange rate volatility and are preserved over time (Appendix Tables A9 and A11). They are also robust to controlling for time-varying country effects, but break down in a model with country-pair fixed effects (Appendix Table A12). This suggests that currency union membership may be correlated with other country-pair characteristics. Once these characteristics are controlled for by the inclusion of country-pair fixed effects, there is no additional trade-promoting effect from currency unions.

Does the Volatility Effect Differ Across Country Groups?

In principle, the effects could be different. Foreign exchange markets are typically less developed and less liquid in developing countries, thereby limiting firms’ opportunities for hedging foreign exchange risk. Indeed, volatile exchange rates are more likely to be associated with the smaller trade of developing countries than with trade among advanced economies in the specification with country-fixed effects. The negative effect disappears for both country groups, however, when country effects are time varying (Appendix Table A15). As hedging instruments become more readily available for the currencies of industrial countries, one might expect that their trade would be less affected by exchange rate volatility. Wei (1999), however, finds little support for the hypothesis that the growing availability of hedging instruments is responsible for the small impact of volatility on trade.

On balance, for both aggregate and disaggregated trade there is empirical evidence pointing to a generally small negative effect of exchange rate volatility on trade. But this evidence is not overwhelming and not robust across different empirical specifications.

20

Data for transition countries are not reported before 1988 because most of these countries did not exist before 1991. Data are available for Yugoslavia only from 1970 and for Hungary beginning in 1976. The effective volatilities for the major country groupings shown in Figures 4.24.4 do include, however, the available bilateral exchange rate data for transition countries, weighted by appropriate trade shares.

21

This impact is computed as the estimated coefficient in the regression equation multiplied by one standard deviation of the volatility measure, multiplied by 100 to convert to percent.

  • Collapse
  • Expand
  • Figure 4.1.

    Effective Volatility of the Real Exchange Rate and World Trade

  • Figure 4.2.

    Effective Volatility of the Real Exchange Rate and Trade by Major Country Groups1

  • Figure 4.3.

    Effective Volatility of the Real Exchange Rate and Trade of Developing Countries by Region1

  • Figure 4.4.

    Effective Volatility of the Real Exchange Rate and Trade of Developing Countries by Type of Export1

  • Alesina, Alberto and Robert J. Barro, 2000, “Currency Unions,” NBER Working Paper 7927 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Alesina, Alberto and Robert J. Barro, and Silvana Tenreyro, 2002, “Optimal Currency Areas,” NBER Working Paper 9072 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Andersen, Margot, and David A. Grier, 1992, “Robust, Non-Parametric Measures of Exchange Rate Variability,” Applied Economics, Vol. 24 (September), pp. 95158.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Andersen, Torben, and others 2001, “The Distribution of Realized Exchange Rate Volatility,” Journal of the American Statistical Association, Vol. 96 (March), pp. 4255.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Anderson, James E., 1979, “A Theoretical Foundation for the Gravity Equation,” American Economic Review, Vol. 69, No. 1, pp. 10616.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Anderson, James E., and Eric van Wincoop, 2003, “Gravity with Gravitas: A Solution to the Border Puzzle,” American Economic Review, Vol. 93(March),17092.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Anderton, Robert, Frauke Skudelny, 2001, “Exchange Rate Volatility and Euro Area Imports,” ECB Working Paper No. 64 (Frankfurt: European Central Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Arize, Augustine C., 1998, “The Long-Run Relationship Between Import Flows and Real Exchange-Rate Volatility: the Experience of Eight European Economies,” International Review of Economics and Finance, Vol. 7, pp. 41735.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bacchetta, Philippe, and Eric van Wincoop, 2000, “Does Exchange-Rate Stability Increase Trade and Welfare?American Economic Review, Vol. 90 (December), pp. 1093109.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bélanger, Denis, and others 1992, “Impact of Exchange Rate Variability on Trade Flows: Further Results on Sectoral U.S. Imports from Canada,” North American Journal of Economics and Finance, Vol. 3, pp. 6182.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bergin, Paul R., and Ivan Tchakarov, 2003, “Does Exchange Rate Risk Matter for Welfare?NBER Working Paper 9900 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bergstrand, Jeffrey H., 1985, “Gravity Equation in International Trade: Some Microeconomic Foundations and Empirical Evidence,” Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 67 (August), pp. 47481.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bini-Smaghi, Lorenzo, 1991, “Exchange Rate Variability and Trade: Why Is It So Difficult To Find Any Empirical Relationship?Applied Economics, Vol. 23 (May), pp. 92735.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bleaney, Michael, 1992, “Comparisons of Real Exchange Rate Volatility Across Exchange Rate Systems,” Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 54 (November), pp. 55765.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bollerslev, Tim Ray Y. Chou, Kenneth F. Kroner, 1992, “ARCH Modeling in Finance: A Review of Theory and Empirical Evidence,” Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 52 (April–May), pp. 559.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Broda, Christian, and John Romalis, 2003, “Identifying the Effect of Exchange Rate Volatility on Trade,” unpublished manuscript, Federal Reserve Bank of New York and Chicago Graduate School of Business.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Brodsky, David A., 1984, “Fixed Versus Flexible Exchange Rates and the Measurement of Exchange Rate Instability,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 16 (May), pp. 295306.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bubula, Andrea, and Ïnci Ötker-Robe, 2002, “The Evolution of Exchange Rate Regimes Since 1990: Evidence from De Facto Policies,” IMF Working Paper 02/155 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Caballero, Ricardo J., Vittorio Corbo, 1989, “The Effect of Real Exchange Rate Uncertainty on Exports: Empirical Evidence,” The World Bank Economic Review, Vol. 3 (Washington: World Bank), pp. 26378.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Canzoneri, Matthew B., and others, 1984, “Effects of Exchange Rate Variability on Output and Employment,” International Finance Discussion Papers No. 240 (Washington: U.S. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Clark, Peter B., 1973, “Uncertainty, Exchange Risk, and the Level of International Trade,” Western Economic Journal, Vol. 11 (September), pp. 30213.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Coe, David T., and others, 2002, “The Missing Globalization Puzzle,” IMF Working Paper 02/171 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Côté, Agathe, 1994, “Exchange Rate Volatility and Trade,” Working Paper No. 94-5 (Ontario: Bank of Canada).

  • Cushman, David O., 1983, “The Effects of Real Exchange Rate Risk on International Trade,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 15 (August), pp. 4363.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cushman, David O., 1986, “Has Exchange Risk Depressed International Trade? The Impact of Third-Country Exchange Risk,” Journal of International Money and Finance, Vol. 5 (September), pp. 36179.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Deardorff, Alan V., 1998, “Determinants of Bilateral Trade: Does Gravity Work in a Neoclassical World?in The Regionalization of the World Economy, ed. by J. Frankel (Chicago: University of Chicago Press), pp. 722.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • De Grauwe, Paul, 1987, “International Trade and Economic Growth in the European Monetary System,” European Economic Review, Vol. 31 (February–March), pp. 38998.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • De Grauwe, Paul, 1988, “Exchange Rate Variability and the Slowdown in the Growth of International Trade,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 35 (March), pp. 6384.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • De Grauwe, Paul, 1992, “The Benefits of a Common Currency,” The Economics of Monetary Integration (New York: Oxford University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • De Grauwe, Paul, and Bernard de Bellefroid, 1987, “Long Run Exchange Rate Variability and International Trade,” in Real Financial Linkages Among Open Economies, ed. by S. Arndt and J. D. Richardson(London and Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dell’Ariccia, Giovanni, 1999, “Exchange Rate Fluctuations and Trade Flows: Evidence from the European Union,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 46 (September–December), pp. 31534.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Devereux, Michael B., Philip R. Lane, 2003, “Understanding Bilateral Exchange Rate Volatility,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 60 (May), pp. 10932.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dixit, A., 1989, “Entry and Exit Decisions Under Uncertainty,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 97 (June), pp. 62038.

  • Edison, Hali J., and Michael Melvin, 1990, “The Determinants and Implications of the Choice of an Exchange Rate System,” in Monetary Policy for a Volatile Global Economy, ed. by William S. Haraf and Thomas D. Willett(Washington: AEI Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ethier, Wilfred, 1973, “International Trade and the Forward Exchange Market,” American Economic Review, Vol. 63 (June), pp. 494503.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Farrell, Victoria S., Dean A. DeRosa, and T. Ashby McCown, 1983, “Effects of Exchange Rate Variability on International Trade and Other Economic Variables: A Review of the Literature,” Working Paper (Washington: U.S. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Feenstra, Robert C., Jon D. Kendall, 1991, “Exchange Rate Volatility and International Prices,” NBER Working Paper 3644 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Flandreau, Marc, and Mathilde Maurel, 2001, “Monetary Union, Trade Integration and Business Cycles in 19th Century Europe: Just Do It,” CEPR Discussion Paper No. 3087 (London: Centre For Economic Policy Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fountas, Stilianos, and Kyriacos Aristotelous, 1999, “Has the European Monetary System Led to More Exports? Evidence from Four European Union Countries,” Economic Letter, Vol. 62 (March), pp. 35763.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Franke, Gunter, 1991, “Exchange Rate Volatility and International Trading Strategy,” Journal of International Money and Finance, Vol. 10 (June), pp. 292307.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Frankel, Jeffrey A., and Andrew K. Rose, 1998, “The Endogeneity of the Optimum Currency Area Criteria,” Economic Journal, Vol. 108 (July), pp. 100925.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Frankel, Jeffrey A., and Andrew K. Rose, and Andrew K. Rose, 2000, “Estimating the Effect of Currency Unions on Trade and Output,” NBER Working Paper 7857 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Frankel, Jeffrey A., and Shang-Jin Wei, 1993, “Trade Blocs and Currency Blocs,” NBER Working Paper 4335 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Glick, Reuven, and Andrew K. Rose, 2002, “Does a Currency Union Affect Trade? The Time Series Evidence,” European Economic Review, Vol. 46 (June), pp. 112551.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Greene, William H., 2000, Econometric Analysis (Upper Saddle River, New Jersey: Prentice Hall).

  • Gros, Daniel, 1987, “Exchange Rate Variability and Foreign Trade in the Presence of Adjustment Costs,” Working Paper No. 8704, Département des sciences économiques, Université Catholique de Louvain.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Helpman, Elhanan, and Paul Krugman, 1985, Market Structure and Foreign Trade: Increasing Returns, Imperfect Competition and the International Economy (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hodrick, Robert J., 1989, “Risk, Uncertainty, and Exchange Rates,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 23 (May), pp. 43359.

  • Hooper, Peter, and Steven Kohlhagen, 1978, “The Effect of Exchange Rate Uncertainty on the Prices and Volume of International Trade,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 8 (November), pp. 483511.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hooper, Peter, and Catherine Mann, 1987, “The U.S. External Deficit: Its Causes and Persistence,” Working Paper (Washington: Federal Reserve Board).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, 1984, The Exchange Rate System: Lessons of the Past and Options for the Future, IMF Occasional Paper No. 30 (Washington).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, and 2003a, World Economic Outlook, World Economic and Financial Surveys (Washington).

  • International Monetary Fund, and 2003b, Exchange Arrangements and Foreign Exchange Markets: Developments and Issues, World Economic and Financial Surveys (Washington).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kawai, Masahiro, and Iizhak Zilcha, 1986, “International Trade with Forward-Futures Markets Under Exchange-Rate and Price Uncertainty,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 20 (February), pp. 8398.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kenen, Peter, 2002, “Currency Unions and Trade: Variations on Themes by Rose and Persson,” Discussion Paper DP/2002/08 (Wellington: Reserve Bank of New Zealand).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kenen, Peter, and Dani Rodrik, 1986, “Measuring and Analyzing the Effects of Short-Term Volatility on Real Exchange Rates,” Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 68 (May), pp. 31115.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Koren, Miklos, and Adam Szeidl, 2003, “Exchange Rate Uncertainty and Export Prices,” mimeo, Harvard University.

  • Krugman, Paul, 1989, “Exchange-Rate Instability,” L. Robbins lecture series (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press).

  • Kumar, Vikram, and Joseph A. Whitt, 1992, “Exchange Rate Variability and International Trade,” Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta, Economic Review, Vol. 37 (May/June), pp. 1732.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lanyi, Anthony, and Esther Suss, 1982, “Exchange Rate Variability: Alternative Measures and Interpretation,” IMF Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 29 (December), pp. 52760.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Makin, John H., 1978, “Portfolio Theory and the Problem of Foreign Exchange Risk,” Journal of Finance, Vol. 33 (May), pp. 51734.

  • McCallum, John, 1995, “National Borders Matter: Canada-U.S. Regional Trade Patterns,” American Economic Review, Vol. 85 (June), pp. 61523.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • McDonald, Robert L., and Daniel Siegel, 1986, “The Value of Waiting to Invest,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 101 (November), pp. 70727.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • McKenzie, Michael D., 1999, “The Impact of Exchange Rate Volatility on International Trade Flows,” Journal of Economic Surveys, Vol. 13 (February), pp. 71106.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Meese, Richard A., and Kenneth Rogoff, 1983, “Empirical Exchange Rate Models of the Seventies: Do They Fit Out of Sample?Journal of International Economics, Vol. 14 (February), pp. 324.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Micco, Alejandro, Ernesto Stein, and Guillermo Ordoñez, 2003, “The Currency Union Effect on Trade: Early Evidence from EMU,” Economic Policy, Vol. 37 (October), pp. 31543 and 34856.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mundell, Robert, 1961, “A Theory of Optimum Currency Areas,” American Economic Review, Vol. 51 (September), pp. 65765.

  • Nitsch, Volker, 2002, “Honey, I Shrunk the Currency Union Effect on Trade,” World Economy, Vol. 25 (April), pp. 45774.

  • Obstfeld, Maurice, and Kenneth Rogoff, 1998, “Risk and Exchange Rates,” NBER Working Paper 6694 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Pakko, Michael R., and Howard J. Wall, 2001, “Reconsidering the Trade Creating Effect of Currency Unions,” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, September/October.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Parsley, David, and Shang-Jin Wei, 2001, “Limiting Currency Volatility to Stimulate Goods Market Integration: A Price-Based Approach,” IMF Working Paper 01/197 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Persson, Torsten, 2001, “Currency Union and Trade: How Large Is the Treatment Effect?Economic Policy: A European Forum, No. 33 (October), pp. 43348.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Pindyck, Robert S., 1982, “Adjustment Costs, Uncertainty, and the Behavior of the Firm,” American Economic Review, Vol. 72 (June), pp. 41527.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Polak, Jacques J., 1988, “The Choice of an Exchange Rate Regime,” in Development Issues in the Current International Monetary System: Essays in Honor of Byanti Khoswaman, ed. by Dahlan M. Sutalaksana (Singapore: Addision Wesley).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Pozo, Susan, 1992, “Are Flexible Exchange Rates Really More Volatile? Evidence from the Early 1900s,” Applied Economics, Vol. 24 (November), pp. 121318.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Prasad, Eswar, and others, 2003, Effects of Financial Globalization on Developing Countries: Some Empirical Evidence, IMF Occasional Paper No. 220 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Rauch, James E., 1999, “Networks Versus Markets in International Trade,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 48 (June), pp. 735.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Reinhart, Carmen M., and Kenneth S. Rogoff, 2002, “A Modern History of Exchange Rate Arrangements: A Reinterpretation,” NBER Working Paper 8963 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Rogoff, Kenneth, and others 2004, Evolution and Performance of Exchange Rate Regimes, IMF Occasional Paper No. 229 (Washington, International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Rose, Andrew K., 2000, “One Money, One Market: The Effect of Common Currencies on Trade,” Economic Policy, No. 30 (April), pp. 945.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Rose, Andrew K., 2002, “Do We Really Know That the WTO Increases Trade?NBER Working Paper 9273 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Rose, Andrew K., and Engel, Charles, 2000, “Currency Unions and International Integration,” NBER Working Paper 7872 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Rose, Andrew K., and van Wincoop, Eric 2001, “National Money as a Barrier to International Trade: The Real Case for Currency Union,” American Economic Review, Vol. 91 (May), pp. 386390.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Sercu, Piet, and Cynthia Vanhulle, 1992, “Exchange Rate Volatility, International Trade, and the Value of Exporting Firms,” Journal of Banking and Finance, Vol. 16 (February), pp. 15582.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Smith, Christie, 2002, “Currency Unions and Gravity Models Revisited,” Discussion Paper DP/2002/07 (Wellington: Reserve Bank of New Zealand).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Tenreyro, Silvana, 2003, “On the Trade Impact of Nominal Exchange Rate Volatility,” Working Paper 03-2 (Boston, Massachusetts: Federal Reserve Bank of Boston).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Tenreyro, Silvana, and Barro, Robert J.Economic Effects of Currency Unions,” NBER Working Paper 9435 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • U. K. Treasury, 2003, “Euro 2003: EMU and Trade,” Available via the Internet: www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/.

  • Viaene, Jean-Marie, and Casper G. de Vries, 1992, “International Trade and Exchange Rate Volatility,” European Economic Review, Vol. 36 (August), pp. 131121.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Wei, Shang-Jin, 1999, “Currency Hedging and Goods Trade,” European Economic Review, Vol. 43 (June), pp. 137194.

  • World Trade Organization, 2003, “Trade Restrictions for Balance-of-Payments Purposes—Note on Issues Raised by Developing Countries in the Doha Round,” WT, TF/COH/13 (Geneva).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation