IV Macroeconomic Effects of Capital Account Liberalization
Author:
Mr. Michael Mussa
Search for other papers by Mr. Michael Mussa in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
,
Mr. Giovanni Dell'Ariccia
Search for other papers by Mr. Giovanni Dell'Ariccia in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
,
Mr. Barry J. Eichengreen https://isni.org/isni/0000000404811396 International Monetary Fund

Search for other papers by Mr. Barry J. Eichengreen in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
, and
Ms. Enrica Detragiache
Search for other papers by Ms. Enrica Detragiache in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close

Abstract

This section describes empirical studies of the link between capital account liberalization and macroeconomic performance.34 It emphasizes measurement issues and the need to recognize the endogeneity of controls, and reviews the statistical evidence on the macroeconomic effects of capital controls and capital account liberalization.

This section describes empirical studies of the link between capital account liberalization and macroeconomic performance.34 It emphasizes measurement issues and the need to recognize the endogeneity of controls, and reviews the statistical evidence on the macroeconomic effects of capital controls and capital account liberalization.

Measurement Issues

A significant obstacle to cross-country studies of capital account liberalization is the absence of a clear measure of the degree of liberalization and the intensity of controls. Most studies have relied on dummy variables constructed from information provided in the IMF’s Annual Report on Exchange Arrangements and Exchange Restrictions (International Monetary Fund, various issues). The most frequently used proxy is a bivariate index of restrictions on payments for capital transactions. Unfortunately, this variable does not measure the intensity of controls, and it primarily captures restrictions on capital outflows (because it refers to resident-owned funds only).35 To overcome the first shortcoming, some studies have also used information on separate exchange rates for some or all capital account transactions (multiple currency practices) and surrender of export proceeds, either separately or combined into a single index of the intensity of controls. A few studies (see, for example, Quinn, 1997; Tamirisa, 1998) have drawn on the information contained in the country-by-country descriptions of foreign exchange restrictions to construct more nuanced indices. Still others have used onshore-offshore or covered interest rate differentials to infer the effectiveness and intensity of controls (see Dooley 1996b for a survey). However, reflecting problems of data availability for many countries, measures based on interest differentials have been used mainly in studies employing high-frequency data for industrial countries. Most of them focus on the effectiveness of controls rather than on their determinants (see Appendix IV).

Determinants of Restrictions

The incidence of controls is not random. Insofar as countries with particular macroeconomic and financial characteristics are especially prone to adopt controls, there is the danger that observers may incorrectly interpret those characteristics as “effects” of controls, when in fact the causality runs in the other direction. It is thus important to analyze the decision to adopt capital account restrictions.

A limited number of studies taking a political economy approach have examined the conditions that make the maintenance of controls or the liberalization of the capital account more likely. Epstein and Schor (1992) are representative of this genre. Using dummy variables from the Annual Report on Exchange Arrangements and Exchange Restrictions for the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) countries, they find that restrictions on capital account transactions are more likely to be imposed in countries with strong left-wing parties and where the central bank is not independent. Alesina, Grilli, and Milesi-Ferretti (1994) and Grilli and Milesi-Ferretti (1995) adopt a similar measure of controls; the first study uses panel data for OECD countries, and the second considers a wider sample of industrial and developing economies. Both find that countries with a fixed or managed exchange rate, low per capita incomes, and high ratios of government consumption to GDP are more likely to maintain controls. Countries with more independent central banks and balanced current accounts are less likely to maintain such controls. Although their measure of the presence of controls does not capture the intensity of the policy, Alesina and Milesi-Ferretti (1995) show that the same results obtain when the capital controls dummy is replaced with a broader measure of restrictions, including multiple exchange rates, surrender of export proceeds, and current account restrictions.

Johnston and others (1998) construct a more detailed measure of controls that exploits the disaggregated information provided in the most recent issue of the Annual Report on Exchange Arrangements and Exchange Restrictions.36 They find that the intensity of capital controls is negatively correlated with economic development and positively correlated with the level of tariff barriers, the black market premium, and the volatility of the exchange rate. No attempt is made, however, to infer the direction of causality. Quinn and Inclán (1997) construct measures of financial openness that combine proxies for current and capital account restrictions and test for the importance of political and structural determinants of openness. They document the trend toward international financial liberalization and find that financial openness is higher in countries with more independent central banks and lower in countries with left-wing governments.37 Finally, Lemmen and Eijffinger (1996) use the onshore-offshore interest differential for 11 OECD countries to proxy for the intensity of controls and find that these are positively related to the domestic rate of inflation, the degree of political instability, and—somewhat surprisingly—the level of investment.38

Macroeconomic Effects

A useful starting point for reviewing this literature is Eichengreen, Rose, and Wyplosz (1996b). These authors ask whether in a sample of industrial countries, there are differences in the behavior of key macroeconomic and policy variables in the presence or absence of capital controls. They separate periods of speculative turbulence, defined as episodes characterized by abnormally large declines in foreign exchange reserves, increases in interest rates, and/or a depreciation of the exchange rate, from tranquil periods. Differences between crises occurring in the presence or absence of controls are evident in the behavior of inflation, money growth, and trade imbalances, all of which are higher in crises occurring in the presence of controls. Such differences are even more noticeable for the observations from tranquil periods: greater real overvaluation, larger budget and trade deficits, and faster growth of money and credit are evident in countries with controls. These findings can be interpreted in two (not incompatible) ways: first, that capital controls have a significant impact on macroeconomic policies and outcomes; and second, that they are imposed to support, at least temporarily, policies that would be unsustainable under free capital mobility.

Other studies, while not distinguishing turbulent and tranquil periods, also focus on the effects of capital controls and liberalization on external variables, inflation, and growth. Johnston and Ryan (1994) test whether capital controls have significantly affected the level and composition of international capital flows in a sample of 52 industrial and developing countries in the 1980s and 1990s. They estimate the determinants of private capital flows and test whether there are differences between restricted and liberalized regimes. For industrial countries, they find that the dismantling of controls has been associated with significant changes in the volume and composition of private capital flows, but they find no evidence of such changes in developing countries, and attribute this last result to evasion.

Citing the experiences of the United Kingdom, Italy, New Zealand, and Spain, Bartolini and Drazen (1997a) and Labán and Larraín (1997) emphasize that the liberalization of outflows often increases inflows. Bartolini and Drazen (1997b) document the positive correlation between restrictions on outflows in developing countries and real interest rates in industrial countries: when industrial country interest rates decline, developing countries tend to remove restrictions on the capital outflows.39 This suggests that the liberalization of capital accounts in the 1990s has been sustained, at least in part, by the persistence of low interest rates in Japan and the United States.40

Alesina, Grilli, and Milesi-Ferretti (1994) and Grilli and Milesi-Ferretti (1995) find that countries imposing controls tend to have higher inflation and greater seigniorage revenue but lower real interest rates. They do not find correlation between capital controls and the rate of economic growth, however.41 Similar results are reported by Rodrik (1998), who finds for a sample of developing countries that the average rate of economic growth during 1975–89 is uncorrelated with the number of years countries had capital controls in place.42 He makes no attempt to control for endogeneity of restrictions, although he argues that, insofar as capital account liberalization generally occurs in periods of good economic performance, the fact that no relation is found may even signal a negative underlying effect of capital controls on growth.43

A limitation of all these studies is that the dummy variable for controls does not provide a measure of their intensity. As noted above, Quinn (1997) addresses this problem by constructing an index of financial and capital account openness for a set of 64 industrial and developing countries. After controlling for initial income, education, and political instability, he analyzes whether changes in this index and its components are correlated with economic growth. He finds a strong positive correlation between capital account liberalization and growth that is robust to changes in model specification. He also finds that capital account liberalization is positively correlated with the ratio of corporate tax revenue to GDP. However, a causal interpretation of these links is complicated by the fact that no effort is made to control for the endogeneity of capital account liberalization.44 Tamirisa (1998) also constructs an index of the degree of capital account restrictions for the year 1996 and finds that capital controls act as a barrier to trade in developing and transition economies.

A final set of studies focuses on whether restrictions on capital mobility limit a country’s ability to smooth consumption when hit by shocks to income (see, for example, Backus, Kehoe, and Kydland, 1992; and Obstfeld, 1994c). Lewis (1996, 1997), for example, tests whether official restrictions on international capital mobility help explain the lack of international risk sharing.45 Her tests are based on the idea that co-movements in consumption and output should be stronger in countries with tighter restrictions on capital flows, because residents of these countries will find it more difficult to smooth shocks to income by borrowing and lending internationally.46 She confirms that consumption and output growth co-vary more strongly in countries with restrictions on international capital flows than in countries without them and that these results hold for different foreign exchange restrictions individually (capital controls, surrender of export proceeds, and so forth). This finding suggests that consumers in countries with extensive international restrictions tend to be more liquidity constrained than consumers in countries with weaker international restrictions.

Financial Development and Growth

A crucial issue in analyzing the link between financial development and growth is measuring financial development itself. Among the measures used in the literature are the ratio of liquid liabilities of the financial system to GDP, the ratio of gross claims on the private sector to GDP, and the share of domestic credit intermediated by deposit banks.1 Studies focusing on the role of liquidity have also used the “value-traded ratio” (the ratio of total value of shares traded on a country’s stock exchanges to GDP) and the turnover ratio (the total value of shares traded on a country’s stock exchanges divided by stock market capitalization) (Levine and Zervos, 1998).

These studies generally conclude that there exists a strong link between financial development and growth (see Levine, 1997, for a survey.) This result is robust to different ways of measuring financial development and holds after initial income, human capital, measures of monetary, trade, and fiscal policy, and political instability are controlled for. Establishing the direction of causality is problematic, however, because financial development is itself affected by economic performance. King and Levine (1993a) adopt a post hoc, ergo propter hoc approach to this problem, confirming that financial development in a particular year is a good predictor of growth performance in subsequent years. Rajan and Zingales (1998) compare growth performance in sectors subject to different degrees of dependence on external finance. If finance stimulates growth, then finance-dependent sectors should grow relatively fast in countries where financial development is more advanced.2 They find evidence that sectors relying more heavily on external finance do indeed grow faster in countries with more developed financial systems.

1 While all these measures have shortcomings, more detailed measures of financial development are not available for enough countries. 2 At the same time, it is less likely that fast growth in these sectors is inducing financial development, and therefore the endogeneity problem in the estimation is reduced.

Qualifications and Implications

These studies provide useful insights into the consequences of capital account liberalization. At best, however, they provide mixed support for the hypothesis that capital account liberalization has a positive impact on economic growth. Existing studies provide weaker evidence of a positive effect on growth for capital account liberalization in particular than for financial development more generally. (On the effects of financial development generally, see Box 4 on page 19.)

It is important to bear in mind several reasons why one might want to be cautious in drawing strong conclusions from these studies. First, insofar as existing studies have failed to fully sort out the direction-of-causality problem, the impact of capital account liberalization on growth may be disguised.47 Second, the dummy variables used in these studies may simply be too crude to capture the growth effects of capital account liberalization.48 Third, whereas the measures of capital controls used in these studies reflect mainly restrictions on capital outflows, much of the current policy discussion focuses on prudential measures likely to have their most immediate impact on capital inflows.49 In this respect, earlier empirical analyses may have only limited implications for the debate over the effectiveness of policies aimed at capital inflows.

Finally, the discussion so far says nothing about one potential macroeconomic effect of removing capital controls: the danger that liberalizing the capital account before the domestic financial system has been suitably strengthened can encourage volatile capital flows that create an environment conducive to the development of serious economic problems and, potentially, financial crises.

34

While a large number of Country-specific studies have examined the impact of capital account liberalization on the domestic financial system (see, for example, Diaz-Alejandro, 1985), and others have focused on the impact of capital account liberalization on economic growth, to our knowledge there exists no systematic cross-country study of the two-way interaction between domestic financial development and capital account liberalization on the one hand and economic performance on the other. The survey here necessarily reflects this limitation of the literature.

35

This is apparent in the data for countries that had controls on capital inflows, such as Germany in the early 1970s; Germany had no capital controls according to this measure.

36

Unfortunately, the nature of the data limits the analysis to a pure cross section for 1996.

37

This last correlation vanishes in the 1980s, however.

38

A possible explanation is that capital controls keep domestic interest rates low, thereby stimulating domestic investment.

39

Conversely, when interest rates rise in the industrial countries, controls in the developing world tend to be tightened.

40

It is important to emphasize the qualifying phrase “in part” when referring to the capital account, and not just because other factors could have been in play. In addition, the relationship does not hold so clearly for policy on capital inflows. That is, a number of countries—brazil, Chile, and Colombia among them—tightened their policies on at least some capital inflows during the same period of low interest rates.

41

After controlling for growth determinants such as initial income, the level of education, and the size of government.

42

After controlling for other growth determinants, among which an index of the quality of government institutions.

43

Rodrik also reports no (conditional) correlation between the number of years capital controls were in place and either the investment rate or the rate of inflation. A possible reconciliation of this last finding and those of Grilli and Milesi-Ferretti (1995) is that the impact of capital account liberalization on the rate of inflation is stronger in time series than in the cross section. This again raises the issue of endogeneity insofar as controls tend to be imposed or strengthened in periods of economic distress when growth is declining and inflation is rising.

44

Clearly, more research is needed to establish the generality of these results. Nevertheless, this study suggests that, to detect an impact of capital account liberalization on economic performance, one must move beyond binary dummy variables and construct measures that proxy, however imperfectly, the intensity of capital account restrictions.

45

Theoretical work by Obstfeld (1994a) and others suggests that the potential welfare gains from international risk sharing can be very large.

46

These tests are applications to international risk sharing of standard tests for the existence of liquidity constraints across consumers. See, for example, Campbell and Mankiw (1989) and Zeldes (1989).

47

As mentioned earlier, Rodrik (1998) argues that insofar as liberalization is associated with faster growth, simultaneity bias, to the extent that it remains, reinforces the skeptical view.

48

As already mentioned, these dummies do not provide a measure of the intensity of controls.

49

See, for example, Folkerts-Landau and Ito (1995). Both these considerations point to the need for complementing the research surveyed in this section with a careful study of recent experiences of countries with and without restrictions on capital inflows (see, for example, Calvo, Leiderman, and Reinhart, 1993; Schadler and others, 1993; and Férnandez-Arias and Montiel, 1996).

Cited By

  • Collapse
  • Expand
Theoretical and Practical Aspects
  • Adams, Charles, and others, 1998, International Capital Markets: Developments, Prospects, and Key Policy Issues, World Economic and Financial Surveys (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Akerlof, George, and Paul M. Romer, 1993, “Looting: the Economic Underworld of Bankruptcy for Profit,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: 2, Brookings Institution.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Alesina, Alberto, and Gian Maria Milesi-Ferretti, 1995, “Controlli sui Movimenti di Capitale e Politica Economica: Un’ Analisi Empirica,” in Studi per il Cinquantenario (Rome, Italy: Laterza).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Alesina, Alberto, Vittorio Grilli, and Gian Maria Milesi-Ferretti, 1994, “The Political Economy of Capital Controls,” in Capital Mobility: The Impact on Consumption, Investment and Growth, ed. by L. Leiderman and A. Razin (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press for CEPR).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Auernheimer, Leonardo, 1987, “On the Outcome of Inconsistent Programs under Exchange Rate and Monetary Rules,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 19, pp. 279305.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bacchetta, Philippe, 1992, “Capital Controls and the Political Premium: The Spanish Experience in the Late 80s” (unpublished; Barcelona, Spain: Institut d’ Analisi Econòmica).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bacchetta, Philippe, and Eric van Wincoop, 1998, “Capital Flows to Emerging Markets: Liberalization, Overshooting and Volatility,” NBER Working Paper No. 6530 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Backus, David K., Patrick J. Kehoe, and Finn E. Kydland, 1992, “International Real Business Cycles,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 100 (August), pp. 74575.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Banerjee, Abhijit, 1992, “A Simple Model of Herd Behavior,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 107, pp. 797817.

  • Bank for International Settlements, 1997, “Central Bank Survey of Foreign Exchange Market Activity” (Basle, Switzerland: Bank for International Settlements, Monetary and Economic Department).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bartolini, Leonardo, and Allan Drazen, 1997a, “Capital Account Liberalization as a Signal,” American Economic Review, Vol. 87 (March), pp. 13854.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bartolini, Leonardo, and Allan Drazen, 1997b, “When Liberal Policies Reflect External Shocks, What Do We Learn?” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 42 (May), pp. 24973.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bayoumi, Tamim, 1990, “Saving-Investment Correlations: Immobile Capital, Government Policy, or Endogenous Behavior?” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 37 (June), pp. 36087.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bayoumi, Tamim, and Barry Eichengreen 1996, “The Stability of the Gold Standard and the Evolution of the International Monetary System,” in Modern Perspectives on the Gold Standard, ed. by Tamim Bayoumi, Barry Eichengreen, and Mark Taylor (Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bernanke, Ben, 1983, “Nonmonetary Effects of the Financial Crisis in the Propagation of the Great Depression,” American Economic Review, Vol. 73, No. 3 (June), pp. 25776.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bhattacharya, Sudipto, and Anjan Thakor, 1994, “Contemporary Banking Theory,” Journal of Financial Intermediation, Vol. 3 (October), pp. 250.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bikhchandani, Sushil, David Hirschleifer, and Ivo Welch, 1992, “A Theory of Fads, Fashion, and Cultural Change in Informational Cascades,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 100 (October), pp. 9921026.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bisignano, Joseph, 1994, “The Internationalisation of Financial Markets: Measurements, Benefits and Unexpected Interdependence,” Cahiers Economiques et Monetaires, Banque de France, Vol. 43, pp. 971.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bloomfield, Arthur I., 1968, “Patterns of Fluctuation in International Finance Before 1914,” Princeton Studies in International Finance, Essays in International Finance, No. 21, International Finance Section, Department of Economics, Princeton University.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bordo, Michael D., and Hugh Rockoff, 1996, “The Gold Standard as a Good Housekeeping Seal of Approval,” Journal of Economic History, Vol. 56 (June), pp. 389428.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bordo, Michael, Barry Eichengreen, and Jong Woo Kim, 1998, “Was There Really an Earlier Period of International Financial Integration Comparable to Today?” paper prepared for the Bank of Korea Conference, “The Implications of Globalization of World Financial Markets,” Seoul, June.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Boyd, John H., and Bruce D. Smith, 1992, “Intermediation and the Equilibrium Allocation of Investment Capital: Implications for Economic Development,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol 30, No. 3, pp. 40932.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Brecher, Richard, and Carlos Diaz-Alejandro, 1977, “Tariffs, Foreign Capital, and Immiserizing Growth,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 7 (November), pp. 31722.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Browne, Francis, and Paul McNelis, 1990, “Exchange Rate Controls and Interest Rate Determination with Traded and Non-Traded Assets: The Irish-United Kingdom Experience,” Journal of International Money and Finance, Vol. 9 (March), pp. 4159.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Buiter, Willem H., 1987, “Borrowing to Defend the Exchange Rate and the Timing and Magnitude of Speculative Attacks” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 23, pp. 22140.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Calomiris, Charles, and R. Glenn Hubbard, 1996, “International Adjustment Under the Gold Standard: Evidence from the United States and Britain, 1879–1914,” in Modern Perspectives on the Gold Standard, ed. by Tamim Bayoumi, Barry Eichengreen, and Mark Taylor (Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Calvo, Guillermo A., 1991, “The Perils of Sterilization,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 38 (December), pp. 92126.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Calvo, Guillermo A., Leonardo Leiderman, and Carmen M. Reinhart, 1993, “Capital Inflows and Real Exchange Rate Appreciation in Latin America: the Role of External Factors,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 40 (March), pp. 10851.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Calvo, Guillermo A., and Enrique G. Mendoza, 1997, “Rational Herd Behavior and the Globalization of Securities Markets,” Institute for Empirical Macroeconomics Discussion Paper, No. 120–1 (August), Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Campbell, John Y., and N. Gregory Mankiw, 1989, “Consumption, Income and Real Interest Rates: Reinterpreting the Time Series Evidence,” Macroeconomics Annual (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Caprio, Gerald, and Daniela Klingebiel, 1996, “Bank Insolvencies: Cross Country Experience,” Working Paper 1620, (Washington: Policy Research Department, World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cardoso, Eliana, and Ilan Goldfajn, 1998, “Capital Flows to Brazil: The Endogeneity of Capital Controls,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 45, (March), pp. 161202.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cardoso, Jaime, and Bernard Laurens, 1998, “The Effectiveness of Capital Controls on Inflows: Lesson from the Experience of Chile” (unpublished; Washington: Monetary and Exchange Affairs Department, International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Chang, Roberto, and Andrés Velasco, 1998, “Financial Fragility and the Exchange Rate Regime,” NBER Working Paper No. 6469 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Chari, V.V., and Ravi Jagannathan, 1988, “Banking Panics, Information, and Rational Expectations Equilibrium,” Journal of Finance, Vol. 43 (July), pp. 74963.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Chari, V.V., and Patrick J. Kehoe, 1997, “Hot Money,” Staff Report 228 (Minneapolis, Minnesota: Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Chinn, Menzie, and Jeffrey Frankel, 1994, “Financial Links Around the Pacific Rim: 1982–1992,” in Exchange Rate Policy and Interdependence, Perspectives from the Pacific Basin, ed. by Reuven Glick, and Michael M. Hutchinson (Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cole, Harold L., and Timothy J. Kehoe, 1996, “A Self-Fulfilling Model of Mexico’s 1994–95 Debt Crisis,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 41 (November), pp. 30930.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cooper, Richard N., 1998, “Should Capital-Account Convertibility Be a World Objective?” in Should the IMF Pursue Capital-Account Convertibility, ed. by Peter B. Kenen, Essays in International Finance, No. 207 (May), International Finance Section, Department of Economics, Princeton University.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cuddington, J.T., 1987, “Capital Flight: Estimates, Issues and Explanations,” Essays in International Finance, No. 58 (December), International Finance Section, Department of Economics, Princeton University.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • DeGrauwe, Paul, and Hans Dewachter, 1990, “A Chaotic Monetary Model of the Exchange Rate,” CEPR Discussion Paper No. 466 (London: Centre for Economic Policy Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Demirgüç-Kunt, Ash, and Enrica Detragiache, 1997, “Banking Crises Around the World: Are There Any Common Threads?” (unpublished; Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Demirgüç-Kunt, Ash, and Enrica Detragiache, 1998, “Financial Liberalization and Financial Fragility,” paper presented at the 1998 World Bank Conference on Development Economics, Washington, D.C., April 22.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Detragiache, Enrica, 1996, “Rational Liquidity Crises in the Sovereign Debt Market: In Search of Theory,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 43 (March), pp. 54570.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Devenow, Andrea, and Ivo Welch, 1996, “Rational Herding in Financial Economics,” European Economic Review, Vol. 40, No. 3–5 (April), pp. 60315.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Diamond, Douglas, and Philip Dybvig, 1983, “Bank Runs, Deposit Insurance, and Liquidity,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 91 (June), pp. 40119.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Diaz-Alejandro, Carlos, 1985, “Good-Bye Financial Repression, Hello Financial Crash,” Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 19 (September–October), pp. 124.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dobson, Wendy, and Pierre Jacquet, 1998, Financial Services Liberalization in the WTO (Washington: Institute for International Economics).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dooley, Michael, 1988, “Capital Flight: A Response to Differences in Financial Risks,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 35 (September), pp. 42236.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dooley, Michael, 1996a, “Capital Controls and Emerging Markets,” International Journal of Finance and Economics, Vol. 1 (July), pp. 197205.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dooley, Michael, 1996b, “A Survey of the Literature on Controls Over International Capital Transactions,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 43 (December), pp. 63987.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dooley, Michael, 1996c, “The Tobin Tax: Good Theory, Weak Evidence, Questionable Policy,” in The Tobin Tax: Copying with Financial Volatility, ed. by Inge Kaul, Isabelle Grunberg, and Mahbub ul Haq (New York: Oxford University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dooley, Michael, and Peter Isard, 1980, “Capital Controls, Political Risks, and Deviations From Interest-Rate Parity,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 88, No. 2 (April), pp. 37084.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dooley, Michael, and Donald Mathieson, 1994, “Exchange Rate Policy, International Capital Mobility, and Monetary Policy Instruments,” in Exchange Rate Policy and Interdependence, Perspective from the Pacific Basin, ed. by R. Glick, and M. Hutchinson (Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dooley, Michael, and Donald Mathieson, and Liliana Rojas-Suarez, 1997, “Capital Mobility and Exchange Market Intervention in Developing Countries,” NBER Working Paper No. 6247 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Edwards, Sebastian, 1989, Real Exchange Rates, Devaluation, and Adjustment (Cambridge, Massachusetts: Massachusetts Institute of Technology Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Edwards, Sebastian, 1998a, “Capital Flows, Real Exchange Rates, and Capital Controls: Some Latin American Experiences” (unpublished; University of California at Los Angeles).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Edwards, Sebastian, 1998b, “The Americas: Capital Controls Are Not the Reason for Chile’s Success,” Wall Street Journal, Section A, April 3, p. 19.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Edwards, Sebastian, and Mohsin Khan, 1985, “Interest Rate Determination in Developing Countries: A Conceptual Framework,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol 32 (September), pp. 377403.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Eichengreen, Barry, and Paul Masson, 1998, Exit Strategies: Policy Options for Countries Seeking Greater Exchange Rate Flexibility, IMF Occasional Paper No. 168 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Eichengreen, Barry, and Andrew K. Rose, 1998, “Staying Afloat When The Wind Shifts: External Factors and Emerging Market Banking Crises,” NBER Working Paper No. 6370, (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Eichengreen, Barry, and Andrew K. Rose, and Charles Wyplosz, 1996a, “Speculative Attacks on Pegged Exchange Rates: An Empirical Exploration with Special Reference to the European Monetary System,” in The New Transatlantic Economy, ed. by (Cambridge, M. B. Canzoneri, V. Grilli and P. Masson, U.K.: Cambridge University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Eichengreen, Barry, and Andrew K. Rose, and 1996b, “Is There a Safe Passage to EMU? Evidence from the Markets,” in The Micro-Structure of Foreign Exchange Markets, ed. by J. Frankel, G. P. Galli, and A. Giovannini (Chicago: University of Chicago Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Eichengreen, Barry, and Charles Wyplosz, 1993, “The Unstable EMS,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: 1, Brookings Institution.

  • Epstein, Gerald, and Juliet B. Schor, 1992, “Structural Determinants and Economic Effects of Capital Controls in OECD Countries,” in Financial Openness and National Autonomy: Opportunities and Constraints, ed. by Tariq Banuri and Juliet B. Schor (Oxford: Clarendon Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Feldstein, Martin, and Charles Horioka, 1980, “Domestic Saving and International Capital Flows,” Economic Journal, Vol. 90 (June), pp. 31429.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Férnandez-Arias, Eduardo, and Peter Montiel, 1996, “The Surge of Capital Inflows to Developing Countries: An Analytical Overview,” World Bank Economic Review, Vol. 10 (January), pp. 5177.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fieleke, Norman, 1994, “International Capital Transactions: Should They Be Restricted?” New England Economic Review (March/April), pp. 2739.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fischer, Stanley, 1998, “Capital Account Liberalization and the Role of the IMF,” in Should the IMF Pursue Capital-Account Convertibility, ed. by Peter B. Kenen, Essays in International Finance, No. 207 (May), International Finance Section, Department of Economics, Princeton University.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fisher, Matthew, and others, 1997, “Capital Account Convertibility and the Role of the Fund—Review of Experience and Consideration of a Possible Amendment of the Articles” (unpublished; Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fishlow, Albert, 1985, “Lessons From the Past: Capital Markets During the 19th Century and the Interwar Period,” International Organization, Vol. 39 (Summer), pp. 383439.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Flandreau, Marc, 1998, “Caveat Emptor: Dealing With Sovereign Risk in the Age of Globalization, 1871–1913” (unpublished; Paris, France: Ecole des Hautes Etudes en Sciences Sociale, Paris).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Flandreau, Marc, Jacques Le Cacheux, and Frederic Zumer, 1998, “Stability Without a Pact? Lessons From the European Gold Standard, 1880–1914,” Economic Policy, No.7, (April), pp. 11562.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Flood, Robert, and Peter Garber, 1984, “Collapsing Exchange Rate Regimes: Some Linear Examples,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 17 (August), pp. 113.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Folkerts-Landau, David, 1997, International Capital Markets: Developments, Prospects, and Key Policy Issues (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Folkerts-Landau, David, and Takatoshi Ito, 1995, International Capital Markets: Developments, Prospects, and Policy Issues (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Folkerts-Landau, David, and Carl-Johann Lindgren, 1998, Towards a Framework for Financial Stability (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Frankel, Jeffrey A., 1993, “Sterilization of Money Inflows: Difficult (Calvo) or Easy (Reisen)?” CIDER Working Paper No. 93–024 (Berkeley, California: University of California at Berkeley).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Frankel, Jeffrey A., and Sergio L. Schmukler, 1996, “Country Fund Discounts and the Mexican Crisis of December 1994: Did Local Residents Turn Pessimistic Before International Investors?” Open Economies Review, Vol. 7, Supp. 1, pp. 51134.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Frankel, Jeffrey A., and Sergio L. Schmukler, 1997, “Country Funds and Asymmetric Information” (unpublished; Berkeley, California: University of California at Berkeley, and Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fukao, Mitsushiro, 1990, “Liberalization of Japan’s Foreign Exchange Controls and Structural Changes in the Balance of Payments,” Bank of Japan Monetary and Economic Studies, Vol. 8 (September), pp. 10165.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Garber, Peter, 1996, “Managing Risk to Financial Markets from Volatile Capital Flows: The Role of Prudential Regulation,” International Journal of Finance and Economics, Vol. 1 (July), pp. 18395.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Garber, Peter, 1998, “Buttressing Capital-Account Liberalization with Prudential Regulation and Foreign Entry,” in Should the IMF Pursue Capital Account Convertibility?, ed. by Peter B. Kenen, Essays in International Finance, No. 207 (May), International Finance Section, Department of Economics, Princeton University.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Garcia, Márcio, and Alexandre Barcinski, 1996, “Capital Flows to Brazil in the Nineties: Macroeconomic Aspects and the Effectiveness of Capital Controls,” Pontificia Universidade Catolica do Rio de Janeiro, Departamento de Economia, Texto Para Discussao No. 357, July.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gerlach, Stefan, and Frank Smets, 1995, “Contagious Speculative Attacks,” European Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 11 (March), pp. 4563.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Giavazzi, Francesco, and Alberto Giovannini, 1989, Limiting Exchange Rate Flexibility: The European Monetary System (Cambridge, Massachusetts: Massachusetts Institute of Technology Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Glick, Reuven, and Andrew K. Rose, 1998, “Why Are Currency Crises Regional?” CEPR Discussion Paper No. 1947 (London: Centre for Economic Policy Research)

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Goldfajn, Ilan, and Rodrigo Valdés, 1997, “Capital Flows and the Twin Crises: The Role of Liquidity,” IMF Working Paper 97/87 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Goldsmith, Raymond W., 1969, Financial Structure and Development (New Haven, Connecticut: Yale University Press).

  • Goldstein, Morris, and David Folkerts-Landau, 1993, International Capital Markets: Part I, Exchange Rate Management and International Capital Flows, World Economic and Financial Surveys, (Washington: International Monetary Fund)

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Goldstein, Morris, and Philip Turner, 1996, “Banking Crises in Emerging Economies: Origins and Policy Options,” BIS Economic Papers No. 46, October.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Goldstein, Morris, and John Hawkins, 1998, “The Origins of the Asian Financial Turmoil” (Australia: Reserve Bank of Australia).

  • Goodman, John B., and Louis W. Pauly, 1993, “The Obsolescence of Capital Controls,” World Politics, Vol. 46 (October), pp. 5082.

  • Greenwald, Bruce, Joseph Stiglitz, and Andrew Weiss, 1984, “Information Imperfections in the Capital Markets and Macroeconomic Fluctuations,” American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, Vol. 74 (May), pp. 19499.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Grilli, Vittorio, and Gian Maria Milesi-Ferretti, 1995, “Economic Effects and Structural Determinants of Capital Controls,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 42, (September), pp. 51751.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gros, Daniel, 1987, “The Effectiveness of Capital Controls: Implications for Monetary Autonomy in the Presence of Incomplete Market Separation,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 34 (December), pp. 62142.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hanson, James A., 1995, “Opening the Capital Account: Costs, Benefits, and Sequencing,” in Capital Controls, Exchange Rates, and Monetary Policy in the World Economy, ed. by Sebastian Edwards (Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hanson, Gordon H., and Antonio Spilembergo, 1996, “Illegal Immigration, Border Enforcement, and Relative Wages: Evidence from Apprehensions at the U.S. Mexico Border,” IMF Seminar Series, No. 1996–33, April.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Haq, Mahbub, Inge Kaul, and Isabelle Grunberg, eds., 1996, The Tobin Tax (Oxford: Oxford University Press).

  • Haque, Nadeem, Manmohan Kumar, and Lamin Leigh, 1994, “International Capital Mobility: Estimates for Developing Countries Using Cointegration Methodology” (unpublished; Washington: Research Department, International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Haque, Nadeem, and Peter Montiel, 1991, “Capital Mobility in Developing Countries: Some Empirical Tests,” World Development, Vol. 19 (October), pp. 139198.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, Annual Report on Exchange Arrangements and Exchange Restrictions, (Washington), various issues.

  • International Monetary Fund, Balance of Payments Statistics Yearbook, (Washington: International Monetary Fund), various issues.

  • International Monetary Fund, 1997, World Economic Outlook, (May/October/December), World Economic and Financial Surveys (Washington).

  • Ito, Takatoshi, and David Folkerts-Landau, 1996, International Capital Markets: Developments, Prospects, and Key Policy Issues (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Jansen, Jos, and Günther Schulze, 1996, “A Note on the Effectiveness of Norwegian Capital Controls,” Aussenwirtschaft, Vol. 51, No. 3 (September), pp. 31325.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Jeanne, O, and Paul R. Masson, 1996, “Was the French Franc Crisis a Sunspot Equilibrium?” (unpublished; Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Johnston, Barry, and Chris Ryan, 1994, “The Impact of Controls on Capital Movements on the Private Capital Accounts of Countries’ Balance of Payments: Empirical Estimates and Policy Implications,” IMF Working Paper No. 94/78 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Johnston, Barry, and others, 1997, “Review of Experience with Capital Account Liberalization and Strengthened Procedures Adopted by the Fund” (unpublished; Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Johnston, Barry, and others, 1998, “Developments and Issues in the International Exchange and Payments System” (unpublished; Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Johnston, Barry, Salim Darbar, and Claudia Echeverria, 1997, “Sequencing Capital Account Liberalization: Lessons from the Experiences in Chile, Indonesia, Korea, and Thailand,” IMF Working Paper No. 97/157 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kamin, Steven, 1988, “Devaluation, Exchange Rate Controls, and Black Markets for Foreign Exchange in Developing Countries,” International Finance Discussion Papers No. 334 (Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kamin, Steven, 1991, “Argentina’s Experience with Parallel Exchange Markets: 1981–1991,” International Finance Discussion Papers, No. 407 (Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kaminsky, Graciela L., and Carmen M. Reinhart, 1996, “The Twin Crises: The Causes of Banking and Balance-of-Payments Problems,” International Finance Discussion Paper No. 544 (Washington: Federal Reserve Board).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kaminsky, Graciela L., Saul Lizondo, and Carmen M. Reinhart, 1998, “Leading Indicators of Currency Crises,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol.45, No. 1 (March), pp. 148.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kane, Edward, J., 1985, The Gathering Crisis in Deposit Insurance, (Cambridge, Massachusetts: Massachusetts Institute of Technology Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • King, Robert, and Ross Levine, 1993a, “Finance, Entrepreneurship and Growth: Theory and Evidence,” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 32 (December), pp. 51342.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • King, Robert, and Ross Levine, 1993b, “Finance and Growth: Schumpeter Might Be Right,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 108 (August), pp. 71737.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Klein, Michael W., and Nancy P. Marion, 1997, “Explaining the Duration of Exchange-Rate Pegs,” Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 54 (December), pp. 387404.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Krugman, Paul, 1979, “A Model of Balance of Payments Crises,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, Vol. 11 (August), pp. 31125.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Krugman, Paul, 1996, “Are Currency Crises Self-Fulfilling?” in Macroeconomics Annual (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Krugman, Paul, 1998, “What Happened to Asia” (unpublished; Cambridge, Massachusetts: Massachusetts Institute of Technology).

  • Labán, Raúl, and Felipe Larraín, 1997, “Can a Liberalization of Capital Outflows Increase Net Capital Inflows?” Journal of International Money and Finance, Vol. 16 (June), pp. 41531.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Le Fort, Guillermo, and Carlos Budnevich, 1996, “Capital Account Regulation and Macroeconomic Policy: Two Latin American Experiences,” The Jerome Levy Economics Institute of Bard College Working Paper No. 162 (Washington: The Jerome Levy Economics Institute of Bard College).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lemmen, Jan J.G., and Sylvester C.W. Eijffinger, 1996, “The Fundamental Determinants of Financial Integration in the European Union,” Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, Vol. 132, No.3, pp. 43256.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Levine, Ross, 1997, “Financial Development and Economic Growth: Views and Agenda,” Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 35 (June), pp. 688726.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Levine, Ross, and Sara Zervos, 1998, “Stock Markets, Banks and Economic Growth,” American Economic Review, Vol. 88 (June) pp. 53758.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lewis, Karen K., 1996, “What Can Explain the Apparent Lack of International Consumption Risk-Sharing?” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 104 (April), pp. 26797.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lewis, Karen K., 1997, “Are Countries with Official International Restrictions ‘Liquidity Constrained’?” European Economic Review, Vol. 41, No. 6 (June), pp. 10791109.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lindgren, Carl-Johann, Gillian Garcia, and Matthew Saal, 1996, Bank Soundness and Macroeconomic Policy (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Maloney, William, 1997, “Testing Capital Account Liberalization Without Forward Rates: Another Look at Chile, 1979–1982,” Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 52 (February), pp. 13968.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Masson, Paul R., 1998, “Contagion: Monsoonal Effects, Spillovers, and Jumps Between Multiple Equilibria” (unpublished; Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mathieson, Donald, and Liliana Rojas-Suárez, 1993, Liberalization of the Capital Account, IMF Occasional Paper No. 103 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • McKinnon, Ronald, 1973, Money and Capital in Economic Development (Baltimore, Maryland: Johns Hopkins University Press).

  • McKinnon, Ronald, 1993, The Order of Economic Liberalization: Financial Control in the Transition to a Market Economy, Second Edition (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • McKinnon, Ronald, and Huw Pill, 1997, “Credible Economic Liberalizations and Over borrowing,” American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, Vol. 87, No. 2 (May), pp. 18993.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Memedovic, Olga, Arie Kuyvenhoven, and Willem Molle, eds., 1997, Globalization of Labour Markets: Challenges, Adjustment and Policy Response in the EU and LDCs (Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Micossi, Stefano, and Salvatore Rossi, 1986, “Controlli sui Movimenti di Capitale: II Caso Italiano,” Giornale degli Economisti, Vol. XLV, No. 1–2 (January/February), pp. 1753.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Milesi-Ferretti, Gian Maria, and Assaf Razin, 1998a, “Sharp Reductions in Current Account Deficits: An Empirical Analysis,” European Economic Review, Vol. 42, No. 3–5, pp. 897908.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Milesi-Ferretti, Gian Maria, and Assaf Razin, 1998b, “Current Account Reversals and Currency Crises: Empirical Regularities,” IMF Working Paper 98/89, June.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Miller, Merton, 1998, “Financial Markets & Economic Growth,” (unpublished, University of Chicago, Graduate School of Business).

  • Miller, Victoria, 1996, “Speculative Currency Attacks with Endogenously-Induced Commercial Bank Crises,” Journal of International Money and Finance, Vol. 15 (June), pp. 383403.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Miller, Victoria, 1998, “The Double Drain with a Cross Border Twist: More on the Relationship Between Banking and Currency Crises,” American Economic Review, Vol. 88, No. 2 (May), pp. 43943.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mishkin, Frederic S., 1996, “Understanding Financial Crises: A Developing Country Perspective,” NBER Working Paper No. 5600 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Montiel, Peter, 1993, “Capital Mobility in Developing Countries: Some Measurement Issues and Empirical Estimates,” Policy Research Department Working Paper No. 1103 (Washington:The World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mussa, Michael, 1998, “Changing Growth Patterns in the World Economy” (unpublished; Washington: International Monetary Fund).

  • Obstfeld, Maurice, 1986, “Rational and Self-Fulfilling Balance of Payments Crises,” American Economic Review, Vol. 76, No. 1 (March), pp. 7281.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Obstfeld, Maurice, 1994a, “Risk-Taking, Global Diversification and Growth,” American Economic Review, Vol. 84, No. 5 (November), pp. 131029.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Obstfeld, Maurice,