9 Moderate Inflation in Poland: A Real Story
Author:
Mr. Thierry Pujol https://isni.org/isni/0000000404811396 International Monetary Fund

Search for other papers by Mr. Thierry Pujol in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close

Abstract

Inflation in Poland has proved resilient. Since stabilizing the economy in 1991-92, policymakers have found it difficult to tame inflation and to bring it back to single-digit levels. Hyperinflation was overcome, but since then inflation has remained stuck at moderate levels. Of particular interest is the fact that a marked slowdown of the currency depreciation, which began in 1994, at first contributed little. Only in 1995, after a series of step appreciations and a more favorable harvest that lowered food prices did inflation start to fall significantly.

Inflation in Poland has proved resilient. Since stabilizing the economy in 1991-92, policymakers have found it difficult to tame inflation and to bring it back to single-digit levels. Hyperinflation was overcome, but since then inflation has remained stuck at moderate levels. Of particular interest is the fact that a marked slowdown of the currency depreciation, which began in 1994, at first contributed little. Only in 1995, after a series of step appreciations and a more favorable harvest that lowered food prices did inflation start to fall significantly.

What explains this resilience of inflation? In a sense, this is the same question Dornbusch and Fischer (1993) asked for other countries: why is it that the switch from moderate to low inflation is almost always slow or costly?

A first answer is that Poland was not willing to bear the high cost of this adjustment. The former finance minister, Grzegorz Kolodko, expressed this view succinctly a few years ago: “It seems that curbing the inflation rate to about 2 percent monthly (i.e., 27 percent yearly) while keeping up the trend to form market-clearing prices is sufficient at this phase of inflation fighting. Because otherwise, e.g., if a goal of the order of 1 percent monthly is laid down, the policy must be much more restrictive, thus sustaining the recessionary trends in the real economy sphere and threatening it with further destruction” (Kolodko, Gotz-Kozierkiewicz, and Skrzeszewska-Paczek, 1992, p. 111). This assessment raises the issue of why the cost of reducing inflation in terms of lost output (the “sacrifice ratio”) is unusually high when inflation is moderate.

The general thrust of the analysis of this paper, which focuses on Poland’s experience through 1995, is that persistent inflation was both caused by and reflects imbalances in the real economy. The main arguments are as follows.

First, a salient feature of Polish inflation is that it has been accompanied by marked changes in relative prices. In particular, utility and rental price inflation has vastly exceeded overall inflation as measured by the consumer price index (CPI), The explanation for this is fairly intuitive: to improve profitability, these sectors, and loss-making firms in general, need to change their relative prices if they are to remain in business. In addition, prices in many sectors had to move closer to international levels.

Second, in a well-indexed economy, the effects of frequent sectoral price hikes will be magnified. A wage-price model of the Polish economy (see below) shows that after four years the initial inflationary impact of a CPI shock is quadrupled, even if the exchange rate remains constant. In a sense, this validates Kolodko’s assertion: to combat inflation, sectoral inflationary pressure combined with high indexation would require very tight monetary policy.

Third, certain underlying structural problems, in particular in the labor market, undermine the efficiency of monetary and fiscal policies. Chief among them is the fact that some loss-making firms were not faced with hard budget constraints. The threat of job losses gives large established firms political power against the imposition of such constraints. In addition, the sizable debts such firms have already accumulated makes default a powerful threat against banks. In this context, a policy of high real interest rates and exchange rate appreciation would place the brunt of adjustment on Poland’s emerging private sector. In short, tight monetary policy is not a substitute for structural reforms.

Sectoral Aspects of Polish Inflation

Price liberalization was a key element of reform programs in transition economies. Hence, there was an outburst of inflation at the inception of the transition, also fueled by a monetary overhang. But, as the primary goal of this liberalization was to restore prices as a means for allocating resources in the economy, it is important to analyze how relative prices have evolved.

A Brief History of Inflation in Poland, 1989-94

Figure 1 illustrates the precipitous increase in inflation in Poland in 1989.1 By October 1989, CPI inflation had reached 55 percent a month, and, in early 1990, Poland was on the verge of hyperinflation (for the year, inflation averaged 585.8 percent). The stabilization program brought inflation down, but was accompanied by an unexpectedly high drop in output (see Ebrill and others, 1994). That period also witnessed marked changes in the terms of trade and in real wages.

Figure 1.
Figure 1.

Poland: Wage and Price Inflation

Sources: Polish authorities; and IMF staff estimates.

During these chaotic developments on the macroeconomic front, movements in the overall CPI masked considerable divergences in relative prices. Past repressed inflation in the service sector suddenly materialized through a marked increase in relative prices. In particular, the drift in the price of services persisted in 1992, even though overall price inflation was tamed (see Figure 2). By 1993, however, it seemed that the bulk of relative price adjustment among food, services, and manufactured goods had already taken place.

Figure 2.
Figure 2.

Poland: Components of Consumer Price Inflation

Sources: Polish authorities; and IMF staff estimates.

Relative price adjustment was, however, not over. At a more disaggregated level, relative price changes remain substantial although less visible. For instance, between January 1992 and May 1995, the relative cost of water tripled. Rental prices have also largely exceeded average inflation. Substantial relative price adjustment can therefore take place not only in the atmosphere of hyperinflation and stabilization, but also during spells of moderate inflation.

The causality between these relative price changes and inflation remains open to question. On the one hand, at low levels of inflation, even small changes in relative prices may have a large proportionate effect on inflation. On the other hand, annual inflation in the range of, say, 20-40 percent can also create large relative price shifts if certain prices are sticky.

The remainder of this section fleshes out the argument linking relative prices to inflation. Following Ball and Mankiw (1995), it is shown that there is a relationship between inflation and the skewness of the distribution of sectoral price changes and that the latter helps explain inflation. This skewness of the distribution can be seen as a proxy for relative price changes, suggesting that they are linked to inflation. To the extent that there is a need for further relative price adjustment—as prices catch up to international levels or as utility prices are increased to recover costs—this suggests a source of future inflationary pressure in Poland.

Relative Price Adjustment, Asymmetric Price Adjustment, and Inflation in Poland

In recent years, economists have paid renewed attention to relative price adjustments. This interest has been fueled by consistent statistical evidence that these adjustments are asymmetric (prices are more flexible upward than downward) and that relative price adjustments are correlated with the level of inflation. Fischer (1981) stressed, for instance, that U.S. inflation is highly correlated with a higher variance of sectoral price inflation. Similarly, Gerhaeusser (1988) found instantaneous Granger-causality between inflation and relative price volatility in Germany.2

The empirical relationship between relative price changes and inflation has until recently been regarded as an analytical puzzle. Indeed, at first glance, there need be no relationship between relative price changes and the overall price level (for example, if money determines the overall level of prices). According to this view, price increases in certain sectors would be offset by price decreases in others, leaving the overall price level in the hands of monetary policy. Of course, if prices were sticky downward, relative price changes could occur only in an inflationary context. But downward price adjustment is difficult to justify on theoretical grounds (unless adjustment costs are, for some reason, asymmetric). A solution to this puzzle must therefore be based on different grounds.

Such a solution has recently been proposed by Ball and Mankiw (1995), who argue that price stickiness (both upward and downward) arising from “menu costs” can cause higher inflation if the distribution of relative price changes is skewed.3 Their argument runs as follows.

In the presence of menu costs, firms will change their prices only if the costs of inaction exceed the menu costs associated with changing prices. Accordingly, small shocks to the economy will have little effect on the price level, because individual firms will be reluctant to change prices. Large shocks will have a disproportionate effect on individual prices—but not necessarily on the aggregate price level: if the distribution of shocks is symmetric, price increases and decreases at the firm level cancel each other out. Thus, greater variance of shocks need not lead to overall price inflation.

Rather, Ball and Mankiw’s approach can justify a relationship between the skewness of price changes and overall inflation. In a skewed distribution, most outliers are on one side of the distribution. Suppose that the distribution of relative price shocks is skewed positive (that is, there is a small number of large positive price shocks, offset by a large number of small negative price shocks). In the presence of menu costs, the large number of firms with small negative price shocks leave their prices unchanged, while firms with large price shocks increase their prices, raising the average price level. Conversely, if the distribution of price shocks is skewed negative, the overall price level will fall.

Empirical analysis of price dispersion in Poland during 1990-94 yields the following results. First, the distribution of price changes is heavily skewed, and not only during the first months of the transition. On average, once every two months there is some change in price more than two standard deviations away from the mean price increase. This fat-tailed distribution of price changes primarily reflects sizable price increases, largely concentrated in particular sectors (for example, utilities). Thus, there is considerable evidence of relative price adjustment within overall price level changes.

Second, monthly inflation (ΔCPI) is highly correlated with the standard deviation (SD) and skewness (SK) of the distribution of sectoral price changes that month.4

ΔCPI=0.20(2.4)ΔCPI(1)+0.67(7.1)SD+1.29(3.3)SK+77.5.(1)

R2=0.59 DW=1.67

Sample period: December 1989–June 1995

Number of observations: 66

This result suggests that relative price shocks are closely linked to aggregate inflation.

However, causation is uncertain. Just as menu costs can explain why relative price increases can cause inflation, they can also explain why trend inflation owing to other causes can lead, in any given period, to a positively skewed distribution of price changes (Ball and Mankiw, 1994). First, in the presence of menu costs and trend inflation, those sectors facing relative price declines can simply avoid paying the menu cost, keep nominal prices unchanged, and allow overall inflation to generate the desired erosion in relative prices. In contrast, those sectors needing to establish relative price increases must increase prices over and above the inflation rate. With no change in certain sectors and increases in others, the result is a positively skewed distribution of price changes. Second, menu costs may differ across sectors. For example, assume that average long-term inflation does not differ between sectors. Sectors with small menu costs will change prices continuously, but those with large menu costs will change prices infrequently—but by large amounts when they do. The result is apparent skewness in the distribution of price changes, without implication for the long-term inflation rate.

The question is whether skewness causes inflation, or whether inflation causes skewness. In the first interpretation, skewness and relative price movements are part of the inflation process; in the second, they are simply an epiphenomenon. If the relative price explanation is correct, one should observe in the same sectors skewed price increases and a lasting improvement in their relative prices. If the second explanation is correct, the skewed price increases should be essentially random, without any lasting effect. To distinguish between these explanations, the change in a sector’s relative price (RCPIi) between December 1989 and June 1995 was regressed against the number of times that sector registered a skewed price increase (NSKi):

ΔRCIi=0.211(4.48)NSKi+0.94(2.03)R2=0.39.(2)

This cross-section regression indicates a strong correlation between a sector’s ability to generate a sustained increase in relative prices and the number of times its price changes are outliers. This is consistent with the claim that skewness captures lasting relative price changes and that these relative price changes were a key cause of Polish inflation.

Price Adjustment in a Well-Indexed Economy

The previous section documented the role that relative price adjustment has played in the Polish inflation story. This section estimates the extent to which Polish inflation has become increasingly inertial, reflecting the widespread move toward indexation. The two elements—relative price adjustment and inertial inflation—are then put together to consider the likely inflationary consequences of future relative price adjustment.

The Dynamics of Wages, Prices, and the Exchange Rate

To gauge the extent of wage and price indexation, we estimated a standard markup model of the Polish economy. Given that the estimation period is restricted to March 1991-May 1995,5 simple dynamic specifications were favored. This exercise sheds some light on the nature of the interplay among prices, wages, and the exchange rate, as well as of the lags involved.

Structure of the Model

For the producer price index (PPI), the following markup pricing is assumed:

PPI=(1+μ)[PICIC+WLY]α.(3)

Thus, producer prices are a markup on unit variable costs, defined as the sum of wage costs (WL) and the costs of intermediate inputs (PICIC), divided by output (Y).

Output affects prices through at least two distinct channels. The first is through the effect on marginal cost. Unless the production function has constant returns to scale, average and marginal productivity differ. For example, with increasing returns to scale and holding factor prices constant, marginal cost will decline as output increases. The second is through the effect on the markup. Some authors have argued that, in industrial economies, price competition fades somewhat during growth spurts. Therefore, the markup μ of prices on costs is a function of capacity utilization, simply proxied here by changes in output.

The impact of the exchange rate (exr) on producer prices is also twofold. First, it directly affects the cost of imported intermediate inputs. Second, foreign competition may also influence the markup of domestic firms: when the currency appreciates, margins shrink in those sectors most exposed to foreign competition. Overall, a reduced-form equivalent of equation (3) can be expressed as

log(PPI)=a1log(W)+a2log(exr)+a3log(Y)+a4.(4)

The CPI equation is largely an accounting identity. Most models simply assume that the CPI is a weighted average of producer price indices and import prices. This CPI equation also incorporates wages. This could be justified on the following grounds. First, consumer goods are often more labor intensive than typical industrial goods. Hence, simply using an aggregate PPI would underestimate the influence of wages. Second, wages also represent an important variable cost for retailers. Thus, for consumer prices, the following equation is assumed:

log(CPI)=b1log(PPI)+b2log(exr)+b3log(W)+b4.(5)

For the labor market, a standard relationship between unemployment and real wages is assumed:

log(Wn)=log(CPI)c1log(UR)+c2,(6)

where UR represents the unemployment rate, and wages are considered net of tax.6

To capture the dynamics associated with high-frequency data, these equations were all estimated in an error-correction form. This involves estimating, first, a long-term (cointegrating) relationship between the various variables and, second, a short-term dynamic equation that determines the speed of adjustment toward the long-term target. Econometric results are reported in Table 1.7

Table 1.

Poland: Wage and Price Equations

article image
Note’. All variables in logarithms. Δ denotes first difference. Error-correction terms ecmw-1, ecmp-1, and ecmc-1; are, respectively, the lagged residuals from the long-run wage, producer price, and consumer price equations of the previous table. Series names: Iwnr = real wage (deflated by consumer price index); lur = unemployment rate; Ippi = producer price index; lip = industrial production; lcu = unit labor costs; lexr= exchange rate; Icpi = consumer price index; and Iwg = gross wages.

A Highly Indexed Economy

Poland is a well-indexed economy and therefore prone to relatively high inflation. Such findings are not unexpected after a hyperinflation spell (see Commander and Coricelli, 1991). However, certain aspects of the econometric results deserve specific comment.

First, wages are much more indexed than prices. After a consumer price shock, the mean lag of wage adjustment amounts to about two months. Hence, an inflationary shock to the CPI or wages is likely to reduce enterprises’ markups rather than real wages. This result may seem counterfactual given that, at the beginning of the transition, average real wages declined strongly. However, there are various ways to reconcile these two facts. For one, Polish households may have learned from the hyperinflation period how to protect themselves against price changes. Also, in addition to the precipitous decline in productivity, the initial real wage decline was facilitated by centralized negotiations, quite independently of any inflationary surprise.8

Second, the producers’ markup reacts rapidly to changes in output and is negatively affected by sudden changes in costs. The first feature may partly explain the growth of the PPI in early 1995 given the brisk pace of output growth. The magnitude of the effect of output on prices is, however, surprising. It may have resulted from a shortage of capital in industry during the recovery of output since 1991 and, subsequently, higher margins accompanying the boost in demand. As expected, exchange rate appreciation compresses producers’ margins. However, such an impact on inflation materializes only with a mean lag of seven to eight months. The pass-through from unit labor cost is somewhat more rapid.

Third, CPI inflation is driven mainly by wages and the domestic PPI. Possible explanations for the strong direct impact of wages on the CPI have already been mentioned. The main surprise is the relatively weak role of the exchange rate: the direct impact appears relatively small, and the mean lag is three to four months. A more disaggregated analysis shows the exchange rate’s impact is statistically significant only for manufactured consumption goods, but not for foodstuffs or services.

A casual inspection of the structure of Polish imports provides an explanation for such findings (Table 2). Before the transition, imports of consumer goods were constrained to fairly low levels in Poland, as in other Eastern European countries. Since then, a strong appetite for Western products combined with a more liberal trade policy has boosted imports of consumer goods. Their share in total imports has more than doubled since 1988 to reach approximately 20 percent.9 As such, since imports and consumption represent, respectively, 25 percent and 70 percent of GDP in 1994, an appreciation of the currency by 10 percent mechanically reduces the CPI only by 0.7 percent.10 This result is in line with our econometric estimates. Overall, the stronger impact of the exchange rate on the PPI than on the CPI mainly reflects the large share of intermediate inputs in total imports (Table 2).

Table 2.

Structure of Polish Imports, 1994

article image
Source: Polish Statistical Office.

It would be utterly misleading, however, to infer from this that the exchange rate is useless in controlling inflation. Indeed, the weak initial impact from the exchange rate on both CPI and PPI is magnified by the high indexation in the economy. To illustrate this point, this model was simulated in two different ways. The first simulation simply consists of a 10 percent devaluation. Consumer prices increase by 2.5 percent after one year and by about 6 percent after three years. In the second simulation, it is assumed that, after the initial shock, the exchange rate is depreciated in line with inflation to offset the loss of competitiveness. This would amount to adding to the previous three equations the following one:

Δlog(exr)=d1Δlog(CPI),(7)

which represents an accommodating policy reaction function. With this addition to the model and, by setting d1 equal to 0.5, assuming only a partly accommodating exchange rate policy, the inflationary effect of the devaluation is severely compounded and exceeds 10 percent. Thus, despite its slow impact, the exchange rate is key as an anchor.

Finally, the wage-price model was used to gauge the inflationary impact of energy price adjustments, to illustrate the interaction among relative price changes, indexation, and inflation. Consider the effect of a 60 percent increase in utility prices—at the lower end of the range that Freund and Wallich (1995) consider necessary for Poland. At first glance, the immediate impact on the CPI would be approximately 6 percent, given the share of energy in the consumption basket. This effect would be stronger if one were to take into consideration the effects of utility price increases on the prices of other public services (for example, transportation) and on household rents.

In the well-indexed Polish economy captured in our wage-price model, any such energy price shock would also induce a considerable multiplier effect. With fixed exchange rates, such a shock would increase the overall level of prices by approximately 20 percent after a four-year period. Additional exchange rate depreciation would compound the inflationary impact. With a partly accommodating exchange rate rule (d1= 0.5), consumer prices would increase by 40 percent after 4 years and by 70 percent after 10 years.11

This exercise in itself need not imply that inflation should be high if energy prices are liberalized, or if there are other market relative price increases. Indeed, one could argue that a tighter monetary policy would keep overall inflation subdued. What is important, however, is that such an outcome would hinge on a severe price adjustment in other sectors. In the face of nominal price rigidity, changes in relative prices can be achieved only through higher inflation.

Monetary Policy, Delayed Restructuring, and Inflation

Inflation is a monetary phenomenon, and there is little doubt that tighter monetary policy will ultimately bring inflation down. The interesting question is, at what cost would such a policy have succeeded in reducing Polish inflation more rapidly?

First, we attempt to gauge whether lax monetary policy has contributed to inflation, or whether monetary policy has accommodated inflationary shocks. We find statistical evidence linking financial variables, including money supply, to inflation. However, the results are quite sensitive to the sample period, and there is also evidence of reverse causality from inflation to monetary growth, suggesting that monetary policy has often accommodated inflationary shocks.

Second, the effectiveness of monetary policy is discussed in the Polish context. We model the effects of monetary policy in a dual economy consisting of a market-oriented sector and an inefficient nontradables sector. We argue that, in such a model, to succeed in reducing inflation, tighter monetary policy must act with disproportionate effect on the restructured traded goods sector—leaving the unreformed sector largely intact. After presenting arguments for and against monetary tightening to reduce inflation in such a second-best world, we conclude that—at least for the inefficient nontradables sector—structural reform should be part of any stabilization program aimed at sustained inflation reduction.

Statistical Evidence on Money and Inflation

During 1991-95, inflation and broad money growth were closely related (Figure 3). The relationship was clearest for annual growth rates, where both broad money growth and inflation declined. The relationship was much less discernible for monthly growth rates. However, even for annual growth rates, it is difficult to ascertain whether monetary growth leads or lags the inflation rate. Finally, over this period, broad money growth, on average, exceeded measured CPI inflation. The result is a sizable trend increase in real money balances. This remonetization is not surprising given the decline in Poland’s inflation rate.

Figure 3.
Figure 3.

Poland: Money Growth and Inflation, June 1991–December 1995

Source: Polish authorities.

The data suggest some relationship between money growth and inflation, but cannot pronounce on its statistical significance. Also, it is difficult to judge the direction of causality: is money leading inflation or lagging inflation? To answer these questions, econometric Granger-causality tests of the relationship between inflation and money were conducted. Strictly speaking, these are simply tests for predictive content, which may only hint at “true” causality and may instead be more useful for finding leading indicators.

Ideally, such tests would be employed on long data series to increase degrees of freedom. But for Poland as a transition economy, there are barely five years of observations. To increase our degrees of freedom, we used monthly data. However, monthly inflation is extremely volatile, reflecting the effects of one-off shocks (such as changes in administered prices) or seasonal factors, and is thus difficult to predict. Adding monthly dummy variables should help capture seasonal patterns insofar as they are regular, but will not incorporate the effects of irregular shocks.

One way around this data problem is to test whether money growth helps predict inflation not for 1 month, but on average over 6 or 12 months. Annual and 6-month inflation rates are far less volatile than monthly rates. Their coefficient of variation is far lower than that for monthly inflation (Table 3). For Western economies, a time lag of 18 months to 2 years between money growth and inflation would be thought commonplace. Indeed, predicting inflation only 6 or 12 months ahead might also be too short, save that inflation in transition economies is much higher and, presumably, the frequency of price changes that much greater, and so the transmission to inflation is that much more rapid.

Table 3.

Consumer Price Inflation, Basic Descriptive Statistics

(January 1990-September 1995)

article image

Table 4 presents the results of causality tests linking financial variables to inflation. The table is divided into four sections, concerned with predicting inflation 12, 6, 3, and 1 month ahead, respectively. In each section, four rows summarize the results of regressing future inflation on past inflation (DLCPI, past inflation and broad money growth (DLFMB), past inflation and changes in the deposit interest rate (DRD), and past inflation, broad money growth, and changes in the deposit rate together.12 Save for interest rates, all variables are in logarithms, so that the first differences measure growth rates.

Table 4.

Predictive Content of Broad Money and Interest Rates in Explaining Inflation

article image
article image
Note: Six lags of the explanatory variable are included.

The results suggest that broad money has considerable predictive power for future inflation. First, consider a simple autoregression of inflation on lagged monthly inflation rates (row 1). Lagged monthly inflation explains only about one-third of the variance of inflation over the next 12 months; the standard deviation of the forecast error is approximately 7 percentage points. Adding lagged broad money growth improves predictive power (row 2). F-tests show statistical significance at even the 0.1 percent level, and the doubling of R2 and the near-halving of the standard error show that money has considerable explanatory power in economic terms. Results predicting inflation one, three, and six months ahead were broadly similar.

However, proponents of alternative theories of inflation might accept that money growth leads to inflation, but would want to go one step further and inquire what caused the money growth. Specifically, they would argue that money growth often accommodated inflationary impulses, such as the attempts of certain sectors to increase their relative prices or of workers to raise their relative wages, to prevent a possible recession.

To test for this possibility, additional causality tests were conducted, this time from lagged inflation to future money growth.13 Except when forecasting money growth one month ahead, lagged inflation proved statistically significant in explaining future broad money growth.

Thus, in general, the results are open to interpretation. There is evidence that financial factors, including money, growth, are linked to future inflation consistent with conventional monetary explanations. At the same time, there is evidence linking inflation to future money growth, consistent with less orthodox and more structural explanations of inflation, or with a monetary policy reaction function that seeks to offset the output costs of adverse supply shocks.

Inflation and Monetary Policy in a Restructuring Economy

So far, three potential sources of entrenched inflation in Poland have been isolated: a drift of certain relative prices, de facto indexation of wages, and some evidence of an accommodating monetary policy. In this section, it is argued that the nature of Polish firms’ restructuring process may be an ultimate underlying cause. Indeed, certain firms have restructured largely through attrition, accompanied by gradual output contraction and accumulated losses. It is argued that, because of this slow restructuring, firms are likely to increase their relative prices or to run deficits. As a result, they are less responsive to traditional macropolicy instruments. Therefore, to the extent that such firms represent a sizable proportion of output, we show that a “hard-currency” strategy to reduce inflation may be unexpectedly costly.14

The move to a market economy was accompanied by a relative price shock of unprecedented magnitude. This shock created a fault line between two groups of firms: those that benefited from it and those for which it proved detrimental.15 In the face of this shock, restructuring in the sectors adversely affected can be expected to follow one of three paths: (1) cutting wages to restore profitability; (2) boosting productivity by shedding labor or, in certain (rare) instances, by investing in new equipment; or (3) a “wait-and-see” approach, where firms merely shrink through attrition. In this situation, they run losses and possibly increase their prices. In a sense, (3) is a slower version of (2), leading to a depletion of the firms’ assets through accumulated losses. The wait-and-see approach seems to capture certain traits of the restructuring process in some sectors of the Polish economy. Indeed, Pujol (1996) showed that, during the early transition years, Polish firms tended to adjust employment levels rather than change relative wages. Employment has fallen most in the loss-making sectors, but did not lead to profitability. He argues that, during this period, the hard budget constraint was not always sufficiently binding to force firms into needed adjustments.

However, it is important to bear in mind two things. First, this characterization only applies to sectors in need of restructuring and that have delayed it. Privatized or newly created firms have been less prone to procrastination and, in certain cases, have made giant strides toward Western productivity standards. In essence, the transition created a dual economy.16 Second, a pure wait-and-see approach is unlikely given that no firm is totally immune from restructuring pressure. As we discuss below, firms are better sheltered if they can secure additional financing (for example, from rolling over loans, tax arrears, or inter enterprise credits). What the above description emphasizes, however, is that the process is relatively slow because managers try to shelter workers from painful wage adjustment or labor shedding. A similar point is made by Berg and Blanchard (1994).

The coal mining sector provides an interesting illustration of this behavior. First, the coal industry has restructured, as evidenced by sizable productivity gains (Table 5). These gains have certainly exceeded what a pure wait-and-see approach would have delivered and have contributed to the improvement in the sector’s profitability. However, despite substantial losses, coal miners have improved their relative wages, which still stand strikingly above the average for industry as a whole. In other words, a large fraction of productivity gains have been erased by additional wage costs. These developments have three main implications. First, the price of Polish coal has increased despite a 15 percent decline in international prices between 1991 and 1994. Second, the sector’s assets have been severely eroded, threatening its long-term viability. Third, the completion of restructuring has been delayed. A recent report issued by the Polish Ministry of Mining now considers that restructuring may take another five years and involve the loss of another 90,000 jobs.17

Table 5.

Restructuring in the Coal Industry

article image
Source: Polish Statistical Office, Biuletyn Statystyczny, various issues. Note: “Employment” is defined as the change in average employment over the year. The coverage of the series changes in 1992. “Relative wage” is the ratio of gross wages in the coal sector to average gross wages in industry. “Relative price index” represents the change in the relative price of sold production. “Profitability” is the ratio of net losses to total income. “Assets-liabilities” is the ratio of short-term assets to short-term liabilities.

How relevant is this example? One may argue that the mining industry is an extreme case, reflecting largely the historical and political clout of miners in Polish society. In a sense, this is precisely the lesson drawn from this example: for whatever reasons, certain sectors have successfully circumvented the hard budget constraint. And, because these sectors represented a substantial fraction of industrial employment before the transition (approximately 12 percent for the coal mining sector), they are more than a statistical curiosity. Indeed, various studies have documented insiders’ resistance to painful restructuring. Aghion, Blanchard, and Burgess (1994) have modeled how certain groups can impose the status quo to avoid mass layoffs. Pujol (1996) also documents various rigidities in the labor market and the lack of reaction of relative wages to the financial situation of firms.

At a macroeconomic level, the slow adjustment to the new post-transition conditions is also well illustrated by the financial results of Polish enterprises. Polish firms restructured between 1992 and 1994, as evidenced by the recovery in profitability (Table 6). However, during this period, the proportion of loss-making firms, as well as their losses as a percentage of total income, remained sizable, consistent with the view that some firms adjusted by slowly reducing activity rather than by raising profitability.18 For the economy as a whole, losses have dwindled partly because some firms are profitable again, but also because loss-making firms have shrunk.

Table 6.

Financial Results of Polish Enterprises

(in percent)

article image
Source: Polish Statistical Office, Biuietyn Statystyczny, various issues.

In percent of total income.

What are the macroeconomic implications of sizable loss-making sectors undergoing only (relatively) slow transformation? To answer that fundamental question, we present a model in which relative price adjustment plays a key role. Such a model is somewhat unrealistic, but nonetheless useful: it provides a way to synthesize certain stylized facts concerning the transition.19 Its main conclusion is that the sector undergoing restructuring will gradually increase its relative prices as it reduces output and labor hoarding, adding to medium-term inflationary pressures. True, if the slowly restructuring sector faces a high price elasticity of demand, achieving such a relative price increase is unlikely, and the inflationary pressure is correspondingly lower. However, in these circumstances, the slowly restructuring sector will incur higher losses for a longer time. For given money supply growth, the credits that the slowly restructuring sector will require to stay afloat will unduly crowd out lending to the expanding sector, prolonging the restructuring process. If these credits remain in place, the burden of tighter monetary policy to reduce inflation will then fall disproportionately on the expanding sector.

Starting with the model, we assume that the economy comprises two distinct groups of firms, say, distressed (sector 1) and profitable (sector 2).20 In sector 1, activity dwindles at a pace determined by the rate of attrition of the labor force. This rate of attrition includes an exogenous factor (say, retirement) and an endogenous one, linked to employment growth in sector 2. The intuition between such a linkage is as follows. Growing employment in the emerging sector is the main source of job creation. Therefore, separations from distressed firms are facilitated by an important pool of job creation. Conversely, quits tend to occur during a period of intense job destruction. As a result, during the transition in Poland, job-to-job movements have become increasingly important as a way to avoid unemployment spells (see Coricelli, Hagemejer, and Rybinski, 1995). Also, for certain occupational groups, intense job creation has led to shortages and, in turn, to higher wages to lure workers away from sector 1. This equation may therefore capture this wage competition between the two sectors.

Consider supply. In sector 1, at any instant, employment is assumed to determine output:

Y1,t=F1(L1,t)withΔL1,t=δL1,tβΔL2,t.(8)

This implies that output in sector 1 is exogenous and does not respond to wage or price changes. However, employment declines by proportion Δ through natural attrition and by proportion β as labor demand increases in sector 2. For simplicity, it is assumed that this latter effect is minor (β ≈ 0). As employment in sector 1 declines, so does output.

In the profitable second sector, output is given by equating the real wage, w/P2, to the marginal product of labor:

F2(L2,t)=wP2.(9)

It is further assumed that nominal wages are given, so that increased prices of goods in sector 2 lower the real product wage and increase employment and output in sector 2.21 In contrast, employment in sector 1 is assumed to be excessive, so that the real wage always exceeds the marginal product of labor. In addition, it is assumed that labor shedding has only a limited impact on output. One measure of progress toward restructuring is the extent to which the marginal product of labor and the real wage in sector 1 can be brought closer together.22 With fixed nominal wages, progress can be achieved only by reducing employment or by increasing output prices.

The demand side of the model is standard and simply assumes a certain substitution of domestic demand for goods in the two sectors depending upon their prices (see Blanchard and Kiyotaki, 1987). It is assumed that the output of sector 1 is consumed entirely at home, whereas the output of sector 2 is both exported and consumed domestically. The share of domestic consumption of goods 1 and 2 as a proportion of domestic income depends on the relative price of the two goods:

P1C1=g(q)IncomeP2C2=h(q)Income(10)

where q = P2 / P1 Income = ΣPiYi,

and where g(.) and h(.) are, respectively, increasing and decreasing functions of q: if the relative price of good 2 increases, consumption of good 1 increases and consumption of good 2 declines. The sum of g(.) and h(.) is constant and is less than unity. Equivalently, households save a constant share of their nominal income.23

It is assumed that the foreign demand for exports of the profitable firms of sector 2 declines as the ratio of the domestic producer price to the exchange rate increases:24

X=X(P2¯e).(11)

To determine equilibrium, we equate supply with demand in the two goods markets:25

Y¯1=C1(P2+P1,P2e)(sector1)(12)

and

Y2+(P2)=C2(P2P1,P2e)+X2(P2e)(sector2).(13)

The underlying mechanisms for the impact of prices on output can be summarized briefly. Demand for good 1 increases with a higher relative price of good 2, through a substitution effect; it is reduced by higher prices in sector 2 relative to the exchange rate because exports, and hence household income, diminish (income effect). Conversely, in sector 2, higher prices of good 2 relative to good 1 reduce domestic consumption, and higher prices relative to foreign prices reduce export demand; in addition, the marginal product of labor conditions determines total supply. Figure 4 depicts these two equilibrium loci.

Figure 4.
Figure 4.

Poland: Equilibrium in a Two-Sector Model

As time goes by, exogenous labor shedding lowers the supply of good 1. Barring any change in households’ demand, producers in this sector will gradually increase their relative price, restoring profitability but at the expense of a lower domestic market share. Conversely, sector 2 is faced with growing demand. Its firms react by increasing their prices slowly, leading to an increase in supply as well as a reduction in exports.26

Overall, this setup provides a potential explanation for the gradual increase in the relative price of sector 1 during the transition. As sector 1 contracts, supply falls and the relative price of good 1 increases. As sector 2 grows, income increases, raising the demand for and relative price of good 1. This relative price shift is facilitated if the elasticity of substitution between goods 1 and 2 is low.

One may draw the following parallel. Some authors have argued that inflation is required in transition economies to eliminate the initial monetary overhang. In our setup, labor hoarding in sector 1 plays a similar role. As labor is dishoarded, output in sector 1 declines, and its relative price increases. However, the size of the relative price increase will depend on the size of the price elasticity of demand. Whether or not it leads to inflation will depend on the extent of monetary accommodation.

In this setting, a hard-currency option will deliver lower domestic prices only at a substantial real cost. Real appreciation combined with imperfectly indexed wages entails lower output growth in sector 2 and, subsequently, in the economy as a whole. Moreover, owing to subdued demand, firms in sector 1 have to postpone their relative price increase, and their profitability deteriorates. As a corollary, the end of the restructuring—when the marginal product and real wage equate in sector 1—is postponed. The greater the spillover from growth in sector 2 to declining employment in sector 1, the stronger this conclusion is. Note, however, that if sector 2 Is already at capacity, enjoying the benefits of an undervalued exchange rate and buoyant foreign demand, more pressure may be needed to promote genuine restructuring. In these circumstances, real appreciation is still appropriate.

Serious caveats apply. As presented, the model is well equipped only to describe the impact of slow restructuring when competition, possibly through foreign imports, is weak. This could well be the case in the energy sector, in nontradables, or where protection is strong. But there are other possibilities. First, in sectors where the price elasticity of demand is high or in sectors exposed to foreign competition, a marked relative price increase is not a viable option. Various segments of Polish industry seem to be in this alternative situation (for example, shipyards and tractors). Second, certain sectors may be producing goods that no one wants. In such a case, there will be no trend increase in relative prices, and there will be no demand spillover from growth in sector 2. Ultimately, there is no alternative to closure. In both of these two possibilities, firms must seek outside financing to cover their losses. In the next section, it is argued that financing losses in these sectors may render the conduct of monetary policy more difficult, hence indirectly hampering the fight against inflation.

Loss-making firms have mainly relied on three different sources of external financing: short-term loans, the accumulation of tax arrears, and interenterprise credits. A World Bank survey (Belka and others, 1995) indicated that, in state-owned firms, the payment of taxes and social security obligations had a much higher priority than obligations to banks or other firms. However, these authors also found that severely distressed firms tended to share the burden more equally between creditors; ultimately, they ended up accumulating substantial debt against the government. As a result, in addition to additional stress on the fiscal front, the Polish banking industry acquired many problem loans, with the potential for crowding out “good” borrowers.

Poorly performing loans have made up a substantial fraction of Polish banks’ assets. Moreover, these loans were highly concentrated in approximately 10 percent of Polish firms (Gomulka, 1994). Baer and Gray (1995) offer an interesting account of how Polish banks handled these nonperforming borrowers. Overall, banks seem to have had only limited leverage to push these firms into restructuring. For instance, these authors mention that only 50 percent of nonperforming borrowers in December 1991 had signed conciliation agreements with banks by April 1994 to avoid lengthy legal procedures. An even smaller fraction, 19 percent, had resumed debt service. As a result, banks are less likely to force companies into bankruptcy, because they come far down in priority as creditors (after employees and liabilities related to social security). Therefore, to keep themselves and the distressed sector afloat, banks will tend to roll over past loans.27

Therefore, an immediate, undesirable outcome of slow restructuring is that it increases the exposure of the banking system to nonperforming loans.28 Against this background, how might banks rebalance their portfolios or alter their lending rates? They could charge higher premiums to distressed firms. Such a move, however, will be largely cosmetic if the book value of these loans is already low. Instead, banks may pursue a quite different strategy to reduce the risk of their portfolio while increasing their margins. It involves increasing their holdings of government paper to reduce their overall credit-risk exposure,29 and reducing loans or increasing the premiums charged to sector 2 firms.

An additional perverse feature of this behavior is readily apparent. Good enterprises, in particular startup firms, may be those most penalized. This crowding-out effect, and the ensuing higher interest rates, hampers capital accumulation in the emerging sector.

Other factors may well undermine the effectiveness of monetary policy. One may think that this undue premium cannot be imposed indefinitely upon good borrowers. Indeed, given that the premium charged to these firms is justified not by the borrowers’ credit risk, but instead by the situation of lenders, other sources of financing may become available. The crowding out could be circumvented, in particular, through the formation of new financial intermediaries, through borrowing abroad, or through long-term capital inflows. If crowding out is circumvented, the problem in the banking sector will rematerialize as a capital-inflow problem. Of course, this could be offset by a steep appreciation of the currency to make zloty-denominated investments riskier, but such a move would again exacerbate the pressure imposed on restructuring firms.

Against this background, a tight monetary policy or a hard-currency option may prove costlier than in more standard conditions. The underlying cause is that they are both rather indiscriminate instruments. As a result, whatever the transmission channel (competitiveness effect or financial crowding out), most of the burden of appreciation is shouldered by the “wrong” sector. Indeed, instead of fostering a more intense restructuring in sector 1 along with a desirable reallocation of resources into sector 2, it simply slows down the emergence of the latter.30

How can these costs of tighter monetary policy be avoided? The message is that tighter monetary policy, be it in the form of exchange rate appreciation or reduced money supply growth, cannot be a substitute for restructuring. Indeed, if it unduly forces the burden of adjustment onto the emerging private sector, tighter monetary policy, unaccompanied by structural reform, might actually delay the restructuring on which future growth will depend. The first-best solution is to extend the discipline of hard budget constraints to all sectors of the economy, to promote restructuring, and to ensure that the burdens of tighter monetary policy are borne proportionately.

Conclusion

This paper offers an alternative explanation of the difficulties of reducing inflation in Poland that may be relevant to other economies in transition: the need for relative price adjustment. Specifically, for the price mechanism to replace central planning as the means of resource allocation, significant relative price adjustment is required. In centrally planned economies, divergences between supply and demand were not eliminated by relative price adjustment. As a result, the structure of prices (and wages) in these economies was vastly different from its Western counterpart. Therefore, relative price changes are pivotal during the move toward a market economy and will affect the allocation of resources and the sizes of the different sectors of the economy. Profits rise in those sectors in which relative prices increase, and output increases as a result. Where relative prices decrease, output will tend to contract. This is how restructuring takes place.

This paper argues that this process of relative price adjustment has contributed to high inflation. This argument is not novel and has been applied to many types of economies. It dates back to at least the 1920s, in the arguments of Graham and Mills, and has been investigated comprehensively by Fischer (1981) after the oil price shock. Most recently, the relationship has been revisited by Ball and Mankiw (1995), this time as evidence in support of the implications of theories of price adjustment based on menu costs. We think that this argument may be of particular relevance to transition economies.

This paper’s contribution has been to document the role that relative price adjustment has played in Poland, both during hyperinflation and in the more moderate inflation that followed. This initial pressure has also been magnified by high indexation. Combined with nominal rigidities, relative price adjustment in a relatively small number of sectors can help generate moderate inflation.

Because inflation is a monetary phenomenon, relative price adjustment cannot be the sole explanation of Poland’s persistent inflation. At best, it explains why money growth has been allowed to increase. This paper also represents an attempt to explain the hurdles facing monetary policy, suggesting that tight monetary policy (through either exchange rate appreciation or lower money supply growth) cannot be a substitute for restructuring. Indeed, without active restructuring, the burden of tight monetary policy is placed on the emerging private sector. Likewise, appreciating the exchange rate places the burden of adjustment on the traded goods sector. Tighter monetary policy is most effective when all firms face hard budget constraints.

What are the policy implications? In our view, the first-best strategy for reducing inflation is to speed up the restructuring process through some combination of tighter monetary policy and active restructuring. Restructuring does not imply the need for centralized industrial policies and strategies: rather, it can be achieved at the microlevel through the imposition of hard budget constraints. Inevitably, this restructuring will entail lower relative wages and employment in loss-making sectors. However, the combination of tighter monetary policy and active restructuring has the potential to reduce inflation in the least costly and most lasting way.

References

  • Aghion, Philippe, Olivier Jean Blanchard, and Robin Burgess, 1994, “The Behavior of State Firms in Eastern Europe: Pre-privatization,” European Economic Review, Vol. 38 (June), pp. 132961.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Baer, Herbert L., and Cheryl W. Gray, 1995, “Debt as a Control Device in Transitional Economies: The Experience of Hungary and Poland,” Policy Research Working Paper No. 1480 (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ball, Laurence, and N. Gregory Mankiw, 1994, “Asymmetric Price Adjustment and Economic Fluctuations,” Economic journal, Vol. 104 (March), pp. 24761.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ball, Laurence, and N. Gregory Mankiw, 1995, “Relative-Price Changes as Aggregate Supply Shocks,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 110 (February), pp. 16293.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Belka, Marek, Mark Schaffer, Saul Estrin, and Inderjit Singh, 1995, “Enterprise Adjustment in Poland: Evidence from a Survey of 200 Private, Privatized, and State-Owned Firms,” Discussion Paper No. 233 (London: London School of Economics and Political Science, Centre for Economic Performance).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Berg, Andrew, and Olivier Jean Blanchard, 1994, “Stabilization and Transition: Poland, 1990-91,” in The Transition in Eastern Europe, Vol. 1, Country Studies, ed. by O. Blanchard, K. Froot, and J. Sachs (Chicago: University of Chicago Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Blanchard, Olivier Jean, and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki, 1987, “Monopolistic Competition and the Effects of Aggregate Demand,” American Economic Review, Vol. 77 (September), pp. 64766.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bonin, John, and Mark Schaffer, 1995, “Banks, Firms, Bad Debts, and Bankruptcy in Hungary: 1991-1994,” Discussion Paper No. 234 (London: London School of Economics and Political Science, Centre for Economic Performance).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Commander, Simon, and Fabrizio Coricelli, 1991, “Price-Wage Dynamics and the Transmission of Inflation in Socialist Economies: Empirical Models for Hungary and Poland,” Policy, Research, and External Affairs Working Paper No. 613 (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Coricelli, Fabrizio, Krzysztof Hagemejer, and Krzysztof Rybinski, 1995, “Poland,” in Unemployment, Restructuring and the Labor Market in Eastern Europe and Russia, ed. by S. Commander and F. Coricelli (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • De Masi, Paula, and Vincent Koen, 1995, “Relative Price Convergence in Russia,” IMF Working Paper 95/54 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dornbusch, Rudiger, and Stanley Fischer, 1993, “Moderate Inflation,” World Bank Economic Review, Vol. 7 (January), pp. 144.

  • Ebrill, Liam P., Ajai Chopra, Charalambos Christofides, Paul Mylonas, Inci Otker, and Gerd Schwartz, 1994, Poland: The Path to a Market Economy, IMF Occasional Paper No. 113 (Washington: International Monetary-Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fischer, Stanley, 1981, “Relative Shocks, Relative Price Variability and Inflation,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: 2, Brookings Institution, pp. 381441.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Freund, Caroline L., and Christine I. Wallich, 1995, “Raising Household Energy Prices in Poland: Who Gains? Who Loses?” Policy Research Working Paper No. 1495 (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gacs, Janos, 1994, “Trade Policy in the Czech and Slovak Republics: Hungary and Poland in 1989-1993, a Comparison,” Studies & Analyses No. 11 (Warsaw, Poland: Center for Economic and Social Research).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gerhaeusser, Klaus, 1988, “Price Dispersion and Inflation: A Test of Causality,” Applied Economics, Vol. 20 (May), pp. 70109.

  • Gomulka, Stanislaw, 1994, “The Financial Situation of Enterprises and Its Impact on Monetary and Fiscal Policies: Poland, 1992-1993,” Economics of Transition, European Bank for Reconstruction and Development, Vol. 2 (June), pp. 189208.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kolodko, Grzegorz W., Danuta Gotz-Kozierkiewicz, and Elzbieta Skrzeszewska-Paczek, 1992, Hyperinflation and Stabilization in Postsocialist Economies (Boston, Massachusetts: Kluwer Academic Publishers).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lach, Saul, and Daniel Tsiddon, 1992, “The Behavior of Prices and Inflation: An Empirical Analysis of Disaggregated Price Data,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 100 (April), pp. 34989.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • National Bank of Poland, 1995, “Sources of Inflationary Threats” (unpublished; Warsaw).

  • Pujol, Thierry, 1996, ‘The Role of Labor Market Rigidities During the Transition: Lessons from Poland,” IMF Working Paper 96/77 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Reinsdorf, Marshall, 1994, “New Evidence on the Relation between Inflation and Price Dispersion,” American Economic Review, Vol. 84 (June), pp. 72031.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Rotemberg, Julio, 1987, ‘The New Keynesian Microfoundations,” NBER Macroeconomics Annual, ed. by S. Fischer (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Schaffer, Mark, 1993, “The Enterprise Sector and Emergence of the Polish Fiscal Crisis, 1990-91,” Policy Research Working Paper No. 1195 (Washington: World Bank).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation

Note: We would like to thank, without implication, Gérard Bélanger, Carlo Cottarelli, Michael Deppler, Juha Kähkönen, Vincent Koert, Markus Rodlauer, and Robert Sirhej for their comments and encouragement; and Patricia Emerson, Indra Perera, and David Maxwell for their assistance. An expanded version of this paper was first issued as IMF Working Paper 96/57.

1

A more detailed analysis of Poland’s inflation history can be found in National Bank of Poland (1995).

2

Lach and Tsiddon (1992) present similar results for the Israeli hyperinflation; however, Reinsdorf (1994) argues for a negative correlation between price dispersion and inflation. See De Masi and Koen (1995) for an analysis of relative price adjustment in Russia’s transition.

3

Menu costs here are shorthand for all of the costs associated with changing prices, from the physical costs of reprinting menus to the costs of lost sales from reduced customer satisfaction (Rotemberg, 1987). An interesting issue is whether these menu costs are similar in high- and low-inflation economies.

4

As in most econometric equations in this paper, (-statistics are reported in parentheses; DW refers to the Durbin-Watson statistic. In the calculations, monthly inflation series for 35 consumer price basket items were seasonally adjusted by regressing on monthly dummies, and then weighted squared and cubed deviations from the mean inflation rate were used to calculate the standard deviation and skewness of the distribution of price changes. Results were somewhat sensitive to the sample period used; including a dummy for the January 1990 price liberalization or confining the sample to the period of more moderate inflation tended to increase the statistical significance of skewness and lessen the statistical significance of the standard deviation term. Lagrange multiplier tests rejected the presence of serial correlations.

5

It is usually accepted that, before the transition, inflation was artificially repressed in Poland, as evidenced by rationing and the significant role of the parallel (black) market. Thus, it would not make sense to use data prior to 1990. In addition, significant behavioral changes accompanying the Polish hyperinflation rule out using 1990 data.

6

In the simulations that follow, the tax wedge is held constant.

7

The short sample prohibits any serious attempt to test for cointegration; it also makes our estimates fragile and subject to small-sample bias. By the same token, the short period did not allow the inclusion of long-term error-correction mechanisms in certain equations (for example, productivity in the wage equation).

8

Growing unemployment is the usual explanation offered for the real wage decline in Poland, but the correlation between the tax ratio on wages and unemployment perhaps suggests an alternative interpretation. As unemployment crept up, the financing of existing government spending (including social outlays) required higher taxes and social security contributions. Either willingly, or because of myopic wage negotiation, wage earners have borne part of the resulting burden. Hence the negative correlation between unemployment and net wages.

9

See Gacs (1994) for a description. Note also that this increasing trend makes our econometric estimates potentially unstable. A time-varying coefficient, however, is a luxury our small sample does not allow.

10

Assuming that importers do not alter their margins.

11

By ignoring the indirect effects of energy price increases on production costs, these estimates probably err on the low side. However, to some extent, this effect should be mitigated by a more efficient use of energy.

12

The deposit rate is chosen as the interest rate measure because more observations are available.

13

To save space, the results are unreported, but are available on request.

14

The simple model presented in this section supports these conclusions, but, of course, there are many alternative models. The most difficult question is to what extent the model in the text provides a relevant description of the Polish economy. The lack of microeconomic data concerning how firms restructure makes this question particularly difficult to answer.

15

The price shock may happen under different guises—for example, a slash in governmental subsidies.

16

Because of this dual nature of transitional economies, average data (for example, on wage costs or productivity) can be misleading.

17

Reuter, December 4, 1995, citing a report in Gazeta Wyborcza.

18

As shown by Schaffer (1993), data on profitability between 1989 and 1991 are considerably affected by the changes in inflation. Indeed, Polish accounting methods based upon historical costs generate lower profits when inflation recedes. The 1991-94 period is less exposed to this bias.

19

By the same token, by delineating which factors impinge upon inflation, it could suggest certain avenues for empirical research, to test its empirical relevance.

20

As discussed later, this is a drastic simplification. By assumption, we assert that the pace of restructuring in sector 1 is exogenous, impervious to the impact of financial or exchange rate policy. We also neglect the possibility that there is really a continuum of sectors, with all firms having the possibility of graduating from unreformed to fully restructured, perhaps encouraged in this process by tighter financial policy. These important topics await further research.

21

Given the econometric findings on wage indexation, this assumption may seem counterintuitive. In fact, this assumption simply captures the fact that when the exchange rate depreciates, wages and CPI are less affected than producer prices. Hence, there is a reduction in wage cost.

22

Although this takes the level of capital stock as given when, in reality, we would expect significant reallocation of capital as part of the transition. We would also need to ensure that the marginal product of capital equaled the real rate of interest. However, the real wage condition is at least a first attempt to measure the degree of successful restructuring in the short run.

23

One could derive such demand functions from a nested Cobb-Douglas-cum-constant-elasticity-of-substitution utility function.

24

The exchange rate (e) is defined as the domestic price of foreign currency; an increase in e represents a depreciation. Implicitly, we are holding the foreign price of good 2 constant, or using it as numeraire.

25

The labor market does not clear because of excess labor supply combined with wage rigidity.

26

The supply-side effect is possibly magnified by exogenous productivity gains in sector 2. If these gains materialize—and, it seems they do currently in Poland—one may observe in fact a growth in exports. Productivity gains in sector 2 must be sizable enough to generate growth in sector 2 and offset the contractionary impact of labor shedding in sector 1.

27

A similar point is made for Hungary by Bonin and Schaffer (1995).

28

An alternative solution for these distressed firms is to obtain additional nonbank financing, most frequently through tax or social security contributions arrears or inter-enterprise credits. To the extent that these means are available, hard budget constraints are more difficult to enforce.

29

The percentage of government and central bank securities amounted to 13 percent of the commercial banks’ balance sheet in December 1991 and to more than 20 percent in May 1995.

30

Again, this conclusion needs to be qualified if the export sector is already growing too rapidly and reaching capacity constraints, when tighter policy would be helpful. Also, it reflects our assertion that the sheltered sector 1 can wholly resist the effects of tighter economic policy, which may not be true in practice.

  • Collapse
  • Expand
The Experience of Transition Economies: The Experience of Transition Economies