16 Small Countries and the VAT
Author:
Mr. Liam P. Ebrill
Search for other papers by Mr. Liam P. Ebrill in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
,
Mr. Michael Keen
Search for other papers by Mr. Michael Keen in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
, and
Ms. Victoria J Perry
Search for other papers by Ms. Victoria J Perry in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close

Abstract

The past decade has seen the adoption of the VAT by a number of countries that—in terms of population—would generally be regarded as small. Even more strikingly, it was seen in Chapter 1 that many of the countries still without a VAT are also small. The suitability of the VAT for small countries, and small islands in particular, is an issue that arises with increasing frequency. Does country size matter is assessing the advisability of adopting a VAT?

The past decade has seen the adoption of the VAT by a number of countries that—in terms of population—would generally be regarded as small. Even more strikingly, it was seen in Chapter 1 that many of the countries still without a VAT are also small. The suitability of the VAT for small countries, and small islands in particular, is an issue that arises with increasing frequency. Does country size matter is assessing the advisability of adopting a VAT?

Background

Table 16.1 lists the 36 small countries that currently have a VAT, with “small” for this purpose being defined as a population of under five million. All but seven of these adopted the VAT since 1989. The list includes, moreover, seven small island economies144 whose distinctive character may give rise to distinct concerns: no such economy had a VAT prior to 1989.

Table 16.1.

Small Countries with a VAT

article image
Source: IMF staff calculations.

Ratio of VAT revenues to private consumption divided by the standard rate: see Chapter 4. Figures are those available to IMF staff in February 2000.

VAT abolished in 1999.

C-efficiency is for 1995.

The average population of those countries without a VAT—excluding India and the United States (both exceptional cases)—is 7.6 million, compared to an average of 38.3 million for those countries with a VAT. Over a quarter of the countries without a VAT, moreover, are small island economies.

Performance of the VAT in Small Countries

The final column of Table 16.1 reports the C-efficiency ratios145 of the VATs implemented in small countries. They are strikingly high. Indeed, at 65 percent, average C-efficiency for these countries is comparable with the highest of any of the regions identified in Table 4.1. The implication is that the VATs in these countries are relatively well designed and well implemented.

Malta and the VAT

Malta introduced a VAT in January 1995. Initial performance was strong, the VAT raising revenue of about 6.8 percent of GDP and having C-efficiency of around 73 percent.

In December 1996 a new government, committed to repealing the VAT, came to power. As noted in the White Paper For a Better Tax System (January 1997), three main criticisms were leveled at the VAT:

  • “The reality of VAT in a state like Malta is that much of it is a disguised customs duty” (paragraph 2.7). It was argued that a return to explicit tariffs would be superior, recognizing that “… in the particular geographic and economic situation of Malta, customs duties need not be replaced by VAT…to ensure a nondiscriminatory system” (paragraph 2.8).

  • Compliance costs were perceived to be high, especially for medium-sized enterprises.

  • The quite extensive zero rating of domestic consumption, including food other than catering, introduced considerable complexity.

On the first of these, Malta is indeed one of the few countries in which imports exceed consumption, so there is some merit to the argument. In relation to the second criticism, an unusual feature of the initial VAT was a threshold of zero. On the third, widespread zero rating on domestic transactions, of course, is not inherent to small countries.

The VAT was replaced during 1997 by a system relying instead on a broad-based tariff, a single-stage sales tax (the “Excise Tax on Products,” ETP), and selective excises on services. The ETP included crediting and other arrangements to avoid cascading. These replacements were introduced sequentially during 1997, complicating evaluation of the revenue effects of the reform. There seems, however, to have been a noticeable fall in revenue, in the order of 1.5 percent of GDP.

Following a further change of government, the VAT was reintroduced in January 1999 by the party that had initially introduced it. The main structural difference from the initial VAT was an increase in the threshold from zero to, for goods, about $38,500.

Experience with the VAT has inevitably been mixed. Malta, for instance, removed the VAT it introduced in 1995; it was then reintroduced at the start of 1999 (Box 16.1 provides an account of this episode). In other cases, however, such as Barbados, the VAT has been generally seen as a success.

The strong revenue performance of the VAT in these countries is associated with the general observation, developed in Chapter 4, that the performance of the VAT is stronger, all else equal, in economies with a heavier reliance on international trade. As discussed and documented by Alesina and Wacziarg (1998), there is a strong negative correlation between country size and the importance of trade.146 Thus, small economies tend to rely more on trade and so would be expected to have higher C-efficiency.

The econometrics reported in Table 16.2 explores the relationship between country size and the revenue performance of the VAT more closely. The dependent variable is in each case the (log of the) ratio of VAT revenues to private consumption. The first column reproduces a parsimonious specification from the general discussion of VAT performance in Chapter 4 above (column B of Table 4.2). As discussed there, the importance of trade has a significant positive effect. Interestingly for present purposes, the small island dummy appears with a strong positive effect: even conditional upon their reliance on trade, the VAT performs well in island economies. Column B of Table 16.2 repeats the same specification but with the inverse of population replacing openness. As expected, this enters with a strong positive effect. The small island dummy becomes insignificant, but this may merely reflect that these tend also to have the smallest populations, and so effectively correspond to the higher values of the size variables. In column C, the dependent variable is the ratio of VAT revenues to GDP rather than consumption: efficiency again emerges as higher in smaller economies, with small islands now performing well even controlling for their size.

Table 16.2.

Size, Importance of Trade, and the Performance of the VAT

article image
Source: IMF staff calculations. Note: Dependent variable is ratio of VAT revenues to private consumption (in percent) in columns A and B; the ratio of VAT revenues to GDP in column C; t-statistics (constructed from White standard errors) shown in parentheses; * indicates significance at 5 percent, † at 10 percent.

By the standard criteria, the VAT has thus performed well in small countries, with some sign that it has performed especially well in small islands. The natural interpretation is that the importance of international trade for these economies enables them to collect considerable amounts of VAT on imports, and that the geographical remoteness of small islands insulates the tax base, to some degree, from smuggling. This general strong performance does not imply, however, that the VAT is an especially appropriate tax for these economies. Thus:

  • It may be that other taxes would also prove good revenue raisers in these economies. Indeed economies where international trade is important tend to have higher tax yields irrespective of whether they have a VAT or not (as seen in Chapter 4). Given the association between the importance of trade and size, the same will be true of small countries. Moreover, very small economies may have social structures that facilitate tax enforcement.147 Finally, the protection against smuggling which may come with remoteness would presumably help secure tariff revenues as much as it does VAT revenues.

  • These empirical results relate only to the yield of the VAT. It is also important to look to collection costs, again relative to those of other taxes.

Both considerations point to the need to make comparisons with other taxes. In general, there is no single alternative tax to the VAT. For many small economies, however, leading alternatives include a broad-based tariff and a retail sales tax.

Comparing VAT with a Uniform Tariff

Collection costs aside, it is well-known that for a small economy—here using the term in the technical sense of one unable to affect the world prices at which it trades—an appropriately designed consumption tax (such as, but not only, a VAT) is superior to any system with nonzero tariffs. Even if the object of policy is simply to maximize revenue, the consumption tax is in this sense intrinsically superior. Intuitively,148 tariffs mean that private producers face prices that differ from those of world markets, so that their decisions do not lead them to maximize the value of national output at those prices. The country is therefore poorer than it need be. Indeed, it is possible to replace tariffs by consumption taxes in such a way that consumers benefit (as a result of more efficient production) and government revenue simultaneously increases.149

In practice, however, there are collection costs to be weighed against this gain. To assess the likely balance of effects, it is helpful to consider more closely the consequences of moving from a regime in which only tariffs are deployed to one in which only destination-based consumption taxes are deployed. It is easy to show (see Appendix III) that there are three effects to consider:

  • The change in public revenues. Since tax and tariff revenues are simply transfers from public to private sector, this revenue effect should be valued at the marginal efficiency cost of raising revenue; that is, the amount by which the social value of $1 of tax revenue exceeds $1.

  • The change in the deadweight loss that arises from distorting the prices that consumers face away from those at which products must be traded on the world market.

  • The gain in production efficiency from aligning the prices faced by producers with those on world markets. Tariffs on intermediate products, for example, will induce domestic manufacturers to substitute away from those intermediates, implying production techniques which, valued at the world prices that ultimately determine the opportunities open to the economy, are less efficient than they might be.

What do these considerations imply for the suitability of VAT in small countries?

It is always possible to raise at least as much revenue from a consumption tax as from a tariff.150 With a properly designed reform, the first of these effects is thus always positive. How large might it be? This will depend on the rates at which the consumption tax and tariff are set. It will also depend on the size of the respective bases. All else equal, the potential revenue gain in moving from a tariff to a VAT is thus likely to be greater the higher consumption is relative to imports.151 Broadly speaking, one would expect the ratio of consumption to GDP to be independent of country size; the import share, on the other hand, has been seen to be strongly negatively related to size. Thus the ratio of consumption to imports would be expected to increase with size, and this is indeed the case.152 On this account, the advantage of VAT over a broad-based tariff is indeed likely to be less in smaller economies.

The sign of the second effect is ambiguous: deadweight loss could rise in moving to a consumption tax. Taking as a benchmark the case in which it is desirable to tax all goods at the same rate,153 one key consideration will be the breakdown of final consumption between imports and domestically produced items. If much final consumption is imported, then a broad-based tariff will function in large part as a broad-based consumption tax. In so far as small economies would be expected to be relatively undiversified in their production, much of their consumption is likely to be imported. Moreover, much of the consumption that is not imported may be of a kind that either would not in any event likely be subject to VAT, (notably basic agricultural products), or could conveniently be taxed by a well-targeted excise (locally produced alcohol, for instance, or hotel rooms). These observations again suggest that the gains from a VAT will typically be greater in large economies.

The third consideration always tells in favor of the consumption tax, since in a competitive economy eliminating tariffs always increases the value of output at world prices in a competitive economy. The gain is likely to be larger of course, the higher the initial tariffs. This consideration also directs attention to the balance of imports between intermediate and final consumption goods: the greater the share of intermediates in imports, the greater the production inefficiencies induced by the tariff are likely to be. These inefficiencies can be mitigated by duty drawback arrangements (that enable tariffs on intermediates to be reclaimed insofar as they are identifiably used to produce exports) or by outright exemption of intermediates, albeit at the cost of some revenue both directly and perhaps indirectly through the scope for abuse thereby created. In any event, there seems no particular reason to suppose the composition of imports between final consumption and intermediate items—or, hence, the importance of this third consideration—to vary systematically, one way or the other, with country size. Rather, the variation may be more a matter of the state of a country’s development.

On balance, there are grounds for presuming that the gain in moving to a VAT from a broad-based tariff will be less in smaller economies, both because the probable widening of the tax base is likely to be less and because more consumption is likely to be caught, in any event, under the tariff. The basic truth remains, however, that, collection costs aside, the gain is positive: it is better to raise revenue by taxing consumption properly than by distorting trade. Moreover, there may be benefits in putting a VAT in place relatively early in the development process so as provide a solid foundation for future growth.

Thus it can only be collection costs that turn the balance in favor of the tariff strategy. While the collection costs of a VAT were discussed in Chapter 5, the issue for present purposes is how those costs compare, for small economies, with those of collecting tariffs. Unfortunately, there appears to be even less evidence on the costs of collecting tariff revenue than there is on the costs of collecting VAT. It does though seem to be widely supposed that—being collected at a single stage, from a limited number of importers, traditionally heavily reliant on physical verification, and, not least, familiar—tariffs are relatively cheap to administer and comply with.

Fixed collection costs may be a particular concern in small economies. As discussed in Chapter 5, there is strong evidence that there are substantial fixed elements in complying with the VAT, which consequently bears more heavily on smaller firms. Insofar as the average size of firms above the appropriate VAT threshold tends to be smaller in smaller economies—which one might expect to be the case—so collection costs will consequently be more burdensome. Presumably there are fixed components to tariff collection costs too. Their extent, however, is unclear.

In the absence of firm estimates of the likely magnitude of such key quantities as differential collection costs between VAT and tariffs, illustrative calculations can be helpful to give some sense of likely magnitudes. Consider a country thinking of moving from a 10 percent tariff to a 10 percent VAT. Assume that the share of consumption in GDP exceeds that of imports by 20 percentage points, and that under both regimes, half of the base will, for various reasons, be exempt. Assume also that the marginal social value of $1 of tax revenue is $1.25. Finally, assume that the efficiency gains from shifting to the VAT will amount to 0.5 percent of GDP. Then shifting to the VAT will be desirable unless its costs of collection exceed those of the tariff by more than 1.75 percent of GDP,154 which is a large amount. It should be stressed, however, that it may be even more desirable, depending on circumstances to shift the balance not to a VAT but to a simple sales tax combined with excises on a few key commodities.

Conclusions

This discussion points to a number of lessons:

  • Size itself does not seem to be a key concern in determining the desirability of a VAT, except insofar as a smaller average size of taxable firms means that collection costs bear more heavily than they would under other taxes. Little is known about the collection costs of, in particular, tariffs, and how these vary with scale.

  • The importance of trade in many small countries, and the remoteness of many small island economies, are conducive to the effective functioning of the VAT. But these same advantages are also likely to apply to other taxes, not least to tariffs.

  • The advantages of a VAT over a tariff will be greater, all else equal, the lower the share of imports in GDP, the smaller the proportion of consumption that is imported and the larger the share of intermediate goods in imports. The first two of these considerations suggest that the gains from moving to a VAT will indeed be lower in smaller economies.

  • Crude calculations suggest, nevertheless, that the collection cost differential would in many cases have to be implausibly large to outweigh the efficiency and base-broadening gains of moving to a VAT.

  • When there are few stages in domestic production, the VAT may offer little gain over a retail sales tax or broad-based tariff. As the economy develops, however, the merit of the VAT in preserving the chain of taxation will grow. As a longer-term strategy, the introduction of the VAT may serve a useful role in developing familiarity with the tax.

As regards the best advice for these countries:

  • It is appropriate to temper general support for the introduction of a VAT into smaller economies with a note of caution. The gain is likely to be lower in such countries than elsewhere. In some cases, there may be little gain, or even a loss, relative to a broad-based tariff155 or a retail sales tax.

  • It is important clearly to articulate and fully incorporate these considerations into pre-introduction policy analysis.

    • Articulation is especially important, given the general lack of favor with which tariffs are viewed: the point needs to be made that in the absence of domestic production there is no economic difference between a consumption tax and a tariff.

    • There are a few key magnitudes upon which the comparison between tariff and consumption tax turn: the share of imported consumption in total consumption; the share of intermediates in total imports; and the number of stages in domestic consumption. The potential gains from introducing a VAT can be quantified, at least roughly, and it would be useful to do so. Less tangible arguments—such as the wisdom of building a tax system suited for a more sophisticated future—are important, but do not reduce the value of simple calculations.

  • Collapse
  • Expand
  • Ab Iorwerth, Aled, and John Whalley, 1998, “Meals on Wheels: Restaurant and Home Meal Production and the Exemption of Food from Sales and Value-Added Taxes,” NBER Working Paper 6653 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Adams, Thomas S., 1921, “Fundamental Problems of Federal Income Taxation,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 35 (No. 4), pp. 52756.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Agha, Ali, and Jonathan Haughton, 1996, “Designing VAT Systems: Some Efficiency Considerations,” Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 78, pp. 30308.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Alesina, Alberto, and Romain Wacziarg, 1998, “Openness, Country Size, and Government,” Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 69, pp. 30521.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Atkinson, Anthony B., and Joseph E. Stiglitz, 1976, “The Design of Tax Structure: Direct Versus Indirect Taxation,” Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 6, pp. 5575.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Atkinson, Anthony B., and Joseph E. Stiglitz, 1980, Lectures on Public Economics (London and New York: McGraw-Hill).

  • Auerbach, Alan, and L.J. Kotlikoff, 1987, Dynamic Fiscal Policy (Cambridge, U.K., and New York: Cambridge University Press).

  • Aujean, M., Peter Jenkins, and Satya Poddar, 1999, “A New Approach to Public Sector Bodies,” International VAT Monitor, Vol. 10 (No. 4), pp. 14449.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Baer, Katherine, Victoria Summers, and Emil Sunley, 1996, “A Destination VAT for CIS Trade,” MOCT-MOST: Economic Policy in Transitional Economies, Vol. 6, pp. 87106.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ballard, Charles L., and John B. Shoven, 1987, “The Value-Added Tax: The Efficiency Cost of Achieving Progressivity by Using Exemptions,” in Modern Developments in Public Finance: Essays In Honor of Arnold Harberger, ed. by M. Boskin (New York and London: Blackwell).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Besley, Timothy, and Ian Jewitt, 1995, “Uniform Taxation and Consumer Preferences,” Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 58, pp. 7384.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bird, Richard, M., 1993, “Review of ‘Principles and Practice of Value Added Taxation: Lessons for Developing Countries,’” Canadian Tax Journal, Vol. 41 (No. 6), pp. 122225.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bird, Richard, M., 1995, “Indirect Taxes in Belarus: VAT by Subtraction,” Tax Notes International, Vol. 10, pp. 58999.

  • Bird, Richard, M., 1999, “Rethinking Tax Assignment: The Need for Better Subnational Taxes” (unpublished; Toronto: University of Toronto).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bird, Richard, M., and Pierre Pascal Gendron, 1998, “Dual VATs and Cross-Border Trade: Two Problems, One Solution?” International Tax and Public Finance, Vol. 5, pp. 42942.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bird, Richard, M., and Pierre Pascal Gendron, 2000, “CVAT, VIVAT, and Dual VAT: Vertical ‘Sharing’ and Interstate Trade,” International Tax and Public Finance, Vol. 7 (No. 6), pp. 75361.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bird, Richard M., and Jack Mintz, 1999, “Tax Assignment in Canada: A Modest Proposal” (unpublished; Toronto: University of Toronto).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Boadway, Robin, and Michael Keen, 2000, “Redistribution,” in Handbook of Income Distribution, ed. by A.B. Atkinson and F. Bourguignon (Amsterdam: North-Holland), pp. 677789.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bogetić, Zeljko, and Fareed M.A. Hassan, 1993, “Determinants of Value-Added Tax Revenue: A Cross-Section Analysis,” World Bank Policy Research Discussion Paper WPS 1203 (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bogetić, Zeljko, and Fareed M.A. Hassan, 1995, “Explaining the Revenue Potential of VAT,” Tax Notes International, Vol. 10, pp. 104346.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bovenberg, A. Lans, 1987, “Indirect Taxation in Developing Countries: A General Equilibrium Approach” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 34, pp. 33373.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bovenberg, A. Lans, 1994, “Destination- and Origin-based Taxation Under International Capital Mobility,” International Tax and Public Finance, Vol. 1, pp. 24773.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Brealey, Mark, and C. Quigley, eds., 1992, Completing the Internal Market of the European Community (Luxembourg: Office for Official Publications of the European Communities).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cecchini, P., with M. Catinat and A. Jacquemin, 1988, The European Challenge, 1992: The Benefits of a Single Market (Brookfield, Vermont: Wildwood House).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cnossen, Sijbren, 1987, “VAT and RST: A Comparison,” Canadian Tax Journal, Vol. 35 (No. 3), pp. 559615.

  • Cnossen, Sijbren, 1991, “Design of the Value-Added Tax: Lessons from Experience,” in Tax Policy in Developing Countries, d. by J. Khalilzadeh-Shirazi and Anwar Shah (Washington: World Bank), pp. 7285.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cnossen, Sijbren, 1993, “Issues in Adopting and Designing a Value-Added Tax,” in Key Issues in Tax Reform, ed. by C. Sandford (Bath, U.K.: Fiscal Publications), pp. 73107.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cnossen, Sijbren, 1994, “Administrative and Compliance Costs of the VAT: A Review of the Evidence,” Tax Notes, Vol. 63, pp. 160926.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cnossen, Sijbren, 1995, “VAT Treatment of Immovable Property,” Tax Notes International, Vol. 10, pp. 103742.

  • Cnossen, Sijbren, 1998, “Global Trends and Issues in Value-Added Taxation,” International Tax and Public Finance, Vol. 5, pp. 399428.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cnossen, Sijbren, and Carl S. Shoup, 1987, “Coordination of Value-Added Taxes,” in Tax Coordination in the European Community, ed. by Sijbren Cnossen (Deventer, Netherlands: Kluwer Law and Taxation), pp. 5984.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cockfield, Roger, 1997, “A VAT Suspension Regime,” International VAT Monitor, Vol. 8 (No. 3), pp. 11119.

  • Conrad, Robert F., 1990, “Real estate and the VAT” in Value Added Taxation in Developing Countries, ed. by Malcolm Gillis, Carl S. Shoup, and Gerardo Sicat (Washington: World Bank), pp. 95103.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Das-Gupta, Arindam, and Ira N. Gang, 1996, “A Comparison of Sales Taxes,” Public Finance, Vol. 51, pp. 21725.

  • De Wit, Guido, 1995, “The European VAT Experience,” Tax Notes International, Vol. 10, 4954.

  • Deaton, Angus, and Nicholas H. Stern, 1986, “Optimally Uniform Commodity Taxes, Taste Difference, and Lump-Sum Grants,” Economics Letters, Vol. 20 (No. 3), pp. 26366.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Diamond, Peter, and James Mirrlees, 1971, “Optimal Taxation and Public Production I: Production Efficiency,” American Economic Review, Vol. 61 (No. 1), pp. 827.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Due, John F., 1957, Sales Taxation (Urbana, Illinois: University of Illinois Press).

  • Due, John F., 1990, “VAT Treatment of Farmers and Small Firms,” in Value-Added Taxation in Developing Countries, ed. by M. Gillis, C. C. Shoup, and G. Sicat (Washington: World Bank), pp. 5869.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Edwards, Jeremy S.S., Michael J. Keen, and Matti Tuomala, 1994, “Income Tax, Commodity Taxes, and Public Good Provision: A Brief Guide,” Finanzarchiv, Vol. 51 (No. 4), pp. 47287.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • European Commission, 1985, Completing the Internal Market (Luxembourg: Office for Official Publications of the European Communities).

  • European Commission, 1996, A Common System of VAT: A Programme for the Single Market, COM 328(96), Final (Brussels).

  • European Commission, 1998, “Proposal for a Council Directive Amending Directive 77/388/EEC as Regards the Rules Governing the Right to Deduct Value-Added Tax,” COM (98) 377, Final (Brussels).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • European Commission, 1999, “Indirect Taxes and e-commerce,” Working Paper, DGXII (Brussels).

  • European Commission, undated, Value-Added Tax: A Study of the Methods of Taxing Financial Institutions (Brussels).

  • Fitzgerald, J.D., T. Quinn, B. Whelan, and J. Williams, 1988, An Analysis of Cross-Border Shopping, Paper 137 (Dublin: Economic and Social Research Institute).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fratianni, Michele, and Herbert Christie, 1981, “Abolishing Fiscal Frontiers Within the EEC,” Public Finance, Vol. 36, pp. 41129.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gale, William G., and Janet Holtzblatt, 2000, “The Role of Administrative Issues in Tax Reform: Simplicity, Compliance, and Administration,” forthcoming in George R. Zodrow and Peter Mieszkowski, eds., United States Tax Reform in the Twenty-First Century (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Genser, Bernd, 1996, “A Generalized Equivalence Property of Mixed International VAT Regimes,” Scandinavian Journal of Economics, Vol. 98, pp. 25362.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Genser, Bernd, and Günter Schultze, 1997, “Transfer Pricing Under an Origin-Based VAT System,” Finanzarchiv, Vol. 54, pp. 5167.

  • Ghura, Dhaneshwar, 1998, “Determinants of Tax Revenue in Sub-Saharan Africa” (unpublished; Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gillis, Malcolm, Carl S. Shoup, and Gerardo Sicat, 1990, Value-Added Taxation in Developing Countries (Washington: World Bank).

  • Godwin, Michael, 1998, “The VAT Registration Threshold,” British Tax Review, No. 6, pp. 54145.

  • Gottfried, Peter, and Wolfgang Wiegard, 1991, “Exemption Versus Zero Rating: A Hidden Problem of VAT,” Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 46, pp. 30728.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Guerard, Michèle, 1973, “The Brazilian State Value-Added Tax,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 20, pp. 11869.

  • Hall, Robert E., and Alvin Rabushka, 1995, The Flat Tax (California: Hoover Institution Press, 2nd ed.).

  • Hemming, Richard, and John A. Kay, 1981, “The United Kingdom,” in The Value-Added Tax: Lessons from Europe, ed. by Henry J. Aaron (Washington: Brookings Institution), pp. 7589.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hossain, Shahabuddin M., 1995, “The Equity Impact of the Value-Added Tax in Bangladesh,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 42, pp. 41130.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Jenkins, Glenn P., and Rup Khadka, 1997, “Value-Added Tax Policy and Implementation in Singapore,” International VAT Monitor, Vol. 9, pp. 3547.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kay, John A., 1980, “The Deadweight Loss from a Tax System,” Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 13, pp. 11119.

  • Kay, John A., and Evan Davis, 1985, “Extending the VAT Base: Problems and Possibilities,” Fiscal Studies, Vol. 6 (No. 1), pp. 116.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kay, John A., and Evan Davis, 1990, “The VAT and Services,” in Value Added Taxation in Developing Countries, ed. by Malcolm Gillis, Carl S. Shoup, and Gerardo C. Sicat (Washington: The World Bank), pp. 7081.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kay, John A., and Neil Warren, 1980, “Effective Rates of Value-Added Tax,” Working Paper 16 (London: Institute for Fiscal Studies).

  • Keen, Michael, 2000, “CVAT, VIVAT, and All That: New Forms of VAT for Federal Systems,” Canadian Tax Journal, Vol. 48 (No.2), pp. 40924.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Keen, Michael, and Sajal Lahiri, 1998, “The Comparison Between Destination and Origin Principles Under Imperfect Competition,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 45 (No. 2), pp. 32350.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Keen, Michael, and Jenny Ligthart, 1999, “Coordinating Tariff Reduction and Domestic Tax Reform,” IMF Working Paper 99/93 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Keen, Michael, and Jack Mintz, 1998, “The Optimal Threshold for a Value-Added Tax” forthcoming in the Journal of Public Economics.

  • Keen, Michael, and Stephen Smith, 1996, The Future of Value Added Tax in the European Union,” Economic Policy (October 23), pp. 375411 and 41920.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Keen, Michael, and Stephen Smith, 2000, “Viva VIVAT!”, International Tax and Public Finance, Vol. 7, (No. 6), pp. 74151.

  • Keen, Michael, and David Wildasin, 2000, “Pareto Efficiency in International Taxation” (unpublished; Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kenyon, Daphne A., 1996, “A New State VAT? Lessons from New Hampshire,” National Tax Journal, Vol. 49, pp. 38199.

  • Kortenaar, G., and Chr. Spanjersberg, 1999, “Taxation and e-Commerce: Dutch Tax Policy Implications,” Intertax, Vol. 27, pp. 18087.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kotlikoff, Laurence J., and Lawrence H. Summers, 1985, “Tax Incidence,” in Handbook of Public Economics, ed. by M.S. Feldstein and A. Auerbach (Amsterdam: North-Holland), pp. 104392.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lahiri, S., and Y. Ono, 1988, “Helping Minor Firms Reduce Welfare,” Economic Journal, Vol. 98, pp. 11991202.

  • Lauré, Maurice, 1953, La Taxe à la Valeur Ajoutée (Paris: Librairie du Receuil Sirey, 2nd ed.).

  • Lauré, Maurice, 1957, Au Secours de la TVA (Paris, Presses Universitaires de France).

  • Lee, Catherine, Mark Pearson, and Stephen Smith, 1988, Fiscal Harmonization: An Analysis of the Commission’s Proposals, IFS Report Series, No. 28 (London: Institute for Fiscal Studies).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lent, George E., Milka Casanegra, and Michèle Guerard, 1973, “The Value-Added Tax in Developing Countries,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 20, pp. 31878.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Leuthold, Jane H., 1991, “Tax Shares in Developing Economies: A Panel Study,” Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 35, pp. 17385.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Liberati, Paolo, 2001, “The Distributional Effects of Indirect Tax Changes in Italy,” International Tax and Public Finance, Vol. 8, (No. 1), pp. 2751.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lockwood, Ben, 1993, “Commodity Tax Competition Under Destination and Origin Principles,” Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 52, pp. 14162.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lockwood, Ben, David de Meza, and Gareth Myles, 1994, “When Are Destination and Origin Regimes Equivalent?” International Tax and Public Finance, Vol. 1, pp. 524.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Longo, Carlos, 1991, “The VAT in Brazil,” in Tax Policy in Developing Countries, ed. by J. Khalilzadeh-Shirazi and A. Shah (Washington: World Bank), pp. 12128.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Marchand, Maurice, Mario Nava, and Fred Schroyen, 1996, “Optimal Fiscal and Public Expenditure Policy in a Two-Class Economy,” Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 61 (No. 1), pp. 11937.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • McLure, Charles E., Jr., 1987, The Value-Added Tax: Key to Deficit Reduction? (Washington: American Enterprise Institute).

  • McLure, Charles E., Jr., 1999, “Electronic Commerce and the State Retail Sales Tax: A Challenge to American Federalism,” International Tax and Public Finance, Vol. 6, pp. 193224.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • McLure, Charles E., Jr., 2000, “Implementing Sub-National Value-Added Taxes on Internal Trade: The Compensating VAT (CVAT), International Tax and Public Finance, Vol. 7 (No. 6), pp. 72340.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Messere, Ken, 1994, “Consumption Tax Rules,” Bulletin for International Fiscal Documentation, Vol. 48, pp. 66581.

  • Mintz, Jack, 1995, “Business Transfer Tax as a Consumption Tax,” Tax Notes International, Vol. 10, pp. 7586.

  • Nellor, David, 1987, “The Effect of Value-Added Tax on the Tax Ratio,” IMF Working Paper 87/47 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Newbery, David, 1986, “On the Desirability of Input Taxes,” Economics Letters, Vol. 20 (No. 3), pp. 26770.

  • New Zealand, Inland Revenue Department, 1999, GST: A Review (Wellington, New Zealand).

  • OECD, 1988, Taxing Consumption (Paris: OECD).

  • OECD, 2001, Taxation and Electronic Commerce: Implementing the Ottawa Taxation Framework Conditions (Paris: OECD).

  • Ogley, Adrian, 1997, “VAT and Telecommunications Services in the European Union,” Tax Notes International, Vol. 14, pp. 115562.

  • Ogley, Adrian, 1998, Principles of Value-Added Tax: A European Perspective (London: Interfisc).

  • Oldman, Oliver, and Alan Schenk, 1995, “The Business Activities Tax: Have Senators Danforth and Boren Discovered a Better Value-Added Tax?” Tax Notes International, Vol. 10, pp. 5574.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Pellechio, Anthony J., and Catherine B. Hill, 1996, “Equivalence of the Production and Consumption Methods of Calculating the Value-Added Tax: Application to Zambia,” IMF Working Paper 96/67 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Piggott, John, and John Whalley, 1998, “VAT Base Broadening, Self-Supply, and the Informal Sector,” NBER Working Paper 6349 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Poddar, Satya, and Morley English, 1997, “Taxation of Financial Services Under a Value-Added Tax: Applying the Cash-Flow Method,” National Tax Journal, Vol. 50, pp. 89111.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Poterba, James, 1989, “Lifetime Incidence and the Distributional Burden of Excise Taxes,” American Economic Review, Vol. 79 (No. 2) pp. 32530.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Rainer, Anno, and Danny Claeys, 1997, “European Commission Proposes VAT Regime for Telecommunication Services,” Tax Notes International, Vol. 14, pp. 54750.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ring, Raymond J., Jr., 1989, “Proportion of Consumers’ and Producers’ Goods in the General Sales Tax,” National Tax Journal, Vol. 42, pp. 16779.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Rodrik, Dani, 1998, “Why Do More Open Economies Have Bigger Governments?” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 106, pp. 9971032.

  • Sah, Raaj K., 1983, “How Much Redistribution Is Possible through Commodity Taxes?” Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 20 (No. 1), pp. 89101.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Schenk, Alan, and Howell H. Zee, 2001, “Treating Financial Services Under a Value-Added Tax: Conceptual Issues and Country Practices,” Tax Notes International, pp. 330916.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Shoup, Carl S., 1973, The Value-Added Tax (Athens, Greece: Center of Planning and Economic Research).

  • Shoup, Carl S., 1990, “Choosing Among Types of VAT,” in Value-Added Taxation in Developing Countries, ed. by Malcolm Gillis, Carl S. Shoup, and Gerardo P. Sicat (Washington: World Bank), pp. 316.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Silvani, Carlos, and Katherine Baer, 1997, “Designing a Tax Administration Reform Strategy: Experiences and Guidelines,” IMF Working Paper 97/30 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Silvani, Carlos, and Katherine Baer, 1993, “An Analysis of VAT Compliance” (unpublished; Washington: International Monetary Fund).

  • Silvani, Carlos, and Katherine Baer, 1996, “Selected Issues in Administering the VAT: Cross-Checking Invoices and Controlling Refunds to Exporters” (unpublished; Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Silvani, Carlos, Katherine Baer, and John Brondolo, 1996, “Selected Issues in Administering the VAT: Cross-Checking Invoices and Controlling Refunds to Exporters” (mimeo; Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Silvani, Carlos, and Richard Fulford, 1995, “Administration of the VAT in the Russian Federation—Self-Assessment of Tax Liabilities” (Vienna: Joint Vienna Institute).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Södersten, Jan, 1999, “Why Europe Adopted the Value-Added Tax” (unpublished; Uppsala, Sweden: Uppsala University).

  • Stockfisch, J.A., 1985, “Value-Added Taxes and the Size of Government: Some Evidence,” National Tax Journal, Vol. 38 (No. 4), pp. 54752.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Stotsky, Janet, and Asegedech WoldeMariam, 1997, “Tax Effort in Sub-Saharan Africa,” IMF Working Paper 97/107 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Strachan, Valerie, 1998, “Twenty-Five Years of VAT,” British Tax Review, No. 6, pp. 54751.

  • Sullivan, Clara K., 1965, The Tax on Value-Added (New York: Columbia University Press).

  • Summers, Victoria P., and Emil M. Sunley, 1995, “An Analysis of Value-Added Taxes in Russia and Other Countries of the Former Soviet Union,” Tax Notes International, Vol. 10, pp. 204972.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Tait, Alan A., 1988, The Value-Added Tax: International Practice and Problems (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

  • Tait, Alan A., ed., 1991, Value-Added Tax: Administrative and Policy Issues, IMF Occasional Paper No. 88 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Tanzi, Vito, 1987, “Quantitative Characteristics of the Tax Systems of Developing Countries,” in The Theory of Taxation for Developing Countries, ed. by D. Newbery and N. Stern (Oxford: Oxford University Press), pp. 20541.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Tanzi, Vito, 1992, “Structural Factors and Tax Revenue in Developing Countries: A Decade of Evidence,” in Open Economies: Structural Adjustment and Agriculture, ed. by I. Goldin and A.L. Winters (Cambridge, U.K., and New York: Cambridge University Press), pp. 20541.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Tanzi, Vito, 1995, Taxation in an Integrating World (Washington: Brookings Institution).

  • Terkper, Seth A., 1995, “Defending the VAT in Africa,” Tax Notes International, Vol. 11, pp. 131319.

  • Terkper, Seth A., 1996, “VAT in Ghana: Why It Failed,” Tax Notes International, Vol. 12, pp. 180116.

  • United Kingdom, National Audit Office, 1994, “H.M. Customs and Excise: Cost to Business of Complying with VAT Requirements” (London: Her Majesty’s Stationery Office).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Varsano, Ricardo, 1999, “Subnational Taxation and the Treatment of Interstate Trade in Brazil: Problems and a Proposed Solution.” forthcoming in S. J. Burki and G. Peary, eds., Decentralization and Accountability of the Public Sector, Proceedings of the Annual Bank Conference on Development in Latin America and the Caribbean (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Wildasin, David, 1977, “Production Efficiency in Tax-Distorted Economies with Multiple Revenue Constraints” (unpublished; University of Illinois).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Williams, David, 1996, “Value-Added Tax,” in Tax Law Design and Drafting, ed. by Victor Thuronyi (Washington: International Monetary Fund), pp. 164230.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Younger, Stephen D., and David E. Sahn, 1998, “Fiscal Incidence in Africa: Microeconomic Evidence,” Cornell Food and Nutrition Policy Program Working Paper 91 (Ithaca, New York: Cornell University).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Younger, Stephen D., David E. Sahn, David Sahn, Steven Haggblade, and Paul A. Dorosh, 1999, “Tax Incidence in Madagascar: An Analysis Using Household Data,” World Bank Economic Review, Vol. 13, pp. 30331.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Zee, Howell, 1995, “Value-Added Tax,” in Tax Policy Handbook, ed. by Parthasarathi Shome (Washington: International Monetary Fund), pp. 8699.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Zodrow, George R., 1999, “The Sales Tax, the VAT, and Taxes in Between—Or, Is the Only Good NRST a ‘VAT in Drag’?” National Tax Journal, Vol. 52, pp. 42942.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation