10 Challenges Confronting Regulation and Supervision
Author:
Mr. Matthew I. Saal https://isni.org/isni/0000000404811396 International Monetary Fund

Search for other papers by Mr. Matthew I. Saal in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
,
Mr. Carl-Johan Lindgren
Search for other papers by Mr. Carl-Johan Lindgren in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
, and
Ms. G. G. Garcia https://isni.org/isni/0000000404811396 International Monetary Fund

Search for other papers by Ms. G. G. Garcia in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close

Abstract

The design and implementation of regulatory and supervisory policies for banks present a number of challenges, including the need to carefully direct policy toward legitimate and achievable objectives and the potential for conflicts of interest at a number of levels. All too often legislators, regulators, or supervisors fail to meet these challenges adequately. For example, politicians may be tempted to use the banking system to achieve social objectives they are unwilling to fund overtly in the budget, but which may prejudice bank soundness. Poorly designed incentive structures may encourage bank supervisors to pursue career interests that detract from bank soundness. Furthermore, bank regulations frequently have a macroeconomic impact. The authorities may legitimately phase in significant escalations of regulations to moderate their impact and give banks time to adjust to the new environment. It is not appropriate, however, to adjust prudential regulations in an attempt to use them as macroeconomic policy instruments.

The design and implementation of regulatory and supervisory policies for banks present a number of challenges, including the need to carefully direct policy toward legitimate and achievable objectives and the potential for conflicts of interest at a number of levels. All too often legislators, regulators, or supervisors fail to meet these challenges adequately. For example, politicians may be tempted to use the banking system to achieve social objectives they are unwilling to fund overtly in the budget, but which may prejudice bank soundness. Poorly designed incentive structures may encourage bank supervisors to pursue career interests that detract from bank soundness. Furthermore, bank regulations frequently have a macroeconomic impact. The authorities may legitimately phase in significant escalations of regulations to moderate their impact and give banks time to adjust to the new environment. It is not appropriate, however, to adjust prudential regulations in an attempt to use them as macroeconomic policy instruments.

Regulatory Failure

Regulations may fail by being too lax, too intrusive, poorly designed, or inadequately implemented. Regulatory failure in some form was a factor in all of the countries in our sample, with the possible exception of Kuwait (see Table 16). Where regulations are insufficiently strict or comprehensive, the solution is clear. Correcting a situation of regulatory capture, which occurs when regulators or legislators are allied with banking interests, is likely to be difficult, but here too the prescription is clear. On the other hand, banking regulations may also be too intrusive, raising the cost of compliance and reducing bank efficiency and the scope for innovation.

Table 16.

Deficiencies in Regulation and Supervision1

article image
article image
article image
article image

Years in parentheses denote the period of banking problems.

Bank behavior is often dictated by regulations that are more quasi-fiscal than prudential. For example, laws in some countries require banks to extend loans that would otherwise not be extended, by designating priority sectors or mandating “community reinvestment” requirements.92 Liquid asset ratios and similar portfolio regulations may require banks to lend to the government or other entities that issue eligible assets, often at below-market yields. Sectoral lending priorities or creating a particular type of banking system (e.g., a system composed of small local banks) is usually politically dictated, with the intent of achieving some social objectives. Interest rate controls may also be imposed in pursuit of certain resource allocation goals. These objectives may be achieved, but often at the expense of distorted prices, impeded market development, and increased bank fragility. Government development and social welfare policies are better handled transparently through budgetary allocations rather than by imposing regulations that could impair bank soundness.

The pursuit of economic efficiency along with banking system stability requires careful review of regulatory and supervisory policies to see that they are in line with the environment and enhance, rather than reduce, bank soundness and market discipline.93 The international trend toward deregulation and financial liberalization reflects the experience that macroeconomic and allocative controls on bank behavior tend to be ineffective and inefficient.94 However, microeconomic efficiency (and private profit) may at times usefully be traded for stability (and public benefit) through prudential or consumer protection regulation; such stability enhances overall market efficiency. At the same time, these regulations should not remove the market’s incentive to monitor bank behavior, by creating excessive deposit guarantees or by interfering so strongly in banking activities that the public infers an implicit government backing for the banks. Similarly, regulations must not shelter banks from healthy competition or from the market for corporate control. For example, Prowse (1995) presents evidence that the effectiveness of board intervention and of hostile takeovers as disciplinary mechanisms was reduced for U.S. banks relative to manufacturing companies and attributes this in part to banking regulation.

In many jurisdictions, different parts of domestic financial conglomerates are supervised by different authorities. Which institutions and activities are subject to banking laws needs to be carefully defined, so that the possibility for regulatory arbitrage among domestic regulators of banks and other financial institutions is limited.

Supervisory Failure

Supervisory failure usually takes the form of forbearance—an adjustment in the interpretation of rules to accommodate problem banks or failure to act in a timely manner to prevent or address unsound banking. This can occur for a number of reasons. Supervisors may not have the ability to act independently, because of inadequate organizational structure or direct political interference. Where the political will to enforce regulations and supervisory standards is missing, supervision is unlikely to succeed in keeping the banking system sound. Some form of supervisory failure was a factor in almost all of the sample countries (Table 16).

Supervisors in some countries develop longstanding relationships with the banks they oversee. Such supervisors are subject to regulatory capture, a process in which the supervisor identifies more closely with the banking industry than with the public interest, and may see his role as protecting rather than disciplining, the banking industry.95

Because the public often perceives the supervisor’s only role as preventing bank failures rather than as ensuring the exit of weak banks so as to maintain systemic soundness, supervisors may be reluctant to close banks.

Supervisory accountability may be lacking, particularly when supervision is part of a bureaucracy in which responsibility for taking tough decisions is not clearly allocated. In addition, political interference may prevent intervention in a bank.

A common reaction to the emergence of banking distress is for the authorities to adopt a “wait-and-see” attitude, hoping that the difficulties are temporary, that no serious threat to the financial system is posed, and that any problems will either resolve themselves or remain submerged until after someone else takes office. This can occur where supervisory systems are not sufficiently independent or are underfunded and lack qualified staff; consequently, authorities are wary of taking potentially controversial decisions. Forbearance, delay, or cover-up may be abetted by ambiguous assignment of responsibility and a lack of accountability. It can also occur in well-developed systems where authorities have become more concerned about their reputation for overseeing a system with no visible difficulties than about resolving banking problems. Deposit insurance may further exacerbate the problem by removing pressure from depositors as a potential spur to action.96

Delay in addressing unsound banks is rarely effective and usually detrimental. Unsound banks continue to operate, weakening initially sound competitors and increasing the likelihood of systemic difficulties. Furthermore, unsound banks tend to take on even more risk or may be looted by insiders, which ultimately increases resolution costs.

Supervisory failure may also result in weakened effectiveness of regulation. Supervisors, sometimes under political pressure, may try to keep a banking system afloat by lowering capital standards, by allowing continued unfettered operation with less-than-adequate capital, or by permitting increased risk exposure. This in turn may delay corrective actions until after a bank has become insolvent. Despite this, supervisors in several countries have relaxed or failed to strengthen valuation and accounting standards when banks were weak, ostensibly to give the banks time to grow out of their problems. For example, U.S. regulators adopted accounting standards that disguised insolvency during the savings and loan debacle (United States, General Accounting Office, 1985). Accounting procedures obscured the true condition of Japanese banks and thrifts; corrective measures were first promised by the Bankers’ Association, rather than the supervisors (“Japan,” November 1995). In these and other cases, delay exacerbated unsoundness.

Systems in which supervisors either do not promulgate regulations independently or enforce those regulations unfailingly often result in the continued operation of weak, undercapitalized banks. Banking laws can be written, however, so as to limit the possibility of supervisory failure. The law should be flexible enough to allow the supervisors to apply successively more stringent corrective measures, while being firm enough to limit supervisory forbearance. It should also protect supervisors acting professionally, and limit lawsuits or other actions against them. Rules governing prompt corrective actions to be taken against banks that are not complying with the laws and regulations should be established in the law. Even with such provisions in place, there are limits to what regulation and supervision can accomplish.

Market participants will always be changing and innovating, and testing the limits of legality and prudence. Regulators and supervisors will almost always be a few steps behind, trying to adapt rules and supervisory procedures to the latest financial products and developments in financial markets. Innovation and capital market liberalization have made it easier for banks to circumvent existing regulations on net foreign exchange positions and leverage. Liberalization also makes it possible for banks to blind supervisors to their risk taking by engaging in complex offshore activities especially when conducted through derivative instruments. For example, Mexican banks’ use of structured notes and other offshore transactions to weaken the impact of domestic financial regulations is often cited as a factor contributing to the pressure on the peso in late 1994.

In general, supervisors will not be able to anticipate sufficiently to out-engineer the financial engineers. At the same time, other market participants will often have insights that supervisors lack. Supervision and regulation must therefore work alongside, and encourage, dynamic market and internal forces. Thus prudential regulation and supervision should be viewed as just one part of a comprehensive system of guidance and incentives influencing bank behavior; the system must also include market discipline and strong internal governance.

Macroeconomic Effects of Prudential Regulations

As explained earlier, bank activities affect macroeconomic conditions, particularly in the monetary area. Prudential policies and regulations that delimit bank activities will therefore have macroeconomic implications. Much of the concern in this area has been over strengthening capital requirements, which, it has been argued, could reduce bank lending and slow economic growth. Other prudential regulations, however, may also have a macroeconomic impact. This does not represent a form of regulatory or supervisory failure and does not argue for suspension of such regulations. The macroeconomic impact of prudential policies can be anticipated, and implementation of such policies can be adjusted accordingly.

Capital Standards

A frequently cited example of the influence of prudential policies on monetary and macroeconomic conditions is the impact of the 1988 Basle capital standards on credit conditions in the major industrial countries. There was a slowdown in credit growth in a number of countries during 1988-91, which appears to have lengthened or worsened cyclical downturns. It is likely the case that this slowdown, referred to as a “credit crunch,” was in part the result of the increase in capital that banks were required to hold against assets. Banks apparently responded to the new capital requirements by reducing the volume of credit extended or by increasing their interest margins to build up own capital.

It is difficult to fully substantiate whether capital constraints contributed to the credit slowdown, however, since the demand and supply schedules for loans are not directly observable.97 While the contribution of capital adequacy requirements to the U.S. credit crunch of 1988-91 cannot be isolated,98 some studies have found evidence that growth in lending by U.S. banks that were constrained by the new capital standards was slower than the growth of lending by better capitalized banks.99 On the other hand, the Bank of England concluded that the U.K. credit slowdown resulted from decreased borrowing capacity and banks’ concern to tighten standards and improve profitability, rather than from problems in meeting the international capital adequacy standard.100 Japanese banks widened their margins and adopted a more restrictive lending stance from 1988 to 1991, but observers differ as to whether or not wider bank margins reduced the macroeconomic impact of looser monetary policy, and whether the reduction in credit was due to a capital constraint or was mainly demand driven.101 Thus the evidence is mixed, but there is some theoretical and empirical support for a capital-induced credit crunch.

Capital adequacy requirements can affect credit expansion in two distinct ways: they compel banks to build up sufficient capital at the time when ratios are initially imposed, and they compel banks to reduce risk assets when the capital constraint becomes binding. To some extent, these rules reinforce what should occur naturally. Banks should maintain adequate capitalization to support the risks they assume. A credit crunch surrounding a rise in capital requirements should be transitory, and may reflect other distortions (such as a real estate bubble) that have resulted in overextension that is difficult to reverse to meet a higher capital-to-asset ratio. If default rates rise in an economic downturn, capital will be reduced. Total assets will also decline as loans are written off, but the loss in asset-carrying capacity will be greater owing to the leveraging of bank capital—if a loan of 100 is written off, minimum required capital would decline by 8 but actual capital would decline by the full 100.

The effects of an economic downturn on bank assets will result in reduced capital due to loan write-offs. Thus the effects of minimum capital ratios tend to be procyclical, binding during recessions and asset price depressions;102 however, capital adequacy ratios will also dampen volatility in the longer term. Thus, discussion of the effects of the Basle Capital Accord needs also to take into account the timing of implementation. Had stricter capital standards been applied in the early 1980s, a larger capital cushion would have been available to absorb losses later in the decade, and capital might not have become a binding constraint on credit growth.103

Other Prudential Instruments

Concern for macroeconomic effects extends also to other regulatory and prudential instruments, including liquidity, interest exposure, foreign exchange exposure, loan limits, and other prudential standards. These may constrain banks’ asset allocation, resulting in higher costs or reduced income, and increasing interest rate spreads. For example, a number of historical periods of tight money in the United States have been linked to regulatory action, in particular to actions regulating interest rates.104 If prudential regulations require banks to hold more liquid assets, and these yield less than other assets the bank might have chosen, the reduced income will be reflected in wider spreads.105 Loan-loss provisioning will similarly increase bank expenses and contribute to wider spreads.

Excessively stringent regulations may be cause for concern. However, to the extent that prudential regulations merely force a recognition of the true costs of doing business safely, the higher price paid by borrowers and the lower yield to depositors do not mean that regulation has created additional costs for banks. Rather, wider interest rate spreads reflect a shifting of costs from the deposit insurer or lender of last resort and to the consumers of banking services.

Regulations may have spillover effects on other financial instruments. Prudential rules on liquidity management by commercial banks typically also affect the demand for, and yield of, liquid assets such as treasury bills and commercial paper. In addition to the possible impact of systemwide regulations on bank lending and interest rates, actions taken to limit the activities of certain banks may also have an impact. For example, supervisory intervention to limit deposit acquisition by weak banks may remove a source of upward interest rate pressure and reduce credit growth. The actual effects of prudential regulations will ultimately depend on the particular circumstances of the banking system and the economy as a whole.

Cyclical Adjustment of Prudential Regulations

Prudential policies should be devoted to creating a framework for sound banks rather than diverted to cyclical demand management. Therefore, prudential requirements should not be viewed as an additional monetary policy tool. While regulations could potentially be adjusted over time to produce procyclical or countercyclical effects on the economy, such an approach to prudential regulation is likely to introduce conflicts of interest within the central bank and weaken the banking system in the long run. For example, expansionary policy could be reinforced by reducing capital requirements.106 This policy tool, however, could be difficult to reverse, with the result that over time the banking system could tend toward lower levels of capital and greater risk of insolvency.

It has been argued that in some circumstances prudential regulations could weaken the effectiveness of monetary policy instruments. For example, a stimulatory monetary policy may be less effective when capital adequacy regulations constrain bank credit expansion, since the central bank can control access to, or the cost of, borrowed funds, but does not control the supply of bank capital.107 While that is true, there are many aspects of credit creation that the central bank cannot control, such as the supply of bankable projects and the credit-screening process. Central banks normally do not seek to control these aspects of credit creation, since it is not desirable to expand the supply of questionable credit.

Arguments against maintaining strict prudential standards on monetary management grounds focus excessively on short-term considerations. The central bank should not seek to expand the supply of credit based on an insecure capital foundation. During periods of economic stress, banks should be encouraged not only to maintain the minimum level of capital, but to build up additional capital if possible, for example, by refraining from paying dividends. In the medium to long term, there is no inconsistency in striving for effective monetary control, strong banks, and sound prudential policies. In fact, an effective system of prudential regulations that fosters a sound banking system will increase the flexibility and effectiveness of monetary policy instruments, which should enhance monetary control in a reasonably stable economy.

Transitional Arrangements in Raising Prudential Standards

Understanding the potential short-run effects of raising prudential standards leads to a policy approach that recognizes that any changes in prudential regulations should be phased to take account of the capacity of the banking system to adjust and of broader macroeconomic trends. An increase or decrease in capital adequacy ratios can leave the banking system starved of or flush with capital. Either could cause problems, depending on current and prospective macroeconomic conditions. For this reason, the Basle Capital Accord was phased in over a period of four years. Similarly, the introduction of new or higher liquidity, interest exposure, loan limits, and other prudential standards needs to be undertaken with due regard for the short-term effects on the banking system and the monetary stance. Prudential policies should be tightened gradually. Any forbearance that may be required must be monitored and phased out under an enforceable compliance timetable.

  • Collapse
  • Expand
  • Akhtar, M.A., “Causes and Consequences of the 1989-92 Credit Slowdown: Overview and Perspective,” Quarterly Review, Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Vol. 18 (Winter 1993-94), pp. 1 –23.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Alexander, William E., Tomás José T. Baliño and Charles Enoch, eds., The Adoption of Indirect Instruments of Monetary Policy, IMF Occasional Paper, No. 526 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1995).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Alexander, William E., and Francesco Caramazza, “Money Versus Credit: The Role of Banks in the Monetary Transmission Process,” in Frameworks for Monetary Stability, ed. by Tomas J. T. Baliño and Carlo Cottarelli (Washington: International Monetary Fund,1994), pp. 397 —422.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Allen, Linda, and Anthony Saunders, “Forbearance and Valuation of Deposit Insurance as a Callable Put,” Journal of Banking and Finance, Vol. 17 (June 1993), pp. 629 –43.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • American Institute of Certified Public Accountants, The Relationship Between Bank Supervisors and External Auditors (New York, July 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Aoki, Masahiko, and Hugh Patrick, eds., The Japanese Main Bank System: Its Relevance for Developing and Transforming Economies (Oxford, New York: Oxford University Press, 1994).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Baer, Herbert, and Daniela Klingebiel, “Systemic Risk When Depositors Bear Losses: Five Case Studies,” in Banking, Financial Markets, and Systemic Risk, Vol. 7 of Research in Financial Services Private and Public Policy, ed. by George G. Kaufman (Greenwich, Connecticut: JAI Press, 1995), pp. 195 –302.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bank for International Settlements, Report of the Committee on Interbank Netting Schemes of the Central Banks of the Group of Ten Countries (Basle, November 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bank for International Settlements, Delivery Versus Payment in Securities Settlement Systems (Basle, September 1992).

  • Bank for International Settlements, Central Bank Payment and Settlement Services “with Respect to Cross-Border and Multi-Currency Transactions (Basle, September 1993).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bank for International Settlements, Report of the Steering Group on Settlement Risk in Foreign Exchange Transactions (Basle, December 1996).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bank of England, “Is There a Credit Crunch?” Quarterly Bulletin, Bank of England, Vol. 31 (May 1991), pp. 256 –59.

  • Bank of Japan, “Characteristics of Interest Rate Indicators,” Quarterly Bulletin, Bank of Japan, Vol. 2 (November 1994), pp. 35 –62.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Barker, David, and David Holdsworth, “The Causes of Bank Failures in the 1980s,” Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Research Paper No. 93-25, August 1993.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Basle Committee on Banking Supervision, Report on the Supervision of Banks’ Foreign Establishments (Basle: Bank for International Settlements, September 1975).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Basle Committee on Banking Supervision, “Principles for the Supervision of Banks’ Foreign Establishments” (Basle: Bank for International Settlements, May 1983).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Basle Committee on Banking Supervision, Report on International Developments in Banking Supervision, No. 9 (Basle: Bank for International Settlements, September 1994).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Basle Committee on Banking Supervision, “Communique” (Basle: Bank for International Settlements, December 1995).

  • Basle Committee on Banking Supervision, “Amendment to the Capital Accord to Incorporate Market Risks” (Basle: Bank for International Settlements, January 1996).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Beany, Anne, Sandra L. Chamberlain, and Joseph Magliola, “Managing Financial Reports of Commercial Banks: The Influence of Taxes, Regulatory Capital and Earnings,” The Wharton Financial Institutions Center, Paper No. 94-02, August 1993.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Benston, George J., “Federal Regulation of Banking: Historical Overview,” in Deregulating Financial Services: Public Policy in Flux, ed. by George G. Kaufman and Roger C. Kormendi (Cambridge, Massachusetts: Ballinger Publishing Company, 1986), pp. 1 –48.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Berg, Jesper, “The Nordic Bank Crisis—Lessons to Be Learned” (unpublished, Washington: July 1995).

  • Berglöf, Erik, “Corporate Governance in Transition Economies: The Theory and Its Policy Implications,” in Corporate Governance in Transitional Economies: Insider Control and the Role of Banks, ed. by Masahiko Aoki and Hyung-Ki Kim (Washington: The World Bank, 1995), pp. 59 –95.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Blum, Jürg, and Martin Hellwig, “The Macroeconomic Implications of Capital Adequacy Requirements for Banks,” European Economic Review, Vol. 39 (1995), pp. 739 –49.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bockelmann, Horst, “Comments [on Goodhart],” in Financial Stability in a Changing Environment, ed. by Kuniho Sawamoto Zenta Nakajima, and Hiroo Taguchi (New York: St. Martin’s Press, 1995), pp. 498 –505.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bonin, John P., Banking in the Transition: Privatizing Banks in Hungary, Poland, and Czech Republic, issue paper for Institute for East West Studies, Comparative Privatization Project, State Withdrawal: Creating Market-Oriented Banking Sectors for the Economies in Transition (London, European Bank for Reconstruction and Development, December 4—5, 1995).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Borish, Michael S., Millard Long, and Michel Noël, Restructuring Banks and Enterprises, World Bank Discussion Paper, No. 279 (Washington: The World Bank, 1995).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bosworth, Barry, “Institutional Change and the Efficacy of Monetary Policy,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity: 1 (1989), pp. 77 –110.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Brinkmann, Emile J., and Paul M. Horvitz, “Risk-Based Capital Standards and the Credit Crunch,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, Vol. 27 (August 1995), pp. 848 –63.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Brock, Philip L., ed., If Texas Were Chile: A Primer on Banking Refonn (San Francisco: ICS Press, 1992).

  • Brunner, Karl, and Allan M. Meltzer, “Money and Credit in the Monetary Transmission Process,” Ametitan Economic Review, Vol. 28 (May 1988), pp. 446 –51.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Calvo, Guillermo A., and Fabrizio Coricelli, “Credit Market Imperfections and Output Response in Previously Centrally Planned Economies,” in Building Sound Finance in Emerging Market Economies, ed. by Gerard Caprio, David Folkerts-Landau, and Timothy D. Lane (Washington: International Monetary Fund and World Bank, 1994), pp. 257 –94.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Calvo, Guillermo A., and Morris Goldstein, “Crisis Prevention and Crisis Management after Mexico: What Role for the Official Sector?” paper presented at the Institute for International Economies Conference on Private Capital Flows to Emerging Markets after the Mexican Crisis, held in Vienna, Austria, September 1995.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Calvo, Guillermo A., and Manmohan S. Kumar, “Money Demand, Bank Credit, and Economic Performance in Former Socialist Economics,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 41 (June 1994), pp. 314 –49.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cantor, Richard, and John Wenninger, “Perspective on the Credit Slowdown, Quarterly Review,” Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Vol. 18 (Spring 1993), pp. 3 –36.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Caprio, Gerard Jr., and Daniela Klingebiel, “Bank Insolvency: Bad Luck, Bad Policy, or Bad Banking?” paper presented at the World Bank Annual Bank Conference on Development Economics, Washington, April 25 –26, 1996.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Carse, David, “Market Entry and Asset Quality,” Quarterly Bulletin, Hong Kong Monetary Authority (February 1995), pp. 42 –49.

  • Chari, V. V, Larry E. Jones, and Rodolfo E. Manuelli, “The Growth Effects of Monetary Policy,” Quarterly Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, Vol. 19 (Fall 1995), pp. 18 –32.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Clair, Robert T, Joanna O. Kolson, and Kenneth J. Robinson, “The Texas Banking Crisis and the Payments System,” Economic Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas (First Quarter 1995), pp. 13 –21.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Clare, Andrew D., “Using the Arbitrage Pricing Theory to Calculate the Probability of Financial Institution Failure,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, Vol. 27 (May 1995), pp. 920 –26.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cole, Rebel A., and Jeffrey W. Gunther, “Separating the Likelihood and Timing of Bank Failure,” Journal of Banking and Finance, Vol. 19 (September 1995), pp. 1073 –89.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cole, Rebel A., Barbara G. Cornyn, and Jeffrey W. Gunther, “FIMS: A New Monitoring System for Banking Institutions,” Federal Reserve Bulletin (January 1995), pp. 1 –15.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cottarelli, Carlo, and Angeiiki Kourelis, “Financial Structure, Bank Lending Rates, and the Transmission Mechanism of Monetary Policy,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 41 (December 1994), pp. 587 –623.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dale, Richard, “International Banking Regulation,” in International Financial Market Regulation, ed. by Benn Steil (Chichester; New York: John Wiley and Sons, 1994), pp. 1 –15.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • De Gregorio, José, and Pablo E. Guidotti, “Financial Development and Economic Growth,” IMF Working Paper 92/101 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, December 1992).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • de Juan, Aristóbulo, “Does Bank Insolvency Matter? And What to Do About It?” Economic Development Institute of the World Bank Working Paper (Washington: Economic Development Institute of the World Bank, 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • De Nederlandsche Bank, “Memorandum on the Role of the Supervisory Board of a Bank,” December 31, 1986, Quarterly Bulletin (Amsterdam: De Nederlandsche Bank, December 1987).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Demirgiic-Kunt, Asli, “Deposit-Institution Failures: A Review of Empirical Literature,” Economic Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Vol. 25 (Fourth Quarter 1989), pp. 2 –18.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Diamond, Douglas W., and Phillip H. Dybvig, “Bank Runs, Deposit Insurance, and Liquidity,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 91 (June 1983), pp. 401 –19.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dimsdale, Nicholas, “Banks, Capital Markets, and the Monetary Transmission Mechanism,” Oxford Review of Economic Policy, Vol. 10 (Winter 1994), pp. 34 –48.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dittus, Peter, Corporate Governance in Central Europe: The Role of Banks, BIS Economic Paper, No. 42 (Basle: Bank for International Settlements, August 1994).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dooley, Michael P., and Peter Isard, “The Role of Incentives and Planning in Market-Oriented Transition,” in Finance and the International Economy 6, ed. by Richard O’Brien (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1992), pp. 19 –31

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dornbusch, Rudiger, and Stanley Fischer, Macroeconomics (New York: McGraw-Hill Book Company, 6th ed. 1994).

  • Drees, Burkhard, and Ceyla Pozarbaşioğlu, “The Nordic Banking Crises: Pitfalls in Financial Liberalization,” IMF Working Paper 95/61 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, June 1995).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dziobek, Claudia, “Regulatory and Tax Treatment of Loan Loss Provisions,” IMF Papers on Policy Analysis and Assessment 96/6 (Washington: International Monetary Fund 1996).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dziobek, Claudia, Olivier Frécaur, and María Nieto, “Non-G-10 Countries and the Basle Capital Rules: How Tough a Challenge Is It to Join the Basle Club?” IMF Paper on Policy Analysis and Assessment 95/5 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, March 1995).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • European Union, Directive 95/26/EC of the European Parliament and Council Directive, Official Journal of the European Communities, No. L 168/7 (June 29, 1995).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • European Union, Directive 77/780CEE of the European Parliament and Council Directive, Official Journal of the European Communities, No. L322/30 (December 12, 1977).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Faig-Aumalle, Mliquel, “Implications of Banking Market Structure for Monetary Policy: A Survey,” IMF Working Paper 87/25 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, April 1987).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fairlamb, David, “Beyond Capital,” Institutional Investor, Vol. 19 (August 1994), pp. 16 –26.

  • Fama, Eugene E. “What’s Different About Banks?” Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 15 (January 1985), pp. 29 –39.

  • Fidler, Stephen (1996a), “IMF urged to do more in monitoring banking,” Financial Times, March 26, 1996, p. 4.

  • Fidler, Stephen, (1996b), “IMF urged to be bolder in fight to stem bank crises,” Financial Times, March 27, 1996, p. 6.

  • Fischer, Klaus P., and Jean-Pierre Gueyie, “Financial Liberalization and Bank Solvency,” paper presented at the symposium on Business Finance in Emerging Markets, held at the University of Laval, Quebec, August 31-September 1, 1995.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fischer, Stanley, “International Capital Flows, the International Agencies and Financial Stability,” in Financial Stability in a Changing Environment, ed. by Kuniho Sawamoto, Zenta Nakajima, and Hiroo Taguchi (New York: St. Martin’s Press, 1995), pp. 26 –37.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Folkerts-Landau, David, Takatoshi Ito, and others, International Capital Markets: Developments, Prospects, and Policy Issues, World Economic and Financial Surveys (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1995).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Freeland, Charles, “The Work of the Basle Committee,” in Current Legal Issues Affecting Central Banks, Vol. 2, ed. by Robert C. Effros (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1994), pp. 231 –40.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fries, Steven M., and Timothy D. Lane, “Financial and Enterprise Restructuring in Emerging Market Economies,” in Building Sound Finance in Emerging Market Economies, ed. by Gerard Caprio, David Folkerts-Landau, and Timothy D. Lane (Washington: International Monetary Fund and World Bank, 1994), pp. 21 –46.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Galbis, Vicente, “Financial Sector Reforms in Eight Countries: Issues and Results,” IMF Working Paper 95/141 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, December 1995).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Galbis, Vicente, “High Real Interest Rates Under Financial Liberalization: Is There a Problem?” IMF Working Paper 93/7 (Washington: International Monetary Fund,January 1993).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Garcia, Gillian, “Comparing and Confronting the Recent Banking Problems in Indonesia, Turkey, and Venezuela” (unpublished, Washington: International Monetary Fund, December 1994).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Garcia, Gillian, “Lessons from Bank Failures Worldwide,” paper presented at the conference on Regulating Depository Institutions, held at Koȩ University, Istanbul, November 3, 1995.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Garcia, Gillian, “Deposit Insurance: Obtaining the Benefits and Avoiding the Pitfalls,” IMF Working Paper 96/83 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, August 1996).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Garcia, Gillian, and Matthew I. Saal, “Internal Governance. Market Discipline, and Regulatory Restraint, “in Rethinking Bank Regulation, proceedings of the 32nd Annual Conference on Bank Structure and Competition, May 1996 (Chicago: Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, forthcoming).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gertler, Mark, “Financial Structure and Aggregate Economic Activity: An Overview,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, Vol. 20 (August 1988, Part 2), pp. 559 –88.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gilbert, R. Alton, and Sangkyun Park, “Value of Early Warning Models in Bank Supervision,” draft working paper, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis and Federal Reserve Bank of New York, 1994.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Goldstein, Morris, and others (1993a), International Capital Markets: Part I: Exchange Rate Management and International Capital Flows, World Economic and Financial Surveys (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1993).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Goldstein, Morris, and others, (1993b), International Capital Markets: Development, Prospects, and Policy Issues, World Economic and Financial Surveys (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1992).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Goodfriend, Marvin, “Money, Credit, Banking, and Payments System Policy,” Economic Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond (January/February 1991), pp. 7 –23.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Guodhart, Charles, “Price Stability and Financial Fragility,” in Financial Stability in a Changing Environment, ed. by Kuniho Sawamoto, Zenta Nakajima, and Hiroo Taguchi (New York: St. Martin’s Press, 1995).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gorton, Gary, “Banking Panics and Business Cycles,” Oxford Economic Papers, No. 40 (December 1988), pp. 221 –55.

  • Griffith-Jones, Stephany, “Introductory Framework,” in Financial Reform in Central and Eastern Europe, ed. by Stephany Griffith-Jones and Zdenĕk Drábek (New York: St. Martin’s Press, 1995), pp. 3 –15.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Guitián, Manuel, “A Neglected Dimension of Monetary Policy” (unpublished, Washington: International Monetary Fund, January 25, 1993).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Guide, Ann-Marie, “Liquid Asset Ratios—An Effective Policy Tool?” IMF Monetary and Exchange Affairs Department Operational Paper 95/04 (unpublished, Washington: International Monetary Fund, May 1995).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hall, Stephen, and David Miles, “Monitoring Bank Risk: A Market Based Approach,” Birkbeck College Department of Economics Discussion Paper in Financial Economics FE-3/90 (April 1990), pp. 1 –19.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hargraves, Monica, and Garry J. Schinasi, “Monetary Policy, Financial Liberalization, and Asset Price Inflation,” Annex I in World Economic Outlook (Washington: International Monetary Fund, May 1993), pp. 81 –95.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hausmann, Ricardo, and Michael Gavin, “The Roots of Banking Crises: The Macroeconomic Context,” paper presented at the Inter-American Development Bank Conference on Banking Crises in Latin America, held in Washington, October 6-7, 1995.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hinds, Manuel, “Economic Effects of Financial Crises,” Policy, Planning, and Research Working Paper, No. 104 (Washington: World Bank, October 1988).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hong Kong Monetary Authority, Annual Report (Hong Kong, 1994).

  • International Accounting Standards Committee, International Accounting Standards (Rochester, England: The Stanhope Press, 1995).

  • International Monetary Fund, Theoretical Aspects of the Design of Fund-Supported Adjustment Programs, IMF Occasional Paper, No.55 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, September 1987).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, “The Special Data Dissemination Standard: Standards for the Dissemination by Countries of Economic and Financial Statistics” (Washington: International Monetary Fund, April 1995).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, Manual on Monetary and Financial Statistics (Washington: International Monetary Fund, forthcoming in mid-1997).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Jaffee, Dwight, and Mark Levonian, “Russian Banking,” in Weekly Letter, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, No. 95-35 (October 20, 1995), pp. 1 –3.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • James, Christopher, “Some Evidence on the Uniqueness of Bank Loans,” Journal of Financial Economics, Vol. 19 (December 1987), pp. 217 –35.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • James, Harold, International Monetary Cooperation Since Bretton Woods (New York: Oxford University Press, 1995).

  • “Japan Lifts Another Veil,” The Banker, November 1995, p. 8

  • Johnston, R. Barry, “Distressed Financial Institutions in Thailand: Structural Weaknesses, Support Operations, and Economic Consequences,” in Banking Crises: Cases and Issues, ed. by V. Sundararajan and Tomás J.T. Baliño (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1991), pp. 234 –75.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Johnston, R. Barry, and Cevla Pazarbaşioğiu. “Linkages Between Financial Variables, Financial Sector Reform, and Economic Growth and Efficiency,” IMF Working Paper, WP/95/103 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, October 1995).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kaminsky, Graciela L., and Carmen M. Reinhart, “The Twin Crises: The Causes of Banking and Balance-of-Payments Problems,” International Finance Discussion Paper No. 544 (Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, March 1996).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kane, Edward J., “Difficulties of Transferring Risk-Based Capital Requirements to Developing Countries,” Pacific-Basin Finance Journal, Vol. 3 (July 1995), pp. 193 –216.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kapur, Ishan, and others, Ghana: Adjustment and Growth, 1983-91, IMF Occasional Paper, No. 86 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, September 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kaufman, George G., “Are Some Banks Too Large to Fail? Myth and Reality,” Contemporary Policy Issues, Vol. 8 (October 1990), pp. 1 –14.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kaufman, George G., “Bank Contagion: A Review of the Theory and Evidence,” Journal of Financial Services Research, Vol. 8 (1994), pp. 123 –50.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kim, Myung-Sun, and William Kross, “The Impact of the 1989 Change in Bank Capital Standards on Loan Loss Provisions” (unpublished, New Brunswick, New Jersey: Rutgers University, August 1995).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kneeshaw, J. T., “Survey of Non-Financial Sector Balance Sheets in Industrialized Countries: Implications for the Monetary Policy Transmission Mechanism,” BIS Working Paper No. 25 (Basle: Bank for International Settlements, April 1995).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kupiec, Paul H., and James M. O’Brien, “A Precommitment Approach to Capital Requirements for Market Risk,” in The New Tool Set, proceedings of the 31st Annual Conference on Bank Structure and Competition, May 1995 (Chicago: Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, 1995), pp. 552 –62.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kyei, Alexander, “Deposit Protection Arrangements: A Survey,” IMF Working Paper 95/134 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, December 1995).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lane, Timothy D., “Market Discipline,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 40 (March 1993), pp. 53 –88.

  • Leone, Alfredo M., “Institutional and Operational Aspects of Central Bank Losses,” IMF Paper on Policy Analysis and Assessment 93/14 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, September 1993).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Louis, Jean-Victor, “Banking in the European Community After 1992,” in Vol. 2 of Current Legal Issues Affecting Central Banks, ed. by Robert C. Effros (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1994), pp. 69 –81.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Luckett, Dudley G., “Credit Standards and Tight Money,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, Vol. 2 (November 1970), p. 420 –33.

  • Ludwig, Eugene A., letter to the Chief Executive Officers of National Banks, including a Survey of Underwriting Policies and Practices, November 7, 1995.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Maciejewski, Edouard, and Ahsan Mansur, eds., Jordan—Strategy for Adjustment and Growth, IMF Occasional Paper, No. 136 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, May 1996).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Marston, David, “The Use of Reserve Requirements in Monetary Control,” IMF Monetary and Exchange Affairs Department Operational Paper (unpublished, Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1996).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mathieson, Donald J., and Richard D. Haas, “Establishing Monetary Control in Financial Systems with Insolvent Institutions,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 42 (March 1995), pp. 184 –201.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mishkin, Frederic S., “Asymmetric Information and Financial Crises: A Historical Perspective,” in Financial Markets and Financial Crises, ed. by Hubbard R. Glenn (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1991), pp. 69 –108.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mishkin, Frederic S., “Preventing Financial Crises: An International Perspective,” NBFR Working Paper No. 4636 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research, February 1994).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Montes-Negret, Fernando, and Luca Papi, “Are Bank Interest Rate Spreads Too High?” Viewpoint (Washington: The World Bank, Financial Sector Development Department, February 1996).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Nascimento, Jean-Claude, “Crisis in the Financial Sector and the Authorities’ Reaction: The Philippines,” in Banking Crises: Cases and Issues, ed. by V. Sundararajan and Tomás J. T Baliño (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1991), pp. 175 –233.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • National Bank of Commerce, Tanzania, “Press Statement” Guardian (Dar es Salaam: July 24, 1995).

  • Otani, Ichiro, and Chi Do Pham, eds., The Lao People’s Democratic Republic—Systemic Transformation and Adjustments, IMF Occasional Paper, No. 137 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, May 1996).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Padoa-Schioppa, Tommaso “Cooperation Between Banking and Market Regulators,” paper presented at the XX Annual Conference of the International Organization of Securities Commissions (IOSCO) held in Paris, July 12, 1995.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Pérez-Campanero, Juan, and Alfredo M. Leone, “Liberalization and Financial Crisis in Uruguay, 1974-87,” in Banking Crises: Cases and Issues, ed. by V. Sundararajan and Tomás J.T. Baliño (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1991), pp. 276 –375.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Perotti, Enrico C. “Bank Lending in Transition Economies,” Journal of Banking and Finance, Vol. 17 (September 1993), pp. 1021 –32.

  • Perú, Superintendencia de Banca y Seguros, Guía del Director de Empresas Bancarias, Financieras y de Crédito de Consumo (Lima, 1995).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Pozdena, Randall J., “Is Banking Really Prone to Panics?” Weekly Letter, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, No. 91-35 (October 11, 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Premchand, A., Effective Government Accounting (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1995).

  • Prowse, Stephen, Corporate Governance in an International Perspective, BIS Economic Paper, No. 41 (Basle: Bank for International Settlements, July 1994).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Prowse, Stephen, “Alternative Methods of Corporate Control in Commercial Banks,” Economic Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas (Third Quarter 1995), pp. 24 –36.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Quirk, Peter J., and Owen Evans, Capital Account Convertibility: Review of Experience and Implications for IMF Policies, IMF Occasional Paper, No. 131 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, October 1995).