1 Introduction and Overview
Author:
Mr. Subhash Madhav Thakur
Search for other papers by Mr. Subhash Madhav Thakur in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
,
Ms. Valerie Cerra
Search for other papers by Ms. Valerie Cerra in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
,
Mr. Balázs Horváth
Search for other papers by Mr. Balázs Horváth in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
, and
Mr. Michael Keen
Search for other papers by Mr. Michael Keen in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close

Abstract

Sweden has long been regarded as epitomizing the modern welfare state. In fact, the “welfare states” of different countries differ in quite fundamental ways.1 That in Sweden—naturally if somewhat imprecisely referred to as the “Swedish model”—is marked by the use of big, centralized institutions and large-scale transfers, commonly provided on a universal basis (rather than being income related) with a view to reducing inequality, alleviating poverty, and insuring against social risks. The key features of this policy regime, which employs both fiscal and nonfiscal measures, include:2

Sweden has long been regarded as epitomizing the modern welfare state. In fact, the “welfare states” of different countries differ in quite fundamental ways.1 That in Sweden—naturally if somewhat imprecisely referred to as the “Swedish model”—is marked by the use of big, centralized institutions and large-scale transfers, commonly provided on a universal basis (rather than being income related) with a view to reducing inequality, alleviating poverty, and insuring against social risks. The key features of this policy regime, which employs both fiscal and nonfiscal measures, include:2

  • An active and large state with a broad political mandate to intervene in the market process to secure equality of income and wealth distribution at a socially desired level;

  • Highly ambitious social insurance arrangements covering an unusually wide array of risks and providing generous income replacement when they materialize;

  • Relatively little use of means-tested benefits;

  • High levels of taxation and social security contributions, needed to sustain large-scale income transfers and sizable public consumption;

  • Elaborate centralized institutions and structures aimed at facilitating effective cooperation between the private sector and a large, service-oriented public sector, with the latter responsible not only for the financing but also for the provision of most social services;

  • Extensive regulatory and supervisory intervention (especially, but not only, in the labor market);

  • Wages and working conditions set in a framework of centralized bargaining (involving employers and well-organized trade unions, but not directly the government, which participates only in its capacity as employer), aiming for full employment, stable labor income, and peaceful conflict resolution;

  • Extensive public employment, concentrated in health care and education; and

  • A relatively large share of publicly owned enterprises.

The Swedish model has consistently enjoyed solid support from all sections of Swedish society. This support seems to stem both from altruism and self-interest. The former seems evident, for example, in the relative generosity of Sweden’s foreign aid program, while the latter is suggested by the pattern of survey responses. There are quite large differences in attitudes, for example, between private and public sector employees, with high-level public employees in Sweden showing more support for the welfare state than do high-level private sector employees. More generally—and not surprisingly—groups with a stronger market position, whether along a gender or class dimension, show weaker support for state intervention. At the other end, the unemployed—the group with the weakest market position—display the strongest support for state intervention. Indeed, similar patterns are repeated throughout the advanced economies, regardless of the nature and extent of welfare provisions.3

The welfare state in Sweden has many impressive achievements. Sweden’s quality of life, public health, and educational attainment indicators are among the best in the world.4 The country is politically stable, with high employment and participation rates and remarkably low levels of labor conflict. A high level of economic and gender equality, as well as substantial public support for the creation and preservation of human capital—both key features of the Swedish model—give rise to dynamic advantages that can offset any static efficiency losses arising from the higher public intervention in market processes. These dynamic advantages arise from, among other things: coverage against a wide array of risks not insurable in private markets (not least the risk of being born to poor or less-educated parents); greater use of talent resulting from higher female participation rates and the effective incorporation of minorities and immigrants into the labor market; greater ability to take risks owing to the presence of a strong social safety net; and enhanced intergenerational mobility. A greater degree of public intervention also has the potential to correct additional market failures arising from imperfect competition, asymmetric information, and various externalities. Not least, the pursuit of equality domestically is matched by relatively generous support for developing countries, and a high degree of sensitivity to environmental issues.

But maintaining a very large welfare state may involve substantial economic costs. The tax burden needed to sustain the welfare state in Sweden is among the highest in the world. Owing to the international mobility of capital, the effective burden of this is likely to be heavily concentrated on labor income. As shown in Figure 1, the high levels of direct taxation and social security contributions make the tax wedge on labor almost the highest in the OECD countries. This, together with generous welfare provisions, creates strong disincentive effects on effective labor supply and a sizable black economy, variously estimated at between 5 and 19 percent of GDP.5 The centralized institutions associated with the Swedish model lack flexibility, hampering efficient and timely adjustment to rapidly changing economic conditions. The compressed wage scale—a direct consequence of the centralized wage bargaining regime—may adversely affect work incentives at the high end of the skill distribution and is likely to discourage investment in human capital. Last, but not least, Lindbeck (1997) and several other participants in the academic debate on the Swedish model have argued that its excessive size was causally related to Sweden’s relatively weak growth performance since the 1970s, reflected in a marked decline in its ranking by per capita GDP within the OECD.

Figure 1.
Figure 1.

Tax Wedge1

Source: OECD Online Statistics.1Income tax plus employee and employer social security contributions in 1998. Single individual at income level of average production worker.

While it is impossible to pin down the “optimal” size of the welfare state precisely—views on this will reasonably differ both in factual assessments of its effects and in judging its ethical merit—government was generally agreed to have become too big by the late 1980s. The “overshooting” in the size of government of this period—a theme in Lindbeck (1997)—was amplified by demographic developments—Sweden’s population was the oldest in the world during the 1980s—and was viewed as an underlying reason for the crisis in the early 1990s, whose proximate cause lay in external shocks and macroeconomic policy mistakes. Despite tax revenues exceeding 60 percent of GDP on the back of a strong cyclical upswing (Figure 2), high and volatile public consumption and transfers (Figure 3) led to large general government deficits (Figure 4) from 1991, and, with the onset of a crisis, to rapidly rising public debt, reaching three-quarters of GDP in the middle of the decade. The resulting surge in budgetary interest payments was coupled with a widespread loss of confidence in fiscal sustain-ability, precipitating the crisis of the early 1990s. The steady streamlining of government following the crisis was thus seen not just as a short-term correction of avoidable macroeconomic policy mistakes, but as a structural necessity. The large role played by government was also believed to hamper the flexibility of the economy to rebound from shocks. The subsequent less than complete recovery of lost output since the crisis period of the early 1990s, despite relatively rapid growth in the past few years, underscores the need for a renewed streamlining of the welfare state to maintain sustainable high growth.

Figure 2.
Figure 2.

General Government Revenues

(In percent of GDP)

Figure 3.
Figure 3.

General Government Expenditures

(In percent of GDP)

Figure 4.
Figure 4.

General Government Balance

(In percent of GDP)

Whatever its past achievements and difficulties, the future seems certain to hold new challenges for the Swedish way of government. Globalization is changing the context in which the Swedish model operates by limiting its tax-based financing. In the past it was possible to maintain a drastically higher level of taxation to sustain a wide and all-encompassing social safety net and a pervasive role for the public sector in the economy, irrespective of what other countries did. But the fiscal basis for this strategy is being increasingly undermined. The scale and sensitivity of international capital flows make the base for taxing capital increasingly mobile. Rapid technological change, heightened regulatory and tax competition, and the increasing mobility of both commodities and labor pose further threats to budgetary revenues. Pressure can also be expected on the other side of the government’s accounts, as the continued aging of the population increases spending needs. The government’s ability to promote social objectives through regulatory measures is likely to be similarly constrained by greater private sector competition induced by globalization and deepening European integration.

The purpose of this short book is to review the prospects for the Swedish welfare state in the light of its past accomplishments. This is an important topic not only for the Swedes themselves but also for others who look to Sweden for lessons of what government can, and cannot, do to foster social equality and growth. The Swedish economy has indeed been widely studied, and the welfare state more generally remains a subject of intense debate among both economists and the wider public.6 This book draws on this extensive body of research to provide a relatively brief and accessible overview, and to assess the way ahead for Sweden.

The thrust of our argument is that it is both necessary and possible to streamline the Swedish model while preserving its key elements. Such a modified welfare state can underpin Sweden’s competitiveness by building on the economy’s existing strengths: effective governance in the public sector; wide-ranging public support for human capital creation, including through broad and efficient provision of education and health care; maintenance of high employment; and solidaristic assistance for the less fortunate at home and abroad to preserve social peace. Sweden’s advanced position in the high-technology sector may also provide scope for enhancing public sector efficiency. Significant further strides in deregulation and privatization of state-owned enterprises in competitive markets would boost this process, and could help support the continuation of key elements of the welfare state. Finally, streamlining the Swedish model would involve a welcome reduction in the tax burden and in public spending, which should strengthen the fiscal position in the long run by raising employment, thus contributing to a broader tax base and reducing the need for budgetary transfers.

The book is structured as follows. Chapter 2 surveys the main elements of the Swedish welfare state. Chapters 3 and 4 explore the Swedish growth experience over recent decades and the extent to which it can be related, for better or worse, to the activities of government. Chapter 5 reviews labor market aspects, while the topic of Chapter 6 is investment and savings. Chapter 7 discusses redistribution, a central element of the Swedish model. Chapter 8 surveys various pressures on the welfare state, and Chapter 9 concludes with a short discussion on the future of the Swedish model and on lessons from the Swedish experience for other countries.

  • Collapse
  • Expand
Can the Bumblebee Keep Flying?
  • Adema, W., 1997, “What Do Countries Really Spend on Social Policies? A Comparative Note,” OECD Economic Studies, Vol. 1, No. 28, pp. 15367.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Agell, Jonas, 1996, “Why Sweden’s Welfare State Needed Reform,” Economic Journal, Vol. 106 (November), pp. 176071.

  • Agell, Jonas, 1998, “What Can the Welfare State Accomplish? An Introduction,” Swedish Economic Policy Review, Vol. 5, No. 1, pp. 310.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Agell, Jonas, L. Berg, and P.A. Edin, 1995, “The Swedish Boom to Bust Cycle: Tax Reform, Consumption, and Asset Structure,” Swedish Economic Policy Review, Vol. 2, pp. 271314.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Agell, Jonas, Peter Englund, and Jan Södersten, 1995, Swedish Tax Policy in Theory and Practice: The 1991 Tax Reform (Stockholm: Frizes).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Agell, Jonas, Peter Englund, and Jan Södersten, 1998, Incentives and Redistribution in the Welfare State: The Swedish Tax Reform (Basingstoke: Macmillan).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Agell, Jonas, and P. Lundborg, 1999, “Survey Evidence on Wage Rigidity and Unemployment: Sweden in the 1990s,” IFAU Working Paper 2 (Uppsala: Institute for Labor Market Policy Evaluation).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Aghion, Philippe, Eva Caroli, and Cecilia García-Peñalosa, 1999, “Inequality and Economic Growth: The Perspective of the New Growth Theories,” Journal of Economic Literature, Vol 37, pp. 161560.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Alesina, Alberto, 1992, “Political Instability and Economic Growth,” NBER Working Paper 4173 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Alesina, Alberto, and Roberto Perotti, 1996, “Income Distribution, Political Instability, and Investment,” European Economic Review, Vol. 40 (June), pp. 120328.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Alesina, Alberto, and Dani Rodrik, 1994, “Distributive Politics and Economic Growth,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 109, Issue 2 (May), pp. 46590.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Andersson, Kirster, 1995, The Mobility of Capital—The Swedish Tax and Expenditure Structure in an Integrated Europe (Stockholm: Ministry of Finance).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Andersson, Kirster, and Johan Fall, 2000, “The Ongoing Tax Competition in the EU to Attract Capital” (unpublished; Stockholm: Federation of Swedish Industries).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Apel, Mikael, and Jan Södersten, 1999, “Personal Taxation and Investment Incentives in a Small Open Economy,” International Tax and Public Finance, Vol. 6, pp. 7988.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Aronsson, Thomas, and James R. Walker, 1997, “The Effects of Sweden’s Welfare State on Labor Supply Incentives,” in The Welfare State in Transition: Reforming the Swedish Model, ed. by Richard B. Freeman, Robert Topel, and Birgitta Swedenborg (Chicago: University of Chicago Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Atkinson, Anthony B., 1995, “The Welfare State and Economic Performance,” National Tax Journal, Vol 48, pp. 17198.

  • Atkinson, Anthony B., 1999, The Economic Consequences of Rolling Back the Welfare State (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press).

  • Balassa, Béla, 1978, “Exports and Economic Growth: Further Evidence,” Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 5, pp. 18189.

  • Banerjee, A.V, and A.F. Newman, 1993, “Occupational Choice and the Process of Development,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 101, pp. 27498.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Barro, Robert J., 1989, “A Cross-Country Study of Growth, Saving, and Government,” NBER Working Paper 2855 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Barro, Robert J., 1991, “Economic Growth in a Cross Section of Countries,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 106, pp. 40743.

  • Barro, Robert J., and Xavier Sala-i-Martin, 1995, Economic Growth (New York: McGraw-Hill).

  • Benabou, Roland, 1996, “Inequality and Growth,” in NBER Macroeconomics Annual, Vol. 11, ed. by B.S. Bernanke and J. Rotemberg (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Berndt, Ernst R., and Bengt Hansson, 1992, “Measuring the Contribution of Public Infrastructure Capital in Sweden,” Scandinavian Journal of Economics, Vol. 94, pp. 15168.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bhagwati, Jagdish N., and T.N. Srinivasan, 1979, “Trade Policy and Development,” in International Economic Policy, ed. by Rudiger Dornbusch and Jacob Frenkel (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bird, Richard, and Michael Smart, 1996, “Federal Fiscal Arrangements in Canada: An Analysis of Incentives,” Proceedings of the National Tax Association (Washington: National Tax Association), pp. 110.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Björklund, Anders, and Richard B. Freeman, 1997, “Generating Equality and Eliminating Poverty the Swedish Way,” in The Welfare State in Transition: Reforming the Swedish Model, ed. by Richard B. Freeman, Robert Topel, and Birgitta Swedenborg (Chicago: University of Chicago Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Björklund, Anders, and Markus Jäntti, 1997, “Intergenerational Income Mobility in Sweden Compared to the United States,” American Economic Review, Vol. 87, pp. 100918.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Björklund, Anders, Marten Palme, and Ingemar Svensson, 1995, “Assessing the Effects of Swedish Tax and Benefit Reforms on Income Distribution Using Different Income Concepts,” Tax Reform Evaluation Report 13 (Stockholm: National Institute of Economic Research, Economic Council, June).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Blackorby, Charles, and David Donaldson, 1988, “Cash Versus Kind, Self-Selection, and Efficient Transfers,” American Economic Review, Vol. 78, No. 4, pp. 691700.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Blanchard, Olivier, and Justin Wolfers, 1999, “The Role of Shocks and Institutions in the Rise of European Unemployment: The Aggregate Evidence,” Harry Johnson Lecture (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Blomqvist, Sören, Matias Eklöf, and Whitney Newey, 2001, “Tax Reform Evaluation Using Non-Parametric Methods: Sweden 1980–1991,” Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 79, pp. 54368.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Boadway, Robin, and Neil Bruce, 1984, “A General Proposition on the Design of a Neutral Business Tax,” Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 24, pp. 23139.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Boadway, Robin, and Neil Bruce, 1992, “Problems with Integrating Corporate and Personal Taxes in an Open Economy,” Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 48, pp. 3966.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Boadway, Robin, Katherine Cuff, and Maurice Marchand, 2000, “Optimal Income Taxation with Quasi-Linear Preferences Revisited,” Journal of Public Economic Theory, Vol. 2, pp. 43560.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Boadway, Robin, and Michael Keen, 2000, “Redistribution,” in Handbook of Income Distribution, Vol. 1, ed. by Anthony Atkinson and François Bourguignon (Amsterdam: North-Holland).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Boadway, Robin, and Michael Keen, 2002, “Theoretical Considerations in the Taxation of Capital Income and Financial Services: A Survey,” in P. Honohan, ed., The Taxation of Domestic Financial Intermediation (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Boeri, T., A. Börsch-Supan, and G. Tabellini, 2001, “Would You Like to Shrink the Welfare State? A Survey of European Citizens,” Economic Policy, Vol. 16, No. 32 (April), pp. 750.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Boije, Robert, 2001, “Challenges for Tax Policy in Sweden,” Sveriges Riksbank Economic Review, No. 2, pp. 5079.

  • Bond, Stephen, and Lucy Chennells, 2000, “Corporate Income Taxes and Investment: A Comparative Study” (unpublished; London: Institute for Fiscal Studies).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Borensztein, Eduardo, Jose De Gregorio, and Jong-Wha Lee, 1994, “How Does Foreign Direct Investment Affect Economic Growth?” IMF Working Paper 94/110 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Brücker, Herbert, Gil S. Epstein, Barry McCormick, Gilles Saint-Paul, Alessandra Venturini, and Klaus Zimmermann, 2002, “Managing Migration in the European Welfare State,” in Immigration Policy and the Welfare System, ed. by Tito Boeri, Gordon H. Henson, and Barry McCormick (Oxford: Oxford University Press), pp. 1168.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Calmfors, Lars, and Mats Persson, 2000, “Economic Policy and Growth: An Introduction,” Swedish Economic Policy Review, Vol. 7, No. 1, pp. 36.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Calmfors, Lars, Anders Forslung, and Maria Henström, 2001, “Does Active Labour Market Policy Work? Lessons from the Swedish Experiences” (unpublished; Stockholm: Department of Economics, Stockholm University).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Calmfors, Lars, and J. Driffill, 1988, “Bargaining Structure, Corporatism, and Macro-economic Performance,” Economic Policy, Vol. 6 (April), pp. 1361.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Carling, Kenneth, Bertil Holmlund, and Altin Vejsiu, 2001, “Do Benefit Cuts Boost Job Finding? Swedish Evidence from the 1990s,” Economic Journal, Vol. 111, No. 474, pp. 76690.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Castles, Francis G., and Steve Dowrick, 1990, “The Impact of Government Spending Levels on Medium-Term Economic Growth in the OECD, 1960–85,” Journal of Theoretical Politics, Vol. 2, pp. 173204.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cerra, Valerie, and Sweta C. Saxena, 2000, “Alternative Methods of Estimating Potential Output and the Output Gap: An Application to Sweden,” IMF Working Paper 00/59 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Chamley, Christophe, 1986, “Optimal Taxation of Capital Income in General Equilibrium with Infinite Lives,” Econometrica, Vol. 54, pp. 60722.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Chirinko, Robert, Stephen Fazzari, and Andrew Meyer, 1999, “How Responsive Is Business Capital Formation to Its User Cost? An Exploration Using Micro-Data,” Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 74, pp. 5380.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cnossen, Sijbren, 2000, “Taxing Capital Income in Nordic Countries,” in Taxing Capital Income in the European Union: Issues and Options for Reform, ed. by Sijbren Cnossen (Oxford: Oxford University Press), pp. 180213.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Coe, David R., and Elhanan Helpman, 1993, “International R&D Spillovers,” NBER Working Paper 4444 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Crafts, Nicholas, 2000, “Globalization and Growth in the Twentieth Century,” IMF Working Paper 00/44 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Daveri, F., and G. Tabellini, 2000, “Unemployment, Growth, and Taxation in Industrial Countries,” Economic Policy, Vol. 15, No. 30 (April), pp. 49104.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Denison, Edward, 1967, Why Growth Rates Differ: Post-War Experience in Nine Western Countries (Washington: Brookings Institution).

  • Devereux, Michael, and Harold Freeman, 1995, “The Impact of Tax on Foreign Direct Investment: Empirical Evidence and Implications for Tax Integration Schemes,” International Tax and Public Finance, Vol. 2, pp. 85106.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Devereux, Michael, and Rachel Griffith, 2002, “Evaluating Tax Policy for Location Decisions,” International Tax and Public Finance (forthcoming).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Devereux, Michael, and Rachel Griffith, and Alexander Klemm, 2002, “Can International Tax Competition Explain Corporate Income Tax Reforms?” Economic Policy (forthcoming).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Diamond, John, 1989, “Government Expenditure and Economic Growth: An Empirical Investigation,” IMF Working Paper 89/45 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Diamond, Peter, and James Mirrlees, 1971, “Optimal Taxation and Public Production, II: Tax Rules,” American Economic Review, Vol. 61, pp. 26178.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Doppelhofer, Gemot, Ronald Miller, and Xavier Sala-i-Martin, 2000, “Determinants of Long-Term Growth: A Bayesian Averaging of Classical Estimates (BAGE) Approach,” NBER Working Paper 7750 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dowrick, Steve, 1996, “Swedish Economic Performance and Swedish Economic Debate: A View From the Outside,” Economic Journal, Vol. 106, pp. 177279.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dowrick, Steve, and Duc-Tho Nguyen, 1989, “OECD Comparative Economic Growth 1950–85: Catch-Up and Convergence,” American Economic Review, Vol. 79, pp. 101030.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Easterly, William R., and Sergio Rebelo, 1993, “Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth: An Empirical Investigation,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 32, pp. 41758.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Edwards, Jeremy, Michael Keen, and Matti Tuomala, 1994, “Income Tax, Commodity Taxes, and Public Good Provision: A Brief Guide,” Finanzarchiv, Vol. 54, pp. 47287.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Esping-Andersen, Gosta, 1990, The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism (Cambridge, U.K.: Polity Press).

  • European Commission, 2001, Company Taxation in the Internal Market (Brussels: European Commission).

  • Feldstein, Martin S., and Charles Horioka, 1980, “Domestic Savings and International Capital Flows,” Economic Journal, Vol. 90, pp. 31429.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Flanagan, R.J., 1999, “Macroeconomic Performance and Collective Bargaining: An International Perspective,” Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 37 (September), pp. 115075.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Forslund, A., and A.S. Kolm, 2000, “Active Labor Market Policies and Real Wage Determination—Swedish Evidence,” IFAU Working Paper 7 (Uppsala: Institute for Labor Market Policy Evaluation).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Freeman, Richard B., Robert Topel, and Birgitta Swedenborg, eds., 1997, The Welfare State in Transition: Reforming the Swedish Model (Chicago: University of Chicago Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Frenkel, Jacob, Assaf Razin, and Chi-Wa Yuen, 1996, Fiscal Policies and Growth in the World Economy (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Friberg, Kent, and E. Uddén-Sonnegärd, 2001, “Changed Wage Formation in a Changed Environment?” Riksbank Economic Review, pp. 4269.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fuest, Clemens, and Bernd Huber, 2000, “The Optimal Taxation at Dividends in a Small Open Economy,” CESifo Working Paper Series, No. 348 (Munich, Germany: Center for Economic Studies and the Ifo Institute for Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gerson, Philip, 1998, “The Impact of Fiscal Policy Variables on Output Growth,” IMF Working Paper 98/01 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gottschalk, Peter, and Timothy M. Smeeding, 2000, “Empirical Evidence on Income Inequality in Industrialized Countries,” in Handbook of Income Distribution, Vol. 1, ed. by Anthony Atkinson and François Bourguignon (Amsterdam: North-Holland).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Griliches, Zvi, 1991, “The Search for R&D Spillovers,” Scandinavian Journal of Economics, Vol. 94, pp. 2947.

  • Gustafsson, Lennart, and Arne Svensson, 1999, “Public Sector Reform in Sweden” (Malmö: Liber Ekonomi).

  • Hagemann, Robert, 1995, “Social Security in Sweden,” in Challenges to the Swedish Welfare State, ed. by D. Lachman and others, IMF Occasional Paper 130 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hamilton, Kirk, 1999, “Genuine Savings Rates in Developing Countries,” World Bank Economic Review, Vol. 13, pp. 33356.

  • Hansson, Ingemar, 1987, “Marginal Cost of Public Funds for Different Tax Instruments and Government Expenditures,” Scandinavian Journal of Economics, Vol. 86, pp. 11531.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hansson, Par, and Magnus Henrekson, 1994, “A New Framework for Testing the Effect of Government Spending on Growth and Productivity,” Public Choice, Vol. 81, pp. 381401.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Henreckson, Magnus, 1996, “Sweden’s Relative Economic Performance: Lagging Behind or Staying on Top?” Economic Journal, Vol. 106, pp. 174759.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Henreckson, Magnus, and Mats Persson, 2002, “The Effects of Sick Leave on Changes in the Sickness Insurance System,” SSE/EFI Working Paper Series in Economics and Finance, No. 444 (Stockholm).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hibbs, D.A., and Jr., Håkan Locking, 2000, “Wage Dispersion and Productive Efficiency: Evidence for Sweden,” Journal of Labor Economics, Vol. 18, No. 4, pp. 75582.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hoff, Karla, and Andrew B. Lyon, 1995, “Nonleaky Buckets: Optimal Redistributive Taxation and Agency Costs,” Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 58, pp. 36590.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Holmlund, B., and A.S. Kolm, 1995, “Progressive Taxation, Wage Setting, and Unemployment: Theory and Swedish Evidence,” Swedish Economic Policy Review, Vol. 2, pp. 42360.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ilmakunnas, Pekka, and Vesa Kanniainen, 2001, “Entrepreneurship, Economic Risks, and Risk Insurance in the Welfare State: Results with OECD Data, 1978–93,” German Economic Review, Vol. 2, pp. 195218.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Jäntti, Markus, and Sheldon Danziger, 2000, “Income Poverty in Advanced Countries,” in Handbook of Income Distribution, Vol. 1, ed. by Anthony Atkinson and François Bourguignon (Amsterdam: North-Holland).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Johansson, P., and M. Palme, 1993, “The Effect of Economic Incentives on Worker Absenteeism: An Empirical Study Using Swedish Micro Data,” Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 59, pp. 195218.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Jorgensen, Dale W, 1993, “Introduction and Summary,” in Tax Reform and the Cost of Capital: An International Comparison, ed. by Dale Jorgensen and Ralph Landau (Washington: Brookings Institution).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kanniainen, Vesa, and Jan Södersten, 1994, “Costs of Monitoring and Corporate Taxation,” Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 55, pp. 30721.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kay, John A., 1980, “The Deadweight Loss from a Tax System,” Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 13, pp. 11120.

  • Keen, Michael, 1999, “EMU and Tax Competition,” prepared for the XI Villa Mondragone International Economic Seminar (Rome, July).

  • Keen, Michael, 2002, “Some International Issues in Commodity Taxation,” Swedish Economic Policy Review, Vol. 9, pp. 1145.

  • Kessler, Anke, Christoph Lülfesmann, and Gordon Myers, 2000, “Redistribution, Fiscal Competition, and the Politics of Economic Integration” (unpublished; Vancouver: Department of Economics, Simon Fraser University).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • King, Mervyn, 1980, “Taxation and Savings,” in Public Policy and the Tax System, ed. by Geoffrey Heal and Gordon Hughes (London: Allen & Unwin).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • King, Mervyn, and Don Fullerton, eds., 1984, The Taxation of Income from Capital: A Comparative Study of the United States, the United Kingdom, Sweden, and West Germany (Chicago: University of Chicago Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • King, Mervyn, and Mark Robson, 1993, “United Kingdom,” in Tax Reform and the Cost of Capital: An International Comparison, ed. by Dale Jorgensen and Ralph Landau (Washington: Brookings Institution).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kneller, Richard, Michael Bleaney, and Norman Gemmell, 1999, “Fiscal Policy and Growth: Evidence from OECD Countries,” Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 74, pp. 17190.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Knight, Malcolm, Norman Loayza, and Delano Villanueva, 1995, “The Peace Dividend: Military Spending Cuts and Economic Growth,” IMF Working Paper 95/53 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kornai, János, 1997, “Paying the Bill for Goulash Communism: Hungary Development and Macro Stabilization in a Macro Economy” in Struggle and Hope: Essays on Stabilization and Reform in a Post-Socialist Economy, ed. by János Kornai (Cheltenham, U.K., and Northampton, Massachusetts: Elgar).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Korpi, Walter, 1985, “Economic Growth and the Welfare System: Leaky Bucket or Irrigation System?” European Sociological Review, Vol. 1, pp. 97118.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Korpi, Walter, 1996, “Eurosclerosis and the Sclerosis of Objectivity: On the Role of Values Among Economic Policy Experts,” Economic Journal, Vol. 106, pp. 172746.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Koskela, Erkki, and J. Vilmunen, 1996, “Tax Progression Is Good for Employment in Popular Models of Trade Union Behavior,” Labor Economics, Vol. 3, pp. 6580.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Krueger, Anne O., 1978, “Foreign Trade Regimes and Economic Development: Liberalization Attempts and Consequences (Cambridge, Massachusetts: Ballinger).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lachman, Desmond, Adam Bennett, John H. Green, Robert Hagemann, and Ramana Ramaswamy, 1995, Challenges to the Swedish Welfare State, IMF Occasional Paper No. 130 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Landau, Daniel L., 1993, “The Economic Impact of Military Expenditures,” World Bank Policy Research Department Working Paper Series, No. 1138 (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lee, Jong-Wha, 1994, “Capital Goods Imports and Long-Run Growth,” NBER Working Paper 4725 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lindbeck, Assar, 1993, The Selected Essays of Assar Lindbeck, Vol. 2, The Welfare State (Aldershot, U.K.: Edward Elgar).

  • Lindbeck, Assar, 1997, “The Swedish Experiment,” Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 35, No. 3, pp. 12731319.

  • Lindbeck, Assar, Per Molander, Torsten Persson, Olof Petersson, Agnar Sandmo, Birgitta Swedenborg, and Niels Thygesen, 1994, Turning Sweden Around (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lindbeck, Assar, and Dennis J. Snower, 2001, “Centralized Bargaining and Reorganized Work: Are They Compatible?” paper presented at the ECB Annual Labor Market Workshop, Frankfurt, Germany, December 10–11, 2001.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lindquist, Matthew J., 2000, “Wage Compression and Welfare in Sweden,” Working Paper 4 (Stockholm: Stockholm University, Department of Economics).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • McCallum, John, and André Biais, 1987, “Government, Special Interest Groups, and Economic Growth,” Public Choice, Vol. 54, pp. 318.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Maddison, Angus, 2001, “The World Economy: A Millennial Perspective,” OECD Development Centre Studies (Paris: Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Martin, Philippe, 2000, “A Quoi Servent les Politiques Régionales?” Economie Internationale, No. 81 (First Quarter), pp. 320.

  • Masson, Paul, 2000, “Fiscal Policy and Growth in the Context of European Integration,” IMF Working Paper 00/133 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mehrez, Gil, 2002, “Sick Leave in Sweden,” in Sweden: Selected Issues, prepared by Axel Schimmelpfennig and Gil Mehrez, IMF Country Report 02/160 (Washington, August), pp. 3944; available on the Internet at http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/scr/2002/cr02160.pdf.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mendoza, Enrique, Gian Maria Milesi-Ferretti, and Patrick Asea, 1997, “On the Ineffectiveness of Tax Policy in Altering Long-Run Growth: Harberger’s Superneu-trality Conjecture,” Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 66, pp. 99126.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ministry of Finance, Sweden, 1995, The Medium-Term Survey of the Swedish Economy (Stockholm).

  • Ministry of Finance, 2000, Updated Swedish Convergence Program (Stockholm).

  • Mintz, Jack, 1996, “The Corporation Tax,” in The Economics of Tax Policy, ed. by Michael P. Devereux (Oxford: Oxford University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Musgrave, Richard A., 1983, “Who Should Tax, Where, and What?” in Tax Assignment in Federal Countries, ed. by C.E. McLure Jr., (Canberra: Australian National University), pp. 219.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Muten, Leif, 1995, “Sweden Considers New Corporate Income Tax Integration,” Tax Notes International, October 9, p. 1591.

  • Myles, Gareth D., 1995, Public Economics (Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press).

  • National Tax Board (Riksskatteverket), 2000, Tax Statistical Yearbook of Sweden 2000 (Stockholm).

  • Nielsen, Søren Bo, Pascalis Raimondos-Møller, and Guttolm Schjelderup, 1999, “Tax Spillovers Under Separate Accounting and Formula Apportionment” (unpublished; Copenhagen: Copenhagen Business School).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Nordhaus, William D., 2002, “The Health of Nations: The Contribution of Improved Health to Living Standards,” NBER Working Paper 8818 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Nordström, Häkan, 1992, “Studies in Trade Policy and Economic Growth,” Monograph 20 (Stockholm: Institute for International Economic Studies).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Olson, M., 1982, The Rise and Decline of Nations (New Haven: Yale University Press).

  • Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD), 1994, “Regional Characteristics Affecting Small Business Formation: A Cross-National Comparison,” Working Papers (International), Vol. II, No. 8 (Paris: OECD).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD), 2000, “The Tax and Transfer System—Balancing Efficiency and Welfare,” in OECD Economic Surveys: Sweden (Paris: OECD).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD), 2002, 2002 Annual Review—Sweden (EC)/EDR(2002)10 (Paris: OECD, Economic and Development Review Committee).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD), annual, Revenue Statistics of OECD Member Countries (Paris: OECD).

  • Otani, Ichiro, and Delano Villanueva, 1990, “Long-Term Growth in Developing Countries and Its Determinants: An Empirical Analysis,” World Development, Vol. 85, pp. 22338.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Peltzman, S., 1980, “The Growth of Government,” Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. 23, pp. 20987.

  • Pennicott, Katie, ed., 2001, “Lasers Illuminate the Flight of the Bumblebee,” PhysicsWeb, October 16 (Bristol, U.K.: IOP Publishing, Ltd.); available on the Internet at http://physicsweb.org/article/news/5110/9.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Persson, Mats, 1995, “Why Are Taxes So High in Egalitarian Countries?” Scandinavian Journal of Economics, Vol. 97, pp. 569621.

  • Persson, Torsten, and Guido Tabellini, 1991, “Is Inequality Harmful for Growth? Theory and Evidence,” NBER Working Paper 3599 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Persson, Torsten, and Guido Tabellini, 1994, “Is Inequality Harmful for Growth?” American Economic Review, Vol. 84, pp. 60021.

  • Pomp, Richard D., 1999, “The State, the Individual, and the Taxation of Economic Migration,” in Income Taxation and International Mobility, ed. by Jagdish Bhagwati and John D. Wilson (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Romer, Paul M., 1989, “What Determines the Rate of Growth and Technological Change?” World Bank Policy, Planning, and Research Working Paper Series, No. 279 (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ruding Committee, 1992, “Report of the Committee of Independent Experts on Company Taxation” (Brussels: European Commission).

  • Sala-i-Martin, Xavier, 1992, “Public Welfare and Growth,” Yale University Economic Growth Center Discussion Paper 666 (New Haven: Yale University).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Schimmelpfennig, Axel, 2002, “Fiscal Policy and Macroeconomic Stabilization in Sweden,” in Sweden: Selected Issues, prepared by Axel Schimmelpfennig and Gil Mehrez, IMF Country Report 02/160 (Washington, August), pp. 338; available on the Internet at http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/scr/2002/cr02160.pdf

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Schneider, Friedrich, and Dominik Enste, 2000, “Shadow Economies: Size, Causes, and Consequences,” Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 38 (March), pp. 77114.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Seade, Jesus, 1977, “On the Shape of Optimal Income Tax Schedules,” Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 7, pp. 20335.

  • Sen, Amartya, 1976, “Real National Income,” Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 43, pp. 1939.

  • Settergren, Ole, 2001, “The Automatic Balance Mechanism of the Swedish Pension System” (unpublished; Stockholm: National Insurance Board of Sweden).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Sinn, Hans-Werner, 1995, “A Theory of the Welfare State,” Scandinavian Journal of Economics, Vol. 97, pp. 495526.

  • Sinn, Hans-Werner, 2000, “The Threat to the German Welfare State,” CESifo Working Paper 320 (Munich: Center for Economic Studies and the Ifo Institute for Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Sinn, Hans-Werner, 2002, “EU Enlargement and the Future of the Welfare State,” Scottish Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 49, pp. 10415.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Södersten, Jan, 1993, “Sweden,” in Tax Reform and the Cost of Capital: An International Comparison, ed. by Dale Jorgensen and Ralph Landau (Washington: Brookings Institution).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Sørensen, Peter Birch, 1994, “From the Global Income Tax to the Dual Income Tax: Recent Tax Reforms in Nordic Countries,” International Tax and Public Finance, Vol. 1, pp. 5779.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Sørensen, Peter Birch, 1995, “Changing Views of the Corporate Income Tax, National Tax Journal, Vol. 47, pp. 27994.

  • Svallfors, Stefan, 2002, “Welfare Regimes and Welfare Opinion: A Comparison of Eight Western Countries,” in The European Welfare Mix: Institutional Configuration and Distributional Outcomes, ed. by J. Vogel.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Tanzi, Vito, 1995, “Long-Run Growth and Public Policy,” in Social Capability and Long-Term Economic Growth, ed. by Bon Ho Koo and Dwight H. Perkins (New York: St. Martin’s), pp. 14256.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Tanzi, Vito, 2000, “Globalization and the Future of Social Protection” IMF Working Paper 00/12 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Tanzi, Vito, and Ludger Schuknecht, 1995, “The Growth of Government and the Reform of the State in Industrial Countries,” IMF Working Paper 95/130 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Tanzi, Vito, and Howell Zee, 1997, “Fiscal Policy and Long-Run Growth,” IMF Staff Papers, Vol. 44 (June), pp. 179209.

  • Temple, Jonathan, 1999, “The New Growth Evidence,” Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 37, pp. 11256.

  • Transparency International, 2001, Global Corruption Report 2001 (Berlin); available on the Internet at http://www.globalcorruptionreport.org/#download.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • United Nations Development Program (UNDP), 2000, Human Development Report 2000 (New York); available on the Internet at http://www.undp.org/hdr2000.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Wasylenko, Michael, 1991, “Empirical Evidence on Interregional Business Location and the Role of Fiscal Incentives in Economic Development,” in Industry and Location in Public Policy, ed. by H.W Herzog, Jr., and A.M. Schlottmann (Knoxville: University of Tennessee Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Weede, Erich, 1986, “Sectoral Reallocation, Distributional Coalitions, and the Welfare State as Determinants of Economic Growth Rates in Industrialized Democracies,” European Journal of Political Research, Vol. 14, pp. 50119.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Weede, Erich, 1991, “The Impact of State Power on Economic Growth Rates in OECD Countries,” Quality and Quantity, Vol. 25, pp. 42138.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • World Health Organization, 2000, World Health Report (Geneva).