VI Scope for Monetary Policy Independence in Oman
Author:
Mr. Khaled Sakr
Search for other papers by Mr. Khaled Sakr in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close

Abstract

As part of its effort to facilitate diversification and enhance resource allocation, the government of Oman has been reforming the financial sector to enhance its ability to efficiently contribute to the objectives of diversification and more rapid growth. This desirable reform, however, has important implications for monetary policy, in particular with regard to the scope of its independence. This section provides empirical evidence on the degree of monetary independence in Oman during the past decade, analyzes the factors that influenced this independence, and examines the scope for such independence at present and in the immediate future.

Scope for Monetary Policy Independence in Oman

As part of its effort to facilitate diversification and enhance resource allocation, the government of Oman has been reforming the financial sector to enhance its ability to efficiently contribute to the objectives of diversification and more rapid growth. This desirable reform, however, has important implications for monetary policy, in particular with regard to the scope of its independence. This section provides empirical evidence on the degree of monetary independence in Oman during the past decade, analyzes the factors that influenced this independence, and examines the scope for such independence at present and in the immediate future.

One might expect the scope of monetary policy independence in Oman, with its open capital account and its fixed exchange rate regime, to be rather limited. Yet empirical evidence suggests that Omani monetary policy has had a significant, albeit varying, degree of independence in the last decade. This section argues that this independence was mainly due to regulatory and institutional factors that limited arbitrage. The evidence, however, also indicates that monetary independence has become increasingly limited, and this trend is expected to continue with progress in vital reforms and with the increased globalization of financial markets. This finding has important implications for the appropriate macroeconomic policy mix and highlights the need for increased reliance on fiscal restraint.

The remainder of this section is organized as follows: We begin with a conceptual background on the scope of monetary policy independence under a fixed exchange rate regime and an open capital account. We then look at certain developments in Oman’s financial sector and at some empirical evidence on the scope for monetary policy independence in Oman during the past decade, and we analyze the factors behind the varying degree of independence. Next the results of formal econometric tests, using cointegration analysis, are reported, to confirm the conclusions of this empirical review. Finally, the key empirical findings and their policy implications are highlighted.

Conceptual Background and Methodology

Theory suggests that, in a small, open economy with a fixed exchange rate regime such as that of Oman, the scope of monetary policy independence is generally limited. Any attempt by the government to influence monetary aggregates, in a way that would result in a significant spread between the domestic interest rate and the interest rate on the peg currency, would lead to large foreign capital flows. These would neutralize the changes in the monetary aggregates and bring the domestic interest rate back to parity.1 Sterilizing such flows can be feasible only in the short run, as it will eventually entice more capital flows unless the economic fundamentals change. In such an environment, the burden of stabilization falls, by and large, on fiscal policy, which, deprived of any active collaboration from monetary policy, has to be restrained in order to maintain price stability and to support the exchange rate.

In the short run, however, significant scope for monetary independence can exist, for various reasons. One is that although monetary policy cannot determine the size of the money supply in an open economy under a fixed exchange rate regime, it can still influence its composition; for example, it can determine the shares of domestic credit and of international reserves in the total. If international money is not a perfect substitute for national money in the short run, monetary policy will then have some independence (Poniachek, 1979). More important, various factors may reduce the efficiency of arbitrage in response to a divergence in interest rates. Such factors include delays in the response of capital flows to interest differentials because of lack of information, institutional factors, high transactions costs, or uncertainty regarding the feasibility of maintaining the peg in view of a deterioration in economic fundamentals. As a result, the government can exercise a reasonable degree of discretion over monetary policy in the short run.2 This would, again in the short run, enable the government to coordinate fiscal and monetary policies more actively. For example, a larger fiscal deficit can be supported by higher interest rates, which will raise domestic financing and at the same time help control inflation. If these factors are at work in the economy, overwhelming inflows should not occur, and therefore there should be no need for large-scale sterilization, no loss of reserves, and no increase in foreign indebtedness.

The next subsection looks at recent trends in the interest rate on Omani treasury bills as compared with that on U.S. treasury bills. The existence of a significant spread between these rates is taken as an indicator of monetary independence. Obviously, such a spread may reflect not only Oman’s degree of monetary independence but also structural differences. For example, unlike the U.S. treasury hill rate, rates on Omani treasury bills are determined only in the primary market—that is, at their auction—since there is no secondary market for these bills. Also unlike U.S. treasury bills, Omani treasury bills are bought primarily by banks. Banks’ demand is not as price-elastic as that of private investors, since treasury bills are counted as reserve assets and thus help banks meet capital adequacy ratios. These considerations may qualify somewhat the results of this study. However, a large spread between the Omani and the U.S. treasury bill rate cannot be sustained for any length of time, given the openness of the Omani economy to international capital flows, unless the CBO has a certain degree of monetary policy independence.

The analysis also links developments in the domestic interest rate (and in the spread) to overall fiscal developments, in particular the domestic financing needs of the budget. Factors permitting monetary independence and restricting arbitrage in the past are also investigated.

An Empirical Investigation

Looking at the case of Oman during the period 1987–97, one can distinguish two main subperiods: the period before the financial liberalization of October 1993, and the period thereafter. We focus our analysis on the behavior of the spread between the interest rates on Omani and U.S. treasury bills and the factors behind that behavior. The two interest rates are plotted in the upper panel of Figure 6.1, and the spread between them is plotted in the lower panel. It appears that until late 1993 the government was able to exercise a considerable degree of monetary independence, as evidenced by the behavior of the interest rate on Omani treasury bills, which, for most of the period, did not track that on U.S. treasury bills. There was a significant spread between the two rates, and this spread changed from negative to positive during that period.

Figure 6.1
Figure 6.1

Omani and U.S. Interest Rates and Spreads

Sources: Data provided by the Omani authorities; IMF, International Financial Statistics, various issues.1 Maturity of 90 days.

Two main factors acting in combination were responsible for this divergence in interest rates. First, interest rates in Oman were subject to various controls that hindered the free operation of the market. For example, interest rate ceilings were imposed on rial Omani deposits of the private sector as well as on commercial bank loans. These distortions affected the way the interest rate behaved so that it did not track the interest rate on the dollar. Second, there was apparently insufficient arbitrage to enforce interest rate parity, because of institutional factors, perceived exchange rate risk, and cost factors. For example, in March 1980 the CBO introduced a facility under which commercial banks could swap dollars at par for five days to three months.3 This facility was intended to improve banks’ ability to manage their own liquidity, but in effect it also encouraged arbitrage operations, as it led to a gain (loss) whenever U.S. interest rates were lower (higher) than that on the rial Omani. In June and July 1986, however, the facility was modified so that arbitrage operations would carry a charge, and this increased their cost. In addition, the modification made banks eligible for subsidies for losses arising from the interest rate differential; this also reduced the incentive for arbitrage.

The ability of resident banks to engage in arbitrage was also restricted by prudential regulations restricting lending and borrowing abroad. For example, effective March 1982, the net foreign exchange position of a resident bank could not exceed 40 percent of its capital and reserves. At the same time, since November 1981, commercial banks have been barred from both holding rial Omani deposits with, and advancing loans in rials to, nonresident banks and financial institutions. These restrictions, in effect, prevented arbitrage by nonresidents, as they were then not able to deal in Omani assets, especially because regulation and tax discrimination severely discouraged both direct and portfolio investment in Oman by foreigners.4 The scope for arbitrage was thus largely limited to arbitrage by resident individuals and to the maximum 40 percent of the relatively small capital and reserves of resident banks. The result of all this was a measure of independence of monetary policy in Oman—as evidenced from the data—during the period up to late 1993.

Looking at domestic interest rate behavior, one can relate these developments to the implicit short-term objective of monetary policy in Oman at that time, which was to raise sufficient domestic financing for the budget. For example, from late 1989 until late 1993, the spread between the interest rate on Omani treasury bills and that on U.S. treasury bills was largely determined by the amount of fiscal financing the government decided to raise, through treasury bills and the issuance of government development bonds at predetermined high interest rates. Indeed, during that period the interest rate spread moved in line with the volume of treasury bills outstanding. This period can be divided into two sub-periods: late 1989 to early 1991, and early 1991 to October 1993.

Developments from Late 1989 to Early 1991

During the first of these two subperiods, high oil prices had a positive impact both on the fiscal balance and on foreign exchange reserves. The government also took this opportunity to limit foreign financing of the budget in 1989 to only RO 46 million, down from about RO 200 million in 1988, and to partly replenish its assets abroad and reduce its foreign debt in 1990 (Table 6.1). So despite the improved overall financial situation, domestic financing increased because the government placed an emphasis on improving the net position of its foreign assets. As a result, domestic financing reached a historically high RO 244 million in 1989 before declining to about RO 190 million in 1990. This was also reflected in an increase in outstanding treasury bills from less than RO 5 million in mid-1989 to more than RO 50 million in early 1991.5

Table 6.1

Budget Financing Needs

(In millions of rials Omani except where noted otherwise)

article image
Source: IMF, Government Finance Statistics, various issues.

Negative numbers indicate deficits.

Despite the increase in outstanding treasury bills and other domestic financing, the government was able to maintain an interest rate that was lower than the interest rate on U.S. treasury bills, with a varying spread that reached 2.9 percentage points in August 1990. This was possible in part because, having increased from a low base, domestic financing needs remained manageable during that period.

Developments from Early 1991 to October 1993

Starting in 1991, however, the negative spread started to narrow; it turned positive by mid-1991. From then until October 1993 the interest rate on Omani treasury bills was higher than that on U.S. treasury bills by up to 2.6 percentage points (in October 1992). This was, again, a result of the government’s decision to restrain foreign financing and the depletion of foreign assets, which resulted in significantly increased domestic financing needs, especially as oil prices weakened and the fiscal deficit widened. During this period, domestic financing of the budget remained at the high level of about RO 200 million and reached a peak of RO 414 million in 1992, In addition to increased borrowing from the monetary authorities, outstanding treasury bills increased to RO 100 million by the end of 1991, RO 160 million by the end of 1992, and about RO 140 million in September 1993. (In October 1992 and July 1993 outstanding treasury bills were estimated at more than RO 200 million.) The government also launched development bonds in September 1991 at a high, administered interest rate to help raise needed budget financing. As a result, the net issuance of treasury bills and development bonds absorbed about 20 percent of national saving in 1991 and 1992. up from as low as 2 percent in 1990 (Table 6.2). This switch in policy, along with the small base of national saving (about 15 percent of GDP), created pressure in the domestic financial market, and this led to a rise in the interest rate. During 1993, however, the government reversed its policy and permitted more foreign financing. This alleviated some of the pressure in the domestic financial market, and as a result the spread started to narrow.

Table 6.2

Debt Instruments and National Saving

article image
Sources: Data provided by the Omani authorities; IMF staff estimates.

Developments Since October 1993

Starting in October 1993, the authorities have been introducing measures aimed at liberalizing the financial market and increasing the participation of nonresidents, particularly GCC nationals. These measures included the elimination of interest rate ceilings on time and savings deposits (October 1993) and on loans (June 1994);6 they also included (in 1996) a reduction in the tax bias against foreign investment and foreign participation in the Muscat Securities Market as part of a more liberal policy toward foreign investors.7 These measures naturally led to an increasing loss of monetary independence. Indeed, as illustrated in Figure 6.1, the interest rate spread between Omani and U.S. treasury bills narrowed starting in late 1993. At the beginning of the period the spread became negative, as the Omani rate became slightly lower than the U.S. rate. By mid-1995, however, the spread took positive values that ranged between 0.07 and 0.53 percentage point. Although this correction was triggered by an increase in domestic financing needs and a corresponding increase in outstanding treasury bills, it also reflected an increased liberalization of the market (and loss of monetary independence). This was evidenced by the fact that the spread continued to remain moderately wide during the second half of 1997, toward a relatively more realistic 0.4 percentage point, despite the continued decline in outstanding treasury bills during the same period.8

Econometric Testing

To formally confirm the findings of the empirical analysis just presented, we tested econometrically for the existence of a significant cointegration between the interest rate on Omani treasury bills and that on U.S. treasury bills, using monthly data. We looked at the period 1987—96 and at three subperiods: 1987–89, 1989–93, and 1993–96. We started by establishing the order of integration of the variables.9 As expected, the stationarity tests confirmed that the variables are nonstationary. The first differences, however, turned out to be stationary, indicating that both variables are integrated of the first order. We then tested for cointegration during the whole period as well as during the three subperiods. As shown in Table 6.3, the results indicate that interest rates on Omani and U.S. treasury bills were not cointegrated during the period 1987–96. This confirms that the Omani interest rate did not closely follow the U.S. interest rate and implies a degree of monetary policy independence during the period as a whole. The results for the three subperiods, however, are somewhat different: Cointegration was found to exist during 1987–89 al a 95 percent confidence level, implying a rather limited degree of independence. No cointegration was found during 1989–93, implying a considerable degree of independence. Finally, during 1993–96 cointegration was observed at a degree of confidence of up to 99 percent, implying loss of monetary independence. These results are in line with the analytical and empirical discussions above and confirm their conclusions.

Table 6.3

Tests for Cointegration (Dickey-Fuller Statistic)

article image
Source: IMF staff estimates.

Indicates cointegration at 99 percent degree of confidence.

Indicates cointegration at 95 percent degree of confidence.

Indicates cointegration at 90 percent degree of confidence.

Conclusions

Past experience indicates that inefficiencies in the financial market, lack of sufficient financial instruments, and restricted foreign access to the domestic market contributed to a degree of monetary independence in Oman in the last decade. The domestic interest rate did not closely follow changes in the U.S. rate, and a spread was sustained whose magnitude corresponded to developments in the government’s domestic financing needs. The analysis presented in this section, however, indicates that, with the availability of more financial instruments, recent financial reform efforts, and increased globalization of financial markets, domestic financial intermediation has increased. This is reflected in the narrowing of the spread and the cointegration of the Omani interest rate with the U.S. rate in the 1993–96 subperiod. As a result, the scope for monetary policy independence in Oman is increasingly narrowing, and the role of monetary policy in the future will essentially be limited to liquidity management based on indirect monetary control. In this context it is fiscal policy that has to shoulder the central role in ensuring macroeconomic stability.

References

  • Dickey, D.A., D.W. Jansen, and D.L. Thornton, 1991, “A Primer on Cointegration with an Application to Money and Income,Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, Vol. 73, No. 2, pp. 5878.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Engle, R., and C. Granger, 1987, “Co-Integration and Error Correction: Representation, Estimation, and Testing,Econometrica, No. 55, pp. 25176.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fleming, J. Marcus, 1962, “Domestic Financial Policies under Fixed and under Floating Exchange Rates,Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 9 (March), pp. 36977.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Frenkel, Jacob A., and Harry G. Johnson, editors, 1976, The Monetary Approach to the Balance of Payments (London: George Allen & Unwin).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hendry, D.F., 1986, “Econometric Modeling with Cointegrated Variables: An Overview,Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, No. 48, pp. 20112.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Johnson, Harry G., 1972, “The Monetary Approach to Balance of Payments Theory,Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, Vol. 7, No. 2 (March), pp. 155572.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Koranchelian, Taline, 1996, “Information Contents of Interest Rate Movements in Jordan and Lebanon: An Empirical Study” (Washington: Middle Eastern Department, International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Laskar, Daniel M., 1982, “Short-Run Independence of Monetary Policy under a Pegged Exchange Rates System: An Econometric Approach,Journal of International Money and Finance, Vol. 1, No. 1 (April), pp. 5779.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mundell, R.A., 1960,The Monetary Dynamics of Adjustment under Fixed and Flexible Exchange Rates,Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 84, No. 2 (May), pp. 22757.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mundell, R.A., 1963, “Capital Mobility and Stabilization Policy under Fixed and under Flexible Exchange Rates,Canadian Journal of Economics, Vol. 29, No. 4 (March), pp. 47585.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ohanian, Lee E., and Alan C. Stockman, 1993, “Short-Run Independence of Monetary Policy under Pegged Exchange Rates and Effects of Money on Exchange Rates and Interest Rates,” NBER Working Paper 4517 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Poniachek, Harvey A., 1979, Monetary Independence under Flexible Exchange Rates (Toronto: Lexington Books).

  • Stockman, Alan C, 1992, “International Transmission under Bretton Woods,” in A Retrospective on Bretton Woods, ed. by Michael Bordo and Barry Eichengreen (Chicago: University of Chicago Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Svensson, Lars E.O., 1994, “Why Exchange Rate Bands? Monetary Independence in Spite of Fixed Exchange Rates,NBER Working Paper 4207 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
1

This scenario is compatible with the monetary approach to the balance of payments and originates in the Mundell-Fleming model, which postulates that capital (lows occur in response to differences between domestic and international interest rates (Mundell, 1960 and 1963; Fleming, 1962). Classic presentations of the monetary approach can he found in (Johnson 1972) and (Frenkel and Johnson 1976).

2

For empirical work supporting this conclusion see (Laskar 1982) and (Stockman 1992). who investigated this question in countries under the Bretton Woods system of fixed exchange rates; see also (Svensson 1994), who looked at European countries in the context of the European Monetary System. For a recent study on two Arab countries, see (Koranchelian 1996).

3

Since December 1991 the facility has entailed maturities ranging from overnight to three months, at the discretion of the participating banks. Individual banks are assigned an access limit based on their net worth.

4

The ability of local branches of foreign banks to arbitrage was also limited by the prudential regulation that prohibited their holding currency balances exceeding their net worth in Oman with their head offices or affiliates abroad.

5

Monthly data on interest rates on treasury bills were obtained from the Omani authorities. The interest rate on U.S. treasury bills was obtained from IMF. International Financial Statistics* various issues.

6

A ceiling continues to apply to consumer loans not exceeding RO 9,000 ($23,400).

7

According to recent amendments in the corporate lax and Muscat Securities Market laws, foreign ownership of up to 49 percent would not disqualify a company from being subject to the same corporate tax rates applied to companies fully owned by Omani nationals. This applied at the beginning to GCC participation only but now extends to all foreign participation.

8

However, the current 0.4-percentage-point spread is still on the low side, partly reflecting the fact that foreign participation remains somewhat restricted, and the fact that the financial market is not yet fully liberalized. For example, an interest rate ceiling on consumer loans remains, and the authorities continue to exert considerable direct guidance over interest rates through unannounced cutoff rates on treasury bill auctions.

9

It is important to establish whether the variables are stationary, that is, integrated or order zero 1(0), because using traditional regressions when the variables are nonstationary can lead to serious problems with traditional statistics such as the R2, the Durbin-Watson statistic, and the t-statistic, resulting in spurious estimates. Economic variables are usually integrated of order one; that is. they are not stationary but their first differences are. One solution around the nonstationarity problem is to run the regression using the first differences. This, however, is inefficient because of the loss of information about the levels. A superior alternative is to test for cointegration, that is, for the existence of a linear combination of the variables that produces a stationary error term. The estimates of that particular linear combination of the variables will not be spurious. An important condition, however, is that the variables have to be integrated of the same order. For classic work on stationarity and cointegration see (Hendry 1986), (Engle and Granger 1987), and Dickey and others, 1991).

  • Collapse
  • Expand
Policies Toward Sustainable Growth
  • Heller, P., Richard Haas, and Ahsan Mansur, 1986, A Review of the Fiscal Impulse Measure, IMF Occasional Paper 44 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation