I Introduction
Author:
Mr. George Kopits
Search for other papers by Mr. George Kopits in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
and
Mr. Steven A. Symansky
Search for other papers by Mr. Steven A. Symansky in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close

Abstract

Growing interest in fiscal policy rules is in part attributable to the deterioration in fiscal performance, the so-called deficit bias, experienced for more than two decades by a large part of the IMF membership. In many countries the deterioration recently has been reversed—in a number of cases, as part of the convergence toward meeting fiscal rules. Still, some advanced economies face a major task in managing a sustainable fiscal policy over the medium to long run, given uncertainties in the macroeconomic outlook, structural rigidities, and the aging of populations. Equally worrisome are the prospects for developing and transition economies, as continued vulnerability to macroeconomic imbalances prevents realization of their full growth potential, especially in the absence of predictable and sound fiscal policies. In the light of these considerations, in its September 1996 Declaration on Partnership for Sustainable Global Growth, the Interim Committee of the Board of Governors of the International Monetary Fund attached particular importance to “achieving budget balance and strengthened fiscal discipline in a multi-year framework” (IMF, 1996b, p. xii).

Growing interest in fiscal policy rules is in part attributable to the deterioration in fiscal performance, the so-called deficit bias, experienced for more than two decades by a large part of the IMF membership. In many countries the deterioration recently has been reversed—in a number of cases, as part of the convergence toward meeting fiscal rules. Still, some advanced economies face a major task in managing a sustainable fiscal policy over the medium to long run, given uncertainties in the macroeconomic outlook, structural rigidities, and the aging of populations. Equally worrisome are the prospects for developing and transition economies, as continued vulnerability to macroeconomic imbalances prevents realization of their full growth potential, especially in the absence of predictable and sound fiscal policies. In the light of these considerations, in its September 1996 Declaration on Partnership for Sustainable Global Growth, the Interim Committee of the Board of Governors of the International Monetary Fund attached particular importance to “achieving budget balance and strengthened fiscal discipline in a multi-year framework” (IMF, 1996b, p. xii).

This paper addresses a number of major questions. What are fiscal policy rules? What are the principal benefits and drawbacks associated with various fiscal rules, particularly compared with alternative approaches to fiscal adjustment? Can fiscal rules contribute to long-run sustainability and welfare without sacrificing short-run stabilization? If so, what characteristics of fiscal rules make this contribution most effective? And in what circumstances and contexts, if any, should the IMF encourage its member countries to adopt fiscal rules? In an attempt to answer these and related questions, the paper ultimately seeks to identify sensible fiscal policy rules that can succeed, if chosen by a member country or a group of countries, as an alternative to discretionary fiscal policies.

At the outset, we should note that fiscal policy rules tend to be more heterogeneous and complex than monetary and exchange rate rules. Fiscal rules vary considerably across countries in terms of the target variable, institutional coverage, and method of implementation. Although this paper refers to the theoretical literature on the subject, it does not pretend to settle the academic debate over the broader question of policy rules versus discretion. Equally, on the basis of the arguments presented and the relatively limited experience with rules, this paper cannot provide a categorical endorsement (or rejection) of fiscal rules over discretionary practices. Rather, the objective is simply to shed light on the usefulness and advantages of implementing—under appropriate circumstances—fiscal rules endowed with certain characteristics.

Anticipating the discussion of the desirable rule characteristics, transparency stands out as probably the most important attribute in determining the usefulness of such rules.1 In general, clarity in institutional arrangements, measurement, and analysis is a critical element for the formulation and implementation of successful fiscal policy. A hardening of budget constraints, through limits on government deficits or borrowing—whether imposed through a rule or on a discretionary basis—may in fact induce nontransparent practices. Accordingly, application of a fiscal rule without an explicit mandate to maintain transparency is likely to lead to circumvention and distortions, which ultimately erode the effectiveness of the rule. By the same token, transparent implementation of a well-designed and credible medium-term fiscal adjustment program can be highly effective in securing fiscal discipline.

The remainder of this section presents a relatively broad definition of fiscal policy rules (illustrated with examples from a survey of rules provided in Appendix I) and a brief discussion of past fiscal developments that serves as background to the rest of the paper. Section II reviews the arguments often advocated in the literature and used by various countries for adopting rules, followed by a discussion of institutional aspects of fiscal rules. Section III examines the likely economic consequences of fiscal rules, on the basis of actual experience with existing rules and of simulations of proposed rules (discussed in detail in Appendices II and III) for major industrial countries. Building on the preceding sections, Section IV discusses the political economy of rules, outlines the key desirable characteristics of fiscal rules, and explores the implications of the analysis for IMF advice to member countries. The final section summarizes the main findings.

Fiscal Policy Rules Defined

For the purposes of this paper, a fiscal policy rule is defined, in a macroeconomic context, as a permanent constraint on fiscal policy, typically defined in terms of an indicator of overall fiscal performance. The rules under consideration cover summary fiscal indicators, such as the government budget deficit, borrowing, debt, or major components thereof—often expressed as a numerical ceiling or target, in proportion to gross domestic product (GDP) (Box 1).2

Besides consisting of restrictions on the overall budget balance, government borrowing, or public debt (as envisaged under Economic and Monetary Union (EMU) for example), fiscal rules may encompass key subsets of these aggregates, including the current budget balance—that is, permitting borrowing only for investment (as applied with regard to subnational governments in Germany and the United States). Also, in the absence of sufficiently developed domestic financial markets or given limited access to external sources of financing, prohibition on domestic borrowing (as in Indonesia) and restrictions on borrowing from the central bank (as in CFA franc zone member countries) may impose a severe constraint on the budget deficit and thus serve as fiscal rules (Table 1). Specialized rules imposed on the level or allocation of certain categories of government expenditure or revenue, though potentially useful in their own right, are beyond the scope of this paper.

Table 1.

Selected Countries: Fiscal Policy Rules

article image

Source: Appendix I.

Including Stability and Growth Pact and pertinent European Council Regulations.

A critical feature of a fiscal rule is that—regardless of the statutory instrument (international treaty, constitutional amendment, legal provision, or policy guideline) or local terminology3—it is intended for application on a permanent basis by successive governments in a given country, at the national or subnational levels. For a policy rule to be credible, it must involve commitment over a reasonably long period of time.4 Thus, constraints that when adopted were meant to apply indefinitely can be viewed as rules, even if eventually they were abandoned or suspended. In this sense, for example, both the former structural deficit ceiling in the Netherlands and the former limitation on government borrowing to finance capital expenditures in Japan qualify as rules.5 By contrast, budget deficit ceilings or targets specified in the context of a fiscal adjustment program over a preannounced period of time—including one-year or multiyear IMF-supported programs—cannot be regarded as fiscal rules.

Major Types of Fiscal Policy Rules

Balanced-budget or deficit rules

  • Balance between overall revenue and expenditure (that is, prohibition on government borrowing); or limit on government deficit as a proportion of GDP.

  • Balance between structural (or cyclically adjusted) revenue and expenditure; or limit on structural (or cyclically adjusted) deficit as a proportion of GDP.

  • Balance between current revenue and current expenditure (that is, borrowing permitted only to finance capital expenditure).

Borrowing rules

  • Prohibition on government borrowing from domestic sources.

  • Prohibition on government borrowing from central bank; or limit on such borrowing as a proportion of past government revenue or expenditure.

Debt or reserve rules

  • Limit on stock of gross (or net) government liabilities as a proportion of GDP.

  • Target stock of reserves of extrabudgetary contingency funds (such as social security funds) as a proportion of annual benefit payments.

Much like other rules-based policies,6 fiscal rules can be defined in terms of the degree of stringency, precision, and enforcement of the statutory instrument. A narrow definition would require both ex ante (budget approval) and ex post (budget execution) compliance, subject to tangible penalties. Examples include the current budget balance in some U.S. states, the reference value for the budget deficit under EMU, and the borrowing limits in the CFA franc zone; in all these cases, ex post noncompliance carries judicial or financial sanctions.7 A broader definition also encompasses cases of mere ex ante compliance (such as the current budget balance in Germany and in the remaining U.S. states) and those with some latitude in interpretation (for example, the former structural deficit ceiling in the Netherlands, the medium-term operating balance in New Zealand, the medium-term overall balance under the EMU Stability and Growth Pact, and the proposed cyclically adjusted balance in Switzerland), accompanied by reputational sanctions for noncompliance.

There are borderline cases that in principle can be viewed as fiscal rules, such as the provisions for reducing the public debt-GDP ratio to a reference value at a satisfactory pace (under EMU) or to a prudent level while achieving an adequate level of net worth (New Zealand). These provisions may be open to considerable judgment and involve mainly reputational sanctions for noncompliance. Given the significant scope for interpretation, it is debatable whether they qualify as fiscal rules.8

The primary focus of this paper is on fiscal policy rules, as distinct from the procedural rules that can be found in many countries to ensure the execution of either discretionary or rules-based policies. Procedural rules include automatic contingency measures, such as across-the-board cuts in noninterest spending (usually, but not always, excluding transfers under mandatory programs), cash limits, sequestration of funds, or imposition of a surtax.9 These or other measures, specified in advance, are triggered during the fiscal year if actual budget implementation (in terms of expenditure or revenue performance) deviates from budget forecasts, whether in the context of an annual or a multiyear program or pursuant to a fiscal policy rule. A fiscal policy rule that incorporates such contingency measures is called a contingent policy rule.10

Background

To understand the current interest in fiscal policy rules, it is useful to recapitulate the broad fiscal trends in major groups of countries. Except for the past few years, the period since the 1970s—following the breakdown of the Bretton Woods system—has seen a rise in the share of government in economic activity in the advanced economies and widening fiscal imbalances: the strong rise in government outlays was not matched by a commensurate improvement in revenue performance.11 The diverging structural trends in government revenue and expenditure, in combination with a fiscal policy stance guided by the short-run stabilization goal, reflected a largely asymmetrical demand management: budget deficits that emerged during recessions were not fully offset by equivalent surpluses during economic expansions.12

Fiscal developments in the developing economies were characterized by far larger fluctuations. While upward pressures on government spending were, for the most part, just as intense as in the advanced economies, the limits to taxation set in at a much lower level—given a relatively larger informal sector and lower administrative capacity. In addition, in the developing regions, expenditure programs and tax revenues were subject to large swings, reflecting terms-of-trade shocks as well as the relatively short decision-making horizon of unstable governments, compounded by rapid shifts in investor confidence. These developments led to a highly volatile and pro-cyclical fiscal policy stance.13

Faced with widening fiscal imbalances, from the mid-1980s onward, a number of countries launched medium-term fiscal adjustment plans;14 these met with success in only some cases, however.15 Among the advanced economies, the adjustment has been sustained in recent years largely as part of the convergence toward a balanced-budget position under actual (in New Zealand and the European Union) or proposed (in Japan, Switzerland, and the United States) fiscal rules. In developing economies, fiscal adjustment—often undertaken, in the context of an IMF-supported program, following an external payments crisis—has usually included a blend of structural fiscal reform and financial and trade liberalization. But in many cases, as market access was restored, the commitment to consolidating the initial gains from the adjustment vanished and a new crisis emerged, requiring an adjustment effort even tougher than the previous one.16 Taken as a whole, however, these countries have managed to reduce their fiscal deficits in recent years.

As they embarked on a market-oriented transition in the early 1990s, the former centrally planned economies underwent considerable fiscal stress. Owing to the collapse of output, waves of privatization, lack of administrative resources, and growth of the informal sector, tax revenue fell dramatically. Meanwhile, the need for government expenditure in building infrastructure and social safety nets and in supporting enterprise and bank restructuring was only partially financed by savings from sizable cuts in price subsidies. In some cases, fiscal imbalances were exacerbated by large, inherited debt-service obligations—in part carried outside the budgetary accounts. More recently, an increasing number of transition economies have made progress in reducing their fiscal deficits and achieving some policy credibility.17

Fiscal developments over the past two decades can be summarized by four observations. First, many countries experienced a deficit bias, reflected in the steady deterioration in public finances; a recent reversal, in a number of cases, is mainly attributable to convergence under fiscal rules. Second, efforts to arrest this deterioration with short- or medium-term discretionary action have succeeded in relatively few countries. Third, contrary to previously held conventional wisdom—largely derived from Keynesian tradition—fiscal adjustment, if underpinned by structural reform, need not induce a recession.18 And, fourth, a critical ingredient to successful adjustment is prolonged commitment to fiscal discipline.

Cited By

  • Collapse
  • Expand
  • Alesina, Alberto, and Tamim Bayoumi, 1996, “The Costs and Benefits of Fiscal Rules: Evidence from U.S. States,” NBER Working Paper No. 5614 (Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Alesina, Alberto, and Roberto Perotti, 1995, “The Political Economy of Budget Deficits,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 42 (March), pp. 1 –31.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • ———, 1996, “Fiscal Adjustments in OECD Countries: Composition and Macroeconomic Effects,” IMF Working Paper 96/70 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Baliño, Tomás, and Charles Enoch, 1997, Currency Board Arrangements: Issues and Experiences, IMF Occasional Paper No. 151 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bayoumi, Tamim, and Barry Eichengreen, 1995, “Restraining Yourself: The Implications of Fiscal Rules for Economic Stabilization,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 42 (March), pp. 32 –48.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bayoumi, Tamim, Morris Goldstein, and Geoffrey Woglom, 1995, “Do Credit Markets Discipline Sovereign Borrowers? Evidence from U.S. States,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 27, Part 1 (November), pp. 1046 –59.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bertola, Giuseppe, and A. Drazen, 1993, “Trigger Points and Budget Cuts: Explaining the Effects of Fiscal Austerity,” American Economic Review, Vol. 83 (March), pp. 11 –26.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Blejer, Mario I., and others, eds., 1997, Optimum Currency Areas: New Analytical and Policy Developments (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bohn, Henning, and Robert P. Inman, 1996, “Balanced Budget Rules and Public Deficits: Evidence from the U.S. States,” NBER Working Paper No. 5533 (Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bordo, Michael D., and Eugene N. White, 1993, “British and French Finance During the Napoleonic Wars,” in Monetary Regimes in Transition, ed. by M. Bordo and F. Capie (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bryant, Ralph C., Dale W. Henderson, Gerald Holtham, Peter Hooper, and Steven A. Symansky, eds., 1988, Empirical Macroeconomics for Interdependent Economies, 2 vols. (Washington: Brookings Institution).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bryant, Ralph C., Peter Hooper, and Catherine L. Mann, eds., 1993, Evaluating Policy Regimes: New Research in Empirical Macroeconomics (Washington: Brookings Institution).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bryant, Ralph C., and Long Zhang, 1996, “Intertemporal Fiscal Policy in Macroeconomic Models: Introduction and Major Alternatives,” Brookings Discussion Papers in International Economics, No. 123 (Washington: Brookings Institution).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Buchanan, James M., and Richard E. Wagner, 1977, Democracy in Deficit: The Political Legacy of Lord Keynes (New York: Academic Press).

  • Buiter, Willem, Giancarlo Corsetti, and Nouriel Roubini, 1993, “Maastricht‘s Fiscal Rules,” Economic Policy: A European Forum, Vol. 8 (April), pp. 58 –100.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Buti, M., D. Franco, and H. Ongena, 1997, “Budgetary Policies During Recessions: Retrospective Application of the ‘Stability and Growth Pact‘ to the Post-War Period,” Economic Papers, No. 121 (Brussels: European Commission Directorate-General for Economic and Financial Affairs).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cangiano, Marco, 1996, “Accountability and Transparency in the Public Sector: The New Zealand Experience,” IMF Working Paper 96/122 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cheasty, Adrienne, and Jeffrey M. Davis, 1996, “Fiscal Transition in Countries of the Former Soviet Union: An Interim Assessment,” IMF Working Paper 96/61 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Clément, Jean A.P., Johannes Mueller, Stéphane Cossé, and Jean Le Dem, 1996, Aftermath of the CFA Franc Devaluation, IMF Occasional Paper No. 138 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Corsetti, Giancarlo, and Nouriel Roubini, 1993, “The Design of Optimal Fiscal Rules for Europe After 1992,” in Adjustment and Growth in the European Monetary Union, ed. by Francisco Torres and Francesco Giavazzi (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cottarelli, Carlo, 1993, Limiting Central Bank Credit to the Government: Theory and Practice, IMF Occasional Paper No. 110 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cour, Philippine, Eric Dubois, Selma Mahfouz, and Jean Pisani-Ferry, 1996, “The Cost of Fiscal Retrenchment Revisited: How Strong Is the Evidence?” CEPII Working Paper 96/16 (Paris: Centre d‘Etudes Prospectives et d‘Informations Internationales).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Craig, Jon D., 1987, “Macro Controls on Public Spending,” Restraining Leviathan: Small Government in Practice, ed. by Michael James (St. Leonards, NSW, Australia: Centre for Independent Studies).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cukierman, Alex, and Allan H. Metzler, 1986, “A Positive Theory of Discretionary Policy, the Cost of Democratic Government, and the Benefits of a Constitution,” Economic Inquiry, Vol. 24 (July), pp. 367 –88.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • de Menil, Georges, 1996, “Budgetary Policies in Europe on the Eve of Monetary Union,” paper presented at the DELTA-CEPII Workshop, “The Macroeconomic Effects of Fiscal Adjustments,” Paris, September (unpublished; Paris: Centre d‘Etudes Prospectives et d‘Informations Internationales).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Drazen, Allan, and Paul R. Masson, 1994, “Credibility of Policies Versus Credibility of Policymakers,” IMF Working Paper 94/49 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dubois, Eric, 1996, “High Real Interest Rates: The Consequence of a Saving-Investment Disequilibrium or of an Insufficient Credibility of Monetary Authorities?” (unpublished; Paris: Institut National de la Statistique et des Etudes Economiques).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Easterly, William, 1996, “When Is Stabilization Expansionary? Evidence from High Inflation,” Economic Policy: A European Forum, No. 22 (April), pp. 67 –107.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Eichengreen, Barry, and Jürgen von Hagen, 1995, “Fiscal Policy and Monetary Union: Federalism, Fiscal Restrictions and the No-Bailout Rule,” CEPR Discussion Paper No. 1247 (London: Centre for Economic Policy Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Eichengreen, Barry, Ricardo Hausmann, and Jürgen von Hagen, 1996, “Reforming Budgetary Institutions in Latin America: The Case for a National Fiscal Council,” IDB Working Paper No. 011 (Washington: Inter-American Development Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • European Commission, 1995, “Methodological and Operational Aspects of the Reporting of Government Deficits and Debt Levels in the Context of the Excessive Deficit Procedure” (Brussels: Directorate-General II, July).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • ———, 1996, “Annexes to the Conclusions of the Presidency,” Bulletin of the European Union (Brussels: European Commission, Secretariat-General), pp. 20 –33.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Evans, Paul, 1985, “Do Large Deficits Produce High Interest Rates?” American Economic Review, Vol. 75 (March), pp. 68 –87.

  • Faruqee, Hamid, Douglas Laxton, and Steven Symansky, 1996, “Government Debt, Life-Cycle Income, and Liquidity Constraints: Beyond Approximate Ricardian Equivalence,” IMF Working Paper 96/140 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fischer, Stanley, 1988, “International Macroeconomic Policy Coordination,” in International Economic Cooperation, ed. by Martin Feldstein (Chicago and London: University of Chicago Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • ———, Ratna Sahay, Carlos A. Vegh, 1996, “Stabilization and Growth in Transition Economies,” Journal of Economic Perspectives (Spring), pp. 45 –66.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ford, Robert, Douglas Laxton, 1995, “World Public Debt and Real Interest Rates,” IMF Working Paper 95/30 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Friedman, Milton, 1995, “Balanced Budget: Amendment Must Put Limit on Taxes,” Wall Street Journal (January 4), p. A12.

  • Gavin, Michael, Hausmann, Ricardo Perotti, Roberto Talvi, Ernesto 1996, “Managing Fiscal Policy in Latin America and the Caribbean: Volatility, Procyclicality, and Limited Creditworthiness,” IDB Working Paper No. 13 (Washington: Inter-American Development Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Green, John H., 1996, “Inflation Targeting: Theory and Policy Implications,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 43 (December), pp. 779 –95.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Guitián, Manuel, 1992, Rules and Discretion in International Economic Policy, IMF Occasional Paper No. 97 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Helbling, Thomas, and Robert Wescott, 1995, “The Global Real Interest Rate,” Staff Studies for the World Economic Outlook, by the Research Department of the IMF (Washington: International Monetary Fund, September), pp. 28 –51.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Helpman, Elhanan, Leonardo Leiderman, and Gil Bufman, 1994, “New Breed Exchange Rate Bands: Chile, Israel, and Mexico,” Economic Policy: A European Forum, No. 19 (October), pp. 259 –306.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, 1995a, Government Finance Statistics Yearbook (Washington).

  • ———, 1995b, World Economic Outlook, October 1995: A Survey by the Staff of the International Monetary Fund, World Economic and Financial Surveys (Washington).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • ———, 1996a, World Economic Outlook, May 1996: A Survey by the Staff of the International Monetary Fund, World Economic and Financial Surveys (Washington).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • ———, 1996b, World Economic Outlook, October 1996: A Survey by the Staff of the International Monetary Fund, World Economic and Financial Surveys (Washington).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • ———, 1996c, “Germany: Recent Economic Developments and Selected Issues,” IMF Staff Country Report No. 96/111 (Washington).

  • Kopits, George, 1994, “Monetary and Fiscal Management During the Transformation,” in Government and Markets: Establishing a Democratic Constitutional Order and a Market Economy in Former Socialist Countries, ed. by Hendrikus J. Blommestein and Bernard Steunenberg (Dordrecht: Kluwer).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • ———, 1997, “Are Europe‘s Social Security Finances Compatible with EMU?” IMF Paper on Policy Analysis and Assessment 97/3 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • ———, and Jon Craig, 1998, Transparency in Government Operations, IMF Occasional Paper No. 158 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kopits, George, Robert Hagemann, Lazaros Molho, and Olav Bjerkholt, 1993, “Fiscal Rules in Indonesia: Analysis and Reform Proposal” (unpublished; Washington: International Monetary Fund, March).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kotlikoff, Laurence J., 1989, “From Deficit Delusion to the Fiscal Balance Rule: Looking for an Economically Meaningful Way to Assess Fiscal Policy,” IMF Working Paper 89/50 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kydland, Finn E., and Edward C. Prescott, 1977, “Rules Rather Than Discretion: The Inconsistency of Optimal Plans,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 85, pp. 473 –91.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Laidler, David, 1985, “Fiscal Deficits and International Monetary Institutions,” Centre for the Study of International Economic Relations Working Paper No. 8526C (London, Canada: University of Western Ontario, Department of Economics).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Masson, Paul R., 1996, “Fiscal Dimensions of EMU,” Economic Journal: The Journal of the Royal Economic Society, Vol. 106 (July), pp. 996 –1004.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • ———, and Michael Mussa, 1995, “Long-Term Tendencies in Budget Deficits and Debt,” IMF Working Paper 95/128 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Masson, Paul R., and Steven Symansky, 1992, “Evaluating the EMS and EMU Using Stochastic Simulations: Some Issues,” Macroeconomic Policy Coordination in Europe: The ERM and Monetary Union, ed. by Ray Barrell and John Whitley (London: SAGE Publications Ltd).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • McDermott, John C., and Robert F. Wescott, 1996, “An Empirical Analysis of Fiscal Adjustments,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 43 (December), pp. 725 –53.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • McKinnon, Ronald I., 1996, “Monetary Regimes, Government Borrowing Constraints, and Market-Preserving Federalism: Implications for EMU,” paper presented at the conference, “The Nation State in a Global/Information Era: Policy Changes,” (Queen‘s University, Kingston, Ontario,: November 13 –15 (unpublished).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Millar, Jonathan 1997, “The Effects of Budget Rules on Fiscal Performance and Macroeconomic Stabilization,” Bank of Canada Working Paper: 97 –15 (June).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Musgrave, Richard A., and Peggy B. Musgrave, 1989, Public Finance in Theory and Practice (United States: McGraw-Hill, Inc., 5th ed).

  • Mussa, Michael, 1994, “Monetary Policy: U.S. Monetary Policy in the 1980s,” American Economic Policy in the 1980s, ed. by Martin Feldstein (Chicago: University of Chicago Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • New Zealand Treasury, 1995, Fiscal Responsibility Act of 1994: An Explanation (Wellington: Adprint Ltd., September).

  • Oort, C.J., and G. de Man, 1968, “De ‘Zijlstra-norm‘ in Theorie en Praktijk,” Reprint from Economisch Kwartaaloverzicht, Nos. 12 and 13 (Amsterdam: Amsterdam-Rotterdam Bank NV).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, 1995, Economic Outlook, No. 57 (Paris: OECD June).

  • Persson, Torsten, and Guido Enrico Tabellini, 1990, Macroeconomic Policy, Credibility and Politics (Chur, Switzerland: Harwood Academic Publishers).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Phelps, Edmund S., 1961, “The Golden Rule of Accumulation: A Fable for Growthmen,” American Economic Review, Vol. 51 (September), pp. 638 –41.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Reischauer, Robert D., 1997, “The Unfulfillable Promise: Cutting Nondefense Discretionary Spending,” Setting National Priorities: Budget Choices for the Next Century, ed. by Robert D. Reischauer (Washington: Brookings Institution Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Roseveare, Deborah, Willi Leibfritz, Douglas Fore, and Eckhard Wurzel, 1996, “Ageing Populations, Pension Systems and Government Budgets: Simulations for 20 OECD Countries,” Economics Department Working Paper No. 168 (Paris: Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Suits, Daniel B., and Ronald C. Fisher, 1985, “A Balanced Budget Constitutional Amendment: Economic Complexities and Uncertainties,” National Tax Journal, Vol. 38 (December), pp. 467 –77

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Sutherland, Alan, 1995, “Fiscal Crises and Aggregate Demand: Can High Public Debt Reverse the Effects of Fiscal Policy?” CEPR Discussion Paper No. 1246 (London: Centre for Economic Policy Research September).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Switzerland, Federal Council, 1995, “Rapport destiné Ȥ l‘envoie en consultation concernant un frein à l‘endettement” (Bern, October).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Tanzi, Vito, 1989, “International Coordination of Fiscal Policies: Current and Future Issues,” Fiscal Policy, Economic Adjustment, and Financial Markets, ed. by Mario Monti (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • ———, 1994, “The Political Economy of Fiscal Deficit Reduction,” Public Sector Deficits and Macroeconomic Performance, ed. by Williauthor Russell Easterly, Carlos Alfredo Rodríguez, and Klaus Schmidt-Hebbel (New York: Oxford University Press for the World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • ———, Fanizza Domenico 1995, “Fiscal Deficit and Public Debt in Industrial Countries, 1970–1994,” IMF Working Paper 95/49 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Tanzi, Vito, and Ludger Schuknecht, 1995, “The Growth of Government and Reform of the State in Industrial Countries,” IMF Working Paper 95/130 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Taylor, John B., 1993, “Discretion Versus Policy Rules in Practice” Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, Vol. 38/39 C.4 (Amsterdam: North Holland), pp. 195 –214.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Teijeiro, Mario, 1996, La Polȷtica Fiscal Durante la Convertibilidad, 1991–95 (Buenos Aires: Centro de Estudios Pɐblicos July).

  • Ter-Minassian, Teresa, 1996, “Borrowing by Subnational Governments: Issues and Selected International Experiences,” IMF Paper on Policy Analysis and Assessment 96/4 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • United States, 1995, Economic Report of the President: Transmitted to the Congress, February 1995 (Washington: Government Printing Office).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • U.S. General Accounting Office, 1989, “Social Security: The Trust Fund Reserve Accumulation, the Economy, and the Federal Budget,” Report to the Chairman, Subcommittee on Social Security and Family Policy, U.S. Senate Committee on Finance (Washington: General Accounting Office, January).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • von Hagen, JŨrgen, and Ian J. Harden, 1994, “National Budget Processes and Fiscal Performance,” European Economy, Reports and Studies: Towards Greater Fiscal Discipline (Brussels: European Commission, Directorate-General for Economic and Financial Affairs No. 3), pp. 311 –418

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • ———, 1996, “Budget Processes and Commitment to Fiscal Discipline,” IMF Working Paper 96/78 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Wellink, A.H.E.M., 1996, “Budgetary Control: Good-hart‘s Law in Government Finances?” Essays on Money, Banking, and Regulation: Essays in Honour of C.J. Oort, ed. by Clemens Kool, Joan Muysken, and Tom van Veen (Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Publishers

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Zalm, G., 1997, “Economic Science and Fiscal Policy,” Economic Science: Art or Asset? The Case of the Netherlands, ed. by Peter A.G. van Bergeijk, A. Lans Bovenberg, Eric E.C. van Damme, and Jarig van Sinderen (Rotterdam: Research Centre for Economic Policy).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation