III Risks and Benefits of Dollarization
Author:
Mr. Adam Bennett
Search for other papers by Mr. Adam Bennett in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
,
Mr. Eduardo Borensztein
Search for other papers by Mr. Eduardo Borensztein in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
, and
Mr. Tomás J. T. Baliño https://isni.org/isni/0000000404811396 International Monetary Fund

Search for other papers by Mr. Tomás J. T. Baliño in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close

Abstract

In a fully liberalized and convertible financial system, savers would prefer to hold a portion of their portfolio in foreign-currency-denominated assets, simply in order to achieve a desired distribution of risk and returns. But such diversification may increase systemic risks when financial systems are still immature and subject to many distortions. Therefore, dollarization of financial systems in developing countries presents both advantages and risks. On the one hand, allowing FCD in the domestic financial system provides the opportunity to allow greater domestic intermediation. On the other hand, because of currency risk and potential balance of payments problems, the systemic risks are high, and dollarization could increase the potential for financial and banking crises. These considerations imply that the speed with which it would be advisable to advance toward a fully convertible financial system and the proper timing for the liberalization of FCD and loans will be determined by the conditions prevailing in specific cases.

In a fully liberalized and convertible financial system, savers would prefer to hold a portion of their portfolio in foreign-currency-denominated assets, simply in order to achieve a desired distribution of risk and returns. But such diversification may increase systemic risks when financial systems are still immature and subject to many distortions. Therefore, dollarization of financial systems in developing countries presents both advantages and risks. On the one hand, allowing FCD in the domestic financial system provides the opportunity to allow greater domestic intermediation. On the other hand, because of currency risk and potential balance of payments problems, the systemic risks are high, and dollarization could increase the potential for financial and banking crises. These considerations imply that the speed with which it would be advisable to advance toward a fully convertible financial system and the proper timing for the liberalization of FCD and loans will be determined by the conditions prevailing in specific cases.

Benefits

Allowing FCD in the domestic financial system enhances the opportunity for reintermediation in economies that have undergone periods of very high inflation and unstable macroeconomic conditions, during which agents may have become reluctant to hold deposits in the banking system. With a restoration of stability, it is likely that confidence will be rebuilt only gradually. The availability of FCD can speed up this process to the extent that agents may be more willing to return to domestic intermediaries if they can hold dollar-denominated assets.

Allowing FCD also promotes financial deepening. Domestic banks can expand their operations rapidly by competing for the FCD held by residents in cross-border accounts. In fact, the growth of domestic banks would be somewhat limited if they were not allowed to offer FCD, since residents are unlikely to reduce significantly the share of their savings held in the form of dollar financial assets for some time. In addition, the existence of dollar accounts in domestic banks could facilitate the integration of the domestic market into the rest of the world and lower the cost of international financial transactions. Also, in case of fear of devaluation, the availability of FCD may encourage depositors to shift at least part of their local currency deposits (LCD) into FCD rather than CBD.14

Allowing residents to hold FCD can increase credibility by raising the cost of monetary indiscipline, thus committing the government to stronger financial policies. Similar arguments have been made to support the introduction of indexed government debt. A similar type of commitment strategy is to issue dollar-denominated debt to domestic residents as a substitute for domestic currency debt. However, it is not always the case that “raising the stakes” in this form will guarantee sound policies or avoid crises, and the costs of a crisis would be higher if one did occur.15 Furthermore, when confidence is very weak, it would appear that a different type of monetary framework, such as a currency board, would be more effective, both to bolster financial discipline and to reinforce confidence. When even this is not sufficient to strengthen the government’s financial discipline sufficiently, full dollarization—abolition of the domestic currency altogether—could indeed be the only alternative to achieve price stability. This would entail certain losses for the country: forgoing seignorage, limitations to the lender of last resort function, and the loss of the exchange rate instrument. It is true, however, that the value of these resources and instruments is limited in economies that are overwhelmingly dollarized.16 Yet full dollarization, being difficult to reverse, effectively precludes the possibility of a recovery in the demand for domestic money.

Risks

On the negative side, a rapid development of dollar-denominated operations in the banking system increases the risk of crisis in financial and foreign exchange markets. Capital inflows intermediated by the banking system may expand gross official international reserves, with a parallel increase in domestic short-run liabilities in the form of the increase in banks’ required reserves with the monetary authorities. Unless the monetary authorities hold all the resultant increase in required reserves in foreign exchange reserves, there will be a deterioration in their net foreign-currency-denominated position. More-over, the rapid expansion in dollar deposits and loans that may result from a return of flight capital is likely to increase the riskiness of the loan portfolio of the domestic banks. Although this increase in risk would also develop in the domestic-currency loan portfolio, an important difference is that the expansion in loans and deposits under the fractional reserve banking system implies that the total volume of dollar-denominated assets and liabilities will greatly exceed the volume of net dollar assets held in the economy. This lessens the central bank’s ability to act effectively as lender of last resort and increases the vulnerability of the banking system to capital outflows.17 Maturity mismatches between bank assets and liabilities in foreign currency would increase banks’ vulnerability to volatile capital flows. For example, withdrawal of short-term, dollar credits from banks forced the Mexican authorities to provide substantial dollar loans to the banking system in early 1995.18 Further, in the case of a devaluation, loan defaults would increase, and the financial position of banks deteriorate, unless dollar lending is largely to debtors whose net financial position benefits from a devaluation, for example exporters. In fact, the central bank may attempt to avoid significant devaluations because of the likely negative effect on the quality of the banks’ loan portfolios, even if there were otherwise valid macroeconomic reasons to devalue.

Dollarization also implies the loss of seignorage revenues for the monetary authorities (see Fischer, 1982). Other things equal, the use of foreign currency reduces the demand for domestic money and implies a lower level of seignorage for the government. While the central bank may earn some seignorage from below-market remuneration of banks’ required reserves in foreign currency, it cannot avoid seignorage losses that result from foreign currency in circulation. The data on flows of U.S. dollar currency to various dollarized economies (see Table 2) suggest that the circulation of foreign currency, and thus the potential seignorage losses, is indeed substantial in some of the more dollarized economies. For example, if the ratio of U.S. dollar currency to GDP is 10 percent, and monetary aggregates grow at an average of 15 percent a year, seignorage losses would amount to 1.5 percent of GDP a year.19

Cited By

  • Collapse
  • Expand
  • Agénor, Pierre-Richard, and Mohsin S. Khan, 1996, “Foreign Currency Deposits and the Demand for Money in Developing Countries,” Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 50, pp. 10118.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Baliño, Tomás J.T., Charles Enoch, Alain Ize, Veerathai Santiprabhob, Peter Stella, and 1997, Currency Board Arrangements: Issues, Experiences, and Implications for IMF-Supported Programs, Occasional Paper 151 (Washington, D.C.: IMF).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Berg, Andrew, Eduardo Borensztein, and Zhaohui Chen, 1997, “Dollarization, Exchange Rates, and Monetary Policy” (unpublished; Washington: IMF).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bordo, M., and E. Choudri, 1982, “Currency Substitution and Demand for Money: Some Empirical Evidence for Canada,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 14, pp. 4857.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Calvo, Guillermo, and Carlos Végh, 1992, “Currency Substitution in Developing Countries: An Introduction,” Revista de Análisis Económico, Vol. 7, pp. 328.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Calvo, Guillermo, and Carlos Végh, 1996, “From Currency Substitution to Dollarization and Beyond: Analytical and Policy Issues,”in Guillermo Calvo, Money, Exchange Rates, and Output (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press), pp. 15375.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Clements, Benedict, and Gerard Schwartz, 1993, “Currency Substitution: The Recent Experience of Bolivia,” World Development, Vol. 21, pp. 188393.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cuddington, J., 1983, “Currency Substitutability, Capital Mobility and Money Demand,” Journal of International Money and Finance, Vol. 2, pp. 11133.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Drazen, Allen, and Paul R. Masson, 1994, “Credibility of Policies Versus Credibility of Policymakers,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 109, pp. 73554.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • El-Erian, Mohamed, 1988, “Currency Substitution in Egypt and the Yemen Arab Republic: A Comparative Quantitative Analysis,” Staff Papers, IMF, Vol. 35, pp. 85103.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Estrella, Arturo, and Frederic Mishkin, 1996, “Is There a Role for Monetary Aggregates in the Conduct of Monetary Policy?NBER Working Paper 5845 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Feldstein, Martin, and James H. Stock, 1994, “The Use of Monetary Aggregates to Target Nominal GDP,” in N. Gregory Mankiw, ed., Monetary Policy (Chicago: University of Chicago Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fischer, Stanley, 1982, “Seignorage and the Case for a National Money,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 90, pp. 295313.

  • Friedman, Benjamin M., and Kenneth N. Kuttner, 1996, “A Price Target for U.S. Monetary Policy? Lessons from the Experience with Money Growth Targets,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: 1, 1996, pp. 77125.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Garber, Peter, 1996, “Managing Risks to Financial Markets from Volatile Capital Flows: The Role of Prudential Regulation,” International Journal of Finance and Economics, Vol. 1, pp. 18395.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • García, Márcio, 1996, “Avoiding Some Costs of Inflation and Crawling Toward Hyperinflation: The Case of the Brazilian Domestic Currency Substitute,” Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 51, pp. 13959.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • García-Herrero, Alicia, 1997, “Banking Crisis in Latin America in the 1990s: Lessons from Argentina, Paraguay, and Venezuela,” Working Paper 97/140 (Washington: IMF).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Giovannini, Albertoand Bart Turtelboom, 1994, “Currency Substitution,” in F. van der Ploeg, ed., Handbook of International Macroeconomics (Cambridge, Massachusetts: Blackwell).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Girton, Lance, and Don Roper, 1981, “Theory and Implications of Currency Substitution,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 13, pp. 1230.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Guidotti, Pablo, and Carlos Rodríguez, 1992, “Dollarization in Latin America: Gresham’s Law in Reverse?” Staff Papers, IMF, Vol. 39, pp. 51844.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gulde, Anne Marie, Jean Claude Nascimento, and Lorena Zamalloa, 1997, “Liquid Asset Ratios and Financial Sector Reform,” Working Paper 97/144 (Washington: IMF).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kamin, Steven, and Neil Ericsson, 1993, “Dollarization in Argentina,” International Finance Discussion Papers, No. 460 (Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kiguel, Miguel, and Nissan Liviatan, 1994, “Exchange-Rate-Based Stabilization in Argentina and Chile: A Fresh Look,” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 1318 (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kochhar, Kalpana, 1996, “The Definition of Reserve Money: Does It Matter for Financial Programs?” Paper on Policy Analysis and Assessment 96/9 (Washington: IMF).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • McKinnon, Ronald I., 1996, “Direct and Indirect Concepts of International Currency Substitution” in Paul Mizenand Eric J. Pentecost, eds., The Macroeconomics of International Currencies: Theory, Policy, and Evidence (Gloucestershire, U.K.: Edward Elgar), pp. 4459.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Miles, M.A., 1978, “Currency Substitution, Flexible Exchange Rates, and Monetary Independence,” American Economic Review, Vol. 68, pp. 42836.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Monetary and Exchange Affairs Department, IMF 1995, “Reserve Requirements on Foreign Currency Deposits,” MAE Operational Paper 95/1 (Washington).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mueller, Johannes, 1994, “Dollarization in Lebanon,” Working Paper 94/129 (Washington: IMF).

  • Obstfeld, Maurice, and Kenneth Rogoff, 1996, Foundations of International Macroeconomics (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press).

  • Porter, Richard, and Ruth Judson, 1996, “The Location of U.S. Currency: How Much Is Abroad?” Federal Reserve Bulletin, Vol. 82, pp. 883903.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Sahay, Ratna, and Carlos A. Végh, 1996, “Dollarization in Transition Economies: Evidence and Policy Implications,” in Paul Mizenand Eric J. Pentecost, eds., The Macroeconomics of International Currencies: Theory, Policy, and Evidence (Gloucestershire, U.K.: Edward Elgar), pp. 195224.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Savastano, M. A., 1992, “The Pattern of Currency Substitution in Latin America: An Overview,” Revista de Análisis Económico, Vol. 7, pp. 2972.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Savastano, M. A., 1996, “Dollarization in Latin America: Recent Evidence and Policy Issues,” in Paul Mizenand Eric J. Pentecost, eds., The Macroeconomics of International Currencies: Theory, Policy, and Evidence (Gloucestershire, U.K.: Edward Elgar), pp. 22555.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation