IV Potential Benefits and Costs of a Common Currency for GCC Countries
Author:
Ms. Andrea Schaechter
Search for other papers by Ms. Andrea Schaechter in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close

Abstract

Why do countries decide to join or form a monetary union? The literature on optimum currency areas, initiated by Mundell’s seminal paper (1961), has extensively discussed the potential benefits and costs of monetary unions.1 Countries can gain from a monetary union through lower transaction costs and the elimination of exchange rate variability, spurring investment, intraregional trade, and economic growth. Other benefits are access to bigger financial markets—lowering borrowing costs—and the potential enforcement of monetary and fiscal discipline. The main costs are the loss of national monetary and exchange rate policies. The magnitude of those costs depends on how symmetrical the economies are in terms of business cycles and vulnerability to shocks and the ease with which the economies can adjust to disturbances. These costs are likely to be lower the higher the degree of labor market flexibility across the member countries. In addition, political objectives can also be the driving force behind joining or forming a monetary union. Establishing a regional economic and political power bloc can result in a bigger role in world financial markets for the region as a whole. Other political incentives may include delegating to an institution outside the domestic political process the enforcement of monetary and fiscal discipline (Mundell, 1997).

Why do countries decide to join or form a monetary union? The literature on optimum currency areas, initiated by Mundell’s seminal paper (1961), has extensively discussed the potential benefits and costs of monetary unions.1 Countries can gain from a monetary union through lower transaction costs and the elimination of exchange rate variability, spurring investment, intraregional trade, and economic growth. Other benefits are access to bigger financial markets—lowering borrowing costs—and the potential enforcement of monetary and fiscal discipline. The main costs are the loss of national monetary and exchange rate policies. The magnitude of those costs depends on how symmetrical the economies are in terms of business cycles and vulnerability to shocks and the ease with which the economies can adjust to disturbances. These costs are likely to be lower the higher the degree of labor market flexibility across the member countries. In addition, political objectives can also be the driving force behind joining or forming a monetary union. Establishing a regional economic and political power bloc can result in a bigger role in world financial markets for the region as a whole. Other political incentives may include delegating to an institution outside the domestic political process the enforcement of monetary and fiscal discipline (Mundell, 1997).

For the GCC countries, moving to a full monetary union—by fixing bilateral exchange rates irrevocably and introducing a common currency—from the current pseudo-monetary-union arrangement—stable nominal bilateral exchange rates—is likely to be beneficial in several aspects. Although direct gains, such as increased intraregional trade from the union, might be relatively small for these countries, indirect gains should be more significant. The planned monetary union should reinforce the beneficial effects of the on-going and planned structural and institutional reforms to better face the challenges of diversifying the economy and generating employment opportunities for a rapidly rising domestic labor force. The monetary union may also enhance a mutual surveillance mechanism, enforcing in particular fiscal discipline across the membership. In addition, it will likely increase price transparency, facilitating appropriate investment decisions across the GCC area. However, the most important benefit of introducing a common currency among GCC countries will most likely be the integration and development of the area’s bond, equity, and money markets, improving the efficiency of financial services, and in turn (non-oil) growth prospects (see “Potential Benefits from a Monetary Union” below).

In contrast, the main costs of a monetary union—giving up the ability to set independent national monetary and exchange rate policies—should be limited because important exogenous shocks (such as crude oil price changes) would affect GCC countries in a similar way given the still high importance of oil in their economies. Indeed, fluctuations in crude oil price changes have induced comparable effects on the GCC countries’ external current account and fiscal positions (Table 4.1). Moreover, high labor market flexibility in GCC countries has also contributed to the relative ease of adjusting to oil shocks under a fixed exchange rate regime—though this flexibility applies only to the large segment of expatriate workers employed in non-oil activities in these countries. In addition, GCC countries have not relied on monetary and exchange rate tools for quite some time under their pegged exchange rate regimes. Overall, the GCC countries seem well positioned to successfully form and sustain a full monetary union. But the union will need to be supported by appropriate macroeconomic policies, a range of structural reforms, and strong political commitment to be fully effective and beneficial for its members. Moreover, the institutional framework will have to be carefully designed to keep the costs of a monetary union low.

Table 4.1.

GCC Countries: Actual Impact of Recent Oil Price Changes on Selected Indicators

(In percentage points of GDP, unless otherwise indicated)

article image
Source: IMF staff estimates based on data from national authorities.

Change vis-à-vis 1997.

The improvement in Qatar reflects higher export volume of liquefied natural gas and crude oil.

Percentage points; excluding oil, natural gas, and refineries.

The sharp deceleration in growth in Qatar reflects the completion of several projects.

Negative sign = decline; positive sign = increase.

Including net lending.

Excluding government investment income.

Change vis-à-vis 1999.

Potential Benefits from a Monetary Union

A monetary union among GCC countries can serve as a catalyst for stronger integration and deepening of financial markets if the introduction of a common currency is accompanied by the full liberalization of financial markets across its members.2

Integration of Money Markets

A single currency can foster the integration of interbank money markets across GCC countries, but at the same time, it is also a precondition for effectively conducting a common monetary policy. Since monetary policy is set at a regional level, and the liquidity is managed for the region as a whole, money markets need to redistribute the liquidity within the region in a way that leads to a common short-term yield curve. Cross-border arbitrage ensures that monetary stimuli are felt by the entire banking system. Establishing an efficient, fully integrated payment system is key to facilitating cross-border payments and the integration of money markets. The necessary harmonization of monetary policy instruments, and complete move to market-based instruments, can also contribute to money market development. At present, monetary policy instruments in GCC countries are not all market-based and often not designed in a way that is conducive to the development of money and securities markets (Table 4.2). For example, Oman applies ceilings on personal loans lending rates (set at 11 percent in early 2003), and Kuwait on all types of loans—though rates are frequently revised. The United Arab Emirates operates mostly through the issuance of central bank certificates of deposit at the initiative of banks. Since these certificates can be sold back to the central bank any time at a very low penalty, interbank activities have been discouraged.

Table 4.2.

GCC Countries: Monetary Policy Instruments

article image
Source: IMF staff based on information from national authorities.

Traditional credit ceilings have been eliminated. The remaining ceilings have regulatory purposes with the aim of financial sector stability.

Integration of Bond and Equity Markets

A monetary union for the GCC countries could also contribute to the integration and development of the region’s bond and equity markets, which would be beneficial for the financing of economic growth and investment and mobilization of savings. At present, government debt is issued in all GCC countries, except the United Arab Emirates, but secondary market turnover is minimal. In addition, the tradable stock of government debt within the region is relatively low (less than 20 percent of GDP), and banks tend to hold securities up to maturity given their excess liquidity and the still limited choice of alternative domestic (regional) investment instruments. Each GCC country has a stock exchange as the trading platform for equities, government securities, and corporate bonds. However, capitalization of most GCC countries’ equity markets is still relatively low and turnover minimal.3 Supervision and regulation of capital markets also exhibit weaknesses that authorities have only just begun to address. With the exception of Oman, the other GCC countries had until recently very restrictive rules for foreign investors in their stock markets. Qatar still does not allow nonnationals to buy stocks and securities (except for two listed companies), while in some other GCC countries, foreigners can invest only through open-ended mutual funds.

Measures conducive to market development and integration that should accompany a monetary union include harmonizing national taxes, legislation,4 and accounting rules related to the holding and trading of securities, while putting in place integrated securities settlement systems. The latter are important to ensure that trades are secure and can be carried out at low transaction costs within the region. Economies of scale could be captured by linking or consolidating stock exchanges, in particular given the limited size of each national market; such a trend can also be observed internationally. Experience with the EMU shows that the introduction of the euro has fostered the integration and development of deeper and more liquid Euro-bond and equity markets, but it has not eliminated all barriers to market integration. The sources for the remaining market fragmentation are differences in tax, accounting, and legal frameworks, and lack of fully integrated clearing and settlement systems. Deficiencies in all those aspects together with the small size of the markets have kept bond and equity markets in the ECCU and CFA zones fragmented and undeveloped.

Integration of the Banking System

Whether a monetary union can contribute to stimulating cross-border banking operations depends foremost on the degree to which the region’s banking systems will be liberalized, and legislative, regulatory, and supervisory frameworks harmonized. The banking systems in the GCC countries are already well developed and capitalized, as well as profitable, and have become a major factor in diversifying the production base in some countries, particularly in Bahrain (Table 4.3). Most GCC countries have, however, refrained from licensing any new banks since the early 1980s. Moreover, the role of foreign banks is somewhat limited and confined to the smaller GCC members, where about half of the credit institutions are foreign owned, but account for a smaller percent of banks’ assets, except in Bahrain.5 Only a few local banks have established branches in other GCC countries—though they have branches in other countries in the region and in Asia.6

Table 4.3.

GCC Countries: Selected Financial Sector Indicators1

article image
Source: National authorities.

Latest available information.

Does not cover the loans of two Islamic banks.

In a GCC monetary union, some consolidation of the banking systems might take place. The potential impact of a monetary union on the growth of bank loans and the type or structure of banking activities is, however, indirect. Whether overall lending increases is mostly a question of economic growth and new investment opportunities in the region. Greater competition for borrowers is more likely to have an effect on credit conditions than on the overall lending level. Diversifying the credit portfolio could be beneficial for banks’ risk management since in several GCC countries bank credit is concentrated in consumer loans. The overall development and integration of financial markets could affect the type of bank operations.7

Potential Costs of a Monetary Union

Having operated under a pegged exchange rate regime and liberal capital flows, the GCC countries have de facto refrained from using national monetary and exchange rate policies for more than two decades. Nevertheless, since in the long term, the importance of oil production is likely to diverge among the GCC countries, relinquishing these policies could be costlier in the long run. Thus, a higher degree of domestic labor flexibility and flexible fiscal policies would then be needed to facilitate adjustments to external shocks. Moreover, an important cost factor or risk for a monetary union could arise from negative externalities from the lack of fiscal prudence in one or more member countries. As a result, negative spillover effects could spread from one member country to the entire membership, with the potential need of the union’s central bank to raise interest rates particularly in the case of an exchange rate peg of the common currency. A key challenge is therefore to set up rules, penalties, and institutional procedures to prevent major macroeconomic imbalances and lack of fiscal discipline in the monetary union. Rigorous macroeconomic policymaking would not only be an outcome of a monetary union but is an essential condition for its functioning (see Section V for more details).

Cost of Institutional Changes

Replacing the existing national currencies by a common currency involves changeover costs. One-time costs are related, for example, to the conversion of accounts and means of book-money payments (checks, transfer forms, cards), price lists and catalogues, adjustment of cashiers and automats, and educating the public about the new currency—the introduction of the euro is estimated to have cost about 0.5 percent of the euro area GDP.

Creating a new monetary institution initially also requires additional resources. There is room for overall savings if central bank functions are organized more efficiently, and duplication of functions at the national and regional level is avoided.8 While a monetary union requires a centralized decision-making body for the entire region, other key functions can be allocated at either the national or regional level. As discussed in Section V, practical and political considerations, including cost efficiency considerations, suggest that national central banks could maintain the functions of implementing regular monetary policy and foreign exchange operations, supervising banks, and collecting data. A common GCC central bank or supranational monetary authority would then be in charge of policy decision making, communicating the policy with the public, consolidating financial data at the regional level, and coordinating issues of regional importance. Overseeing and operating the payment systems could either be done at the centralized or decentralized level. Other potential costs for members of a GCC currency union could result from potentially lower central bank profits and negative spillovers from a financial crisis. However, both can be limited by appropriate institutional arrangements.

Credit Policies

Retaining national credit policies in a monetary union could impede the effectiveness of monetary policy for the region as a whole as well as the development and integration of securities markets. The importance of credit policies varies among GCC countries. These policies generally aim at stimulating investment in certain sectors, and they are also a tool for the authorities to distribute the proceeds from the oil wealth to its residents. The governments in GCC countries, directly or through specialized credit institutions or development banks, provide soft long-term funding or grants for investment projects, including housing.

The government’s involvement in credit allocation and funding has two side effects that create negative externalities for other monetary union members. First, the credit channel is disrupted, since the favored sectors are far less responsive to interest rate changes. This limits the effectiveness of monetary policy for the union. Interest rate changes will be felt and transmitted more strongly to the real economy in countries where the government’s involvement in credit allocation and funding plays a smaller role. And second, the government’s involvement in credit allocation and funding discourages other forms of long-term financing, such as the issuance of securities and the development of securities markets, thus reducing a potential benefit for monetary union. In essence, GCC countries have to decide whether they want to create a level playing field among their economies with the objective of fostering competition and integration by liberalizing credit policies, or they are willing to tolerate distortions created by subsidized (long-term) interest rates with the negative implications for monetary policy effectiveness and overall capital market development.

1

For a survey of the optimum currency area literature see, for example, Masson and Taylor (1993). Attempts to estimate the benefits and costs for monetary unions have been made by, among others, De Grauwe and Vanhaverbeke (1991), Bayoumi and Eichengreen (1994), Mélitz and Weber (1996), Rose (2000), and Persson (2001).

2

While there have been numerous theoretical and empirical studies on the effects of monetary unions on the real economy, the impact on financial integration has hardly been discussed other than under the scenario of a common market. The European Central Bank (ECB), however, has conducted a detailed assessment of the impact of the euro on money, bonds, and equity markets. See ECB (2001a, 2001b, and 2001c); and Santillán, Bayle, and Thygesen (2000).

3

Except the stock market of Saudi Arabia, which with a market capitalization of more than 40 percent of GDP, is by far the largest in the region and Arab world.

4

For example, limits on foreign ownership of stocks, either by law or under the companies’ articles of association.

5

In addition to the onshore markets, Bahrain has developed into an offshore banking center with close to 50 offshore banks.

6

Two U.A.E. banks have branches in Bahrain, Oman, and Qatar, and one bank has branches in Bahrain and Kuwait. One Omani bank has a branch in the United Arab Emirates and recently bought an existing bank in Bahrain.

7

In the euro area, some changes in the structure of the banking system have taken place since the introduction of a single currency. The trend toward consolidation has been mostly among domestic banks. Despite the intention of some large European banks to merge, national political interests have prevented a stronger cross-border consolidation. Banking systems in the other monetary unions continue to be not well integrated even after the introduction of a common currency a long time ago.

8

The costs for operating the European Central Bank, measured as expenditure for staff, administration, and depreciation of fixed assets, amounted to 0.0025 percent of GDP on average for 1999 and 2000. At the same time, most national central banks of the European System of Central Banks have begun to streamline their organization and reduce the number of staff.

  • Collapse
  • Expand
  • Abed, George T., S. Nuri Erbas, and Behrouz Guerami, 2003, “The GCC Monetary Union: Some Considerations for the Exchange Rate Regime,” IMF Working Paper No. 03/66 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Alexander, William E., Tomás J.T. Baliño, and Charles Enoch, 1995, The Adoption of Indirect Instruments of Monetary Policy, IMF Occasional Paper No. 126 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Alesina, Alberto, and Robert J. Barro, eds., 2001, Currency Unions (Stanford, California: Hoover Institution Press, Stanford University).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Allen, Polly Reynolds 1976, Organization and Administration of a Monetary Union, Princeton Studies in International Finance No. 38 (Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Askari, Hossein Vahid Nowshirvani, and Mohamed Jaber, 1997, Economic Development in the GCC: The Blessing and the Curse of Oil (Greenwich, Connecticut: JAI Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Barnett, Steven A., and Rolando J. Ossowski, 2002, “Operational Aspects of Fiscal Policy in Oil-Producing Countries,” IMF Working Paper No. 02/177 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bayoumi, Tamim, and Barry Eichengreen, 1994, One Money or Many? Analyzing the Prospects for Monetary Unification in Various Parts of the World, Princeton Studies in International Finance No. 76 (Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Beetsma, Roel Xavier Debrun, and Franc Klaassen, 2001, “Is Fiscal Policy Coordination in EMU Desirable?” IMF Working Paper No. 01/178 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Blejer, Mario I., Jacob A. Frenkel, Leonardo Leiderman, and Assaf Razin, eds., 1997, Optimum Currency Areas, New Analytical and Policy Developments (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bordo, Michael D. Lars Jonung, 1999, “The Future of EMU: What Does the History of Monetary Unions Tell Us?” NBER Working Paper No. 7365 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Clément, Jean A.P., 1996, Aftermath of the CFA Franc Devaluation, IMF Occasional Paper No. 138 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Davis, Jeffrey, Rolando Ossowski, James Daniel, and Steven Barnett, 2001, Stabilization and Savings Funds for Nonrenewable Resources: Experience and Fiscal Policy Implications, IMF Occasional Paper No. 205 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • De Grauwe, Paul, and Wim Vanhaverbeke, 1991, “Is Europe an Optimum Currency Area? Evidence From Regional Data,” CEPR Discussion Paper No. 555 (London: Centre for Economic Policy Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • de la Torre, Augusto, Kelly, Margaret R., 1992, Regional Trade Arrangements, IMF Occasional Paper No. 93 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Doré, Ousmane, and Paul R. Masson, 2002Experience with Budgetary Convergence in the WAEMU,” IMF Working Paper No. 02/108 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Deutsche Bundesbank, 2000, “The Integration of the German Money Market in the Single Euro Money Market,” in Monthly Report January 2000, pp. 15 -30 (Frankfurt).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Eichengreen, Barry 1997, “Is Europe an Optimum Currency Area?” in European Monetary Unification: Theory, Practice, and Analysis, by Barry Eichengreen (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • El-Erian, Mohamed A., and Stanley Fischer, 1996, “Is MENA a Region? The Scope for Regional Integration,” IMF Working Paper No. 96/30 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Engel, Eduardo, and Rodrigo O. Valdes, 2000, “Optimal Fiscal Strategy for Oil Exporting Countries,” IMF Working Paper No. 00/118 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • European Central Bank, 1999a, “Banking in the Euro Area: Structural Features and Trends,” Monthly Report (April), pp. 41 -53.

  • European Central Bank, 1999b, “The Implementation of the Stability and Growth Pact,” Monthly Report (May), pp. 45 -72.

  • European Central Bank, 2000, “EMU and Banking Supervision,” Monthly Bulletin (April), pp. 49 -64.

  • European Central Bank, 2001a, The Euro Money Market, July (Frankfurt).

  • European Central Bank, 2001b, The Euro Bond Market, July (Frankfurt).

  • European Central Bank, 2001c, The Euro Equity Markets, August (Frankfurt).

  • European Central Bank, 2001d, The Monetary Policy of the ECB (Frankfurt).

  • European Commission, 1990, “One Market, One Money: An Evaluation of the Potential Benefits and Costs of Forming An Economic and Monetary Union,European Economy, Vol. 44.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • European Central Bank, 1996, Credit Institutions and Banking, The Single Market Review Series. Subseries II—Impact on Services (Brussels).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • European Central Bank, 1999, Report of the Giovannini Group, EU Repo Markets: Opportunities for Change (Brussels).

  • European Central Bank, Economic and Financial Committee, 2001, Report on Financial Crisis Management, EFC/ECFIN/ 251/01 (Brussels).

  • Fasano, Ugo 2000, “Review of the Experience with Oil Stabilization and Savings Funds in Selected Countries,” IMF Working Paper No. 00/112 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fasano, Ugo 2001a, “With Limited Oil Resources, Oman Faces Challenges of Economic Diversification, Structural Reforms,IMF Survey, Vol., 30, No. 15 (July 30), pp. 254 -57.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fasano, Ugo 2001b, “Sluggish Growth, Declining Oil Resources Prompt Qatar to Diversify Economy Away from OilIMF Survey, Vol, 30, No. 22 (November 26), pp. 382 -84.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fasano, Ugo 2002, “With Open Economy and Sound Policies, U.A.E. Has Turned Oil ‘Curse’ into a Blessing,IMF Survey, Vol. 31, No. 19 (October 21), pp. 330 -32.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fasano, Ugo 2003, “Fiscal Sustainability with Oil Resources,” in United Arab Emirates: Selected Issues and Statistical Appendix, IMF Country Report No. 03/67 (Washington: International Monetary Fund), pp. 38 -41.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fasano, Ugo and Zubair Iqbal, 2002, “Common Currency,Finance & Development, Vol. 39 (December), pp. 42 -45.

  • Fasano, Ugo and Qing Wang, 2001, “Fiscal Expenditure Policy and Non-Oil Economic Growth: Evidence from GCC Countries,” IMF Working Paper No. 01/195 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fasano, Ugo and Qing Wang, 2002, “Testing the Relationship Between Government Spending and Revenue: Evidence from GCC Countries,” IMF Working Paper No. 02/201 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fasano, Ugo and Rishi Goyal, 2003, “Rising Unemployment in GCC Countries: Policy Options,forthcoming IMF Working Paper.

  • Hernández-Catá, Ernesto, and other, 1998, The West African Economic and Monetary Union, IMF Occasional Paper No. 170 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, 2003, “United Arab Emirates: Financial System Stability Assessment, Including Reports on the Observance of Standards and Codes on the Following Topics: Monetary and Financial Policy Transparency, Banking Supervision and Payment Systems,” IMF Country Report No. 03/20 (Washington).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Issing, Otmar, 1999, “The Monetary Policy of the Eurosystem,Finance & Development, Vol. 36 (March), pp. 18 -21.

  • Jadresic, Esteban, 2002, “On a Common Currency for the GCC Countries,” IMF Policy Discussion Paper No. 02/12 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Jahjah, Samir, 2001, “Financial Stability and Fiscal Crises in a Monetary Union,” IMF Working Paper No. 01/201 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kopits, George, ed., 1992, Tax Harmonization in the European Community: Policy Issues and Analysis, IMF Occasional Paper No. 94 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Masson, Paul, and Jacques Mélitz, 1991, “Fiscal Policy Independence in a European Monetary Union,Open Economics Review, Vol. 2, pp. 113 -36.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Masson, Paul, and Catherine Pattillo, 2001, Monetary Union in West Africa (ECOWAS): Is It Desirable and How Could It Be Achieved?, IMF Occasional Paper No. 204 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Masson, Paul, and Mark Taylor, 1993, “Currency Unions: A Survey of the Issues,” in Policy Issues in the Operation of Currency Unions, ed. Paul Masson Mark Taylor (Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mélitz, Jacques and Axel A. Weber, 1996, “The Costs/Benefits of a Common Monetary Policy in France and Germany and Possible Lessons for Monetary Union,” CEPR Discussion Paper No. 1374 (London: Centre for Economic Policy Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mehran, Hassanali, and others, 1998, Financial Sector Development in Sub-Saharan African Countries, IMF Occasional Paper No. 169 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mundell, Robert A., 1961, “A Theory of Optimum Currency Areas,American Economic Review, Vol. 51, pp. 657 -64.

  • Mundell, Robert A., 1997, “Updating the Agenda for Monetary Union,” in Optimum Currency Areas: New Analytical and Policy Developments, ed. by Mario Blejer Jacob A. Frenkel Leonardo Leiderman Assaf Razin (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Padoa-Schioppa, Tommaso, 1994, The Road to Monetary Union in Europe: The Emperor, the Kings, and the Genies (Oxford: Clarendon Press).

  • Padoa-Schioppa, Tommaso, 1999, “EMU and Banking Supervision,” lecture delivered at the London School of Economics, Financial Markets Group, February 24.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Padoa-Schioppa, Tommaso, 2000, “The Eurosystem and Financial Stability,” speech delivered at the Belgian Financial Forum, February 10.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Persson, Torsten, 2001, “Currency Unions and Trade: How Large Is the Treatment Effect?Economic Policy: A European Forum, No. 33 (October) pp. 435 -61.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Rose, Andrew, 2000, “One Money, One Market: Estimating the Effects of Common Currencies on Trade,Economic Policy: A European Forum, No. 30 (April) pp. 9 -45.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Sandwick, John A., ed., 1987, The Gulf Cooperation Council: Moderation and Stability in an Interdependent World (Boulder, Colorado: Westview Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Santillán, Javier, Marc Bayle, Christian Thygesen, 2000, The Impact of the Euro on Money and Bond Markets, ECB Occasional Paper No. 1 (Frankfurt: European Central Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Sinn, Hans-Werner and Holger Feist, 1997, “Eurowinners and Eurolosers: The Distribution of Seigniorage Wealth in EMU,” NBER Working Paper No. 6072 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Tenreyro, Silvana 2001, “On the Causes and Consequences of Currency Unions,” paper presented at an IMF Research Department Seminar, December 5.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • van Beek, Frits, José Roberto Rosales, Mayra Zermeno, Ruby Randall, Jorge Shepherd, 2000, The Eastern Caribbean Currency Union: Institutions, Performance, and Policy Issues, IMF Occasional Paper No. 195 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Williams, Oral, Tracy Polius, and Selvon Hazel, 2001, “Reserve Pooling in the Eastern Caribbean Currency Union and the CFA Franc Zone: A Comparative Analysis,” IMF Working Paper No. 01/104 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • World Bank, 2001, World Development Indicators (Washington).