IV Role of Macroeconomic Policies
Author:
Ms. Kalpana Kochhar
Search for other papers by Ms. Kalpana Kochhar in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
,
Mr. Erik Offerdal
Search for other papers by Mr. Erik Offerdal in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
,
Mr. Louis Dicks-Mireaux
Search for other papers by Mr. Louis Dicks-Mireaux in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
,
Mr. Mauro Mecagni
Search for other papers by Mr. Mauro Mecagni in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
,
Ms. Jianping Zhou
Search for other papers by Ms. Jianping Zhou in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
,
Mr. Balázs Horváth
Search for other papers by Mr. Balázs Horváth in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
,
Mr. David John Goldsbrough
Search for other papers by Mr. David John Goldsbrough in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close
, and
Ms. Sharmini Coorey
Search for other papers by Ms. Sharmini Coorey in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close

Abstract

Although initial internal and external conditions varied considerably across the eight countries, in most of them the need for adjustment stemmed from an excess of domestic demand over output that had led to an unsustainable external imbalance. So the task before policymakers was to bring domestic absorption down to more sustainable levels in a way that minimized contractionary effects on output, and, at the same time, to foster conditions for raising long-term growth. This section highlights several broad themes of stabilization policies pursued by these countries, drawing where appropriate upon particular country examples, as well as the econometric analysis of private investment behavior discussed in Section V.

Although initial internal and external conditions varied considerably across the eight countries, in most of them the need for adjustment stemmed from an excess of domestic demand over output that had led to an unsustainable external imbalance. So the task before policymakers was to bring domestic absorption down to more sustainable levels in a way that minimized contractionary effects on output, and, at the same time, to foster conditions for raising long-term growth. This section highlights several broad themes of stabilization policies pursued by these countries, drawing where appropriate upon particular country examples, as well as the econometric analysis of private investment behavior discussed in Section V.

The output response to stabilization policies depends on a complex set of interactions among a variety of factors, including the mix of policy measures, structural features of the economy, the conditions prevailing prior to adjustment, and the impact of exogenous shocks. The three main macroeconomic policy tools used to achieve stabilization have been fiscal policy, exchange rate policy, and monetary or credit policy. These policies influence output and long-term growth through several channels: by acting on the level of aggregate demand (expenditure reduction); by influencing the ease with which demand and supply shift between the tradable and nontradable goods sectors (resource switching); and by affecting intertemporal consumption choices, that is, the composition of demand between investment and consumption.

Within this broad framework, this section centers on three main themes: how the timeliness of policy responses to emerging imbalances can greatly influence the initial impact of stabilization policies on output and investment; the importance of the consistency and sustainability of policies; and the need to take careful account of key structural rigidities in designing macroeconomic policies.

Costs of Delayed Adjustment

In most of the eight countries, adjustment had to be implemented in the context of some form of macroeconomic crisis. Thus, in all of them except Thailand and Bangladesh, the authorities were faced with uncontrolled inflation, or an abrupt deterioration in access to foreign financing, or both (see Table 3 and Chart 5). The experience of the eight countries suggests that stabilization policies undertaken because of a macroeconomic crisis will generally have more substantial, and more prolonged, contractionary effects than when policies are implemented in a more timely manner. This arises not simply because the size of initial imbalances requiring adjustment is larger, but—what is equally important—because crisis tends to spawn second-best policies and sap the private sector’s confidence in government actions.

Abrupt Reduction in Real Domestic Absorption

Delays in adjustment that led to the buildup of large initial imbalances, the depletion of foreign exchange reserves, and the emergence of severe external financing constraints were often associated with a more abrupt reduction in real domestic absorption. This can be illustrated by comparing the magnitude of corrections to domestic absorption and the contemporaneous slowdown in output growth—as measured by output gaps (Table 6).22 The largest reductions in domestic demand generally occurred in countries that had the greatest initial internal and external imbalances (notably Chile and Mexico) or where existing macroeconomic problems made economies especially vulnerable to adverse external shocks. The latter were particularly large in several cases—for example, Chile I and Ghana prior to the Economic Recovery Program, as well as in Thailand (see Chart 6). For most of the countries with severe initial macroeconomic imbalances, there were few realistic alternatives to rapid and substantial stabilization; such cases were usually associated with the largest widening of output gaps and the most prolonged subsequent recessions—unless, as in Morocco, favorable supply shocks intervened.

Table 6.

Changes in Domestic Absorption and Output Gaps During Particular Contractionary Episodes

(Cumulative changes in percent over indicated period; in constant prices, unless indicated otherwise)

article image
Note: Senegal was not included in this part of the exercise because supply shocks were so frequent that it was not possible to estimate meaningful output gaps.

Excluding transfers.

Excluding grants. Positive change indicates a decrease in the deficit or an increase in the surplus.

Based on the contemporaneous rate of inflation of the GDP deflator. For Bangladesh, Morocco, and Senegal, includes credit to public enterprises.

The change in nonagricultural GDP is given in parentheses, to exclude the impact of weather-related supply shocks.

But initial conditions and policy delays are not the only reasons for contraction. Even countries that are generally regarded as having acted in a timely manner, such as Thailand, did not escape fully from contractionary influences: although not weak by international standards, per capita growth slowed to the lowest rate in a decade during 1985-86, and the lag in the response of output and investment to adjustment policies was of concern to the authorities at the time.

Second-Best Crisis Measures

Policies undertaken in crisis conditions sometimes included ad hoc or emergency measures that were not necessarily conducive to investment and growth. Fiscal adjustment tended to be greatest in cases where the initial imbalances were largest—particularly Chile I, Mexico, and Morocco, and where loss of access to external financing forced an especially abrupt adjustment (Chart 10).23 It is difficult to establish precise links between particular fiscal consolidation measures and growth. The reduction in public investment in these countries reversed previous booms and may well have eliminated many projects with low rates of return. However, the discussion in the companion study on the composition of fiscal adjustment does illustrate that fiscal adjustment in such circumstances was usually not based, at least initially, on well-designed changes in tax and expenditure systems of the type thought to be conducive to growth:

Chart 10.
Chart 10.

Fiscal Indicators1

(In percent of GDP)

Source: IMF staff estimates.1 t is the initial year (given in parentheses) of adjustment period.2 Excluding grants, except Mexico, India and Bangladesh. No data on primary deficit for Bangladesh.3 At constant prices; for Chile and Senegal excludes public enterprise investment.4 t–l is the average of 1970–73.5 Excluding central bank losses.
  • Often there is a sequencing problem, where deficiencies in public expenditure management and tax administration initially require a rather crude approach to expenditure restraint and prevent the speedy reform of the tax system. Some expenditure cuts can, however, be damaging, if not reversed in due course. To facilitate their reversal and to improve expenditure allocation, immediate action to reform both tax administration and public expenditure management is necessary.24

Moreover, in a number of cases (Ghana, Morocco, Mexico, and India), initial efforts to protect the balance of payments involved the imposition or intensification of import and exchange controls, which squeezed imports of intermediate and capital goods and probably added an adverse supply shock to the contractionary effects stemming from the demand side. Also, in a few countries (for example, Mexico and in Ghana on several occasions prior to the Economic Recovery Program), measures of a confiscatory nature, such as mandatory conversion of foreign currency bank deposits on nonmarket terms, further eroded private confidence.

Uncertainty and the Effectiveness of Policies

The uncertainty and loss of credibility associated with a crisis can influence the effectiveness of particular policy measures. A deterioration in private confidence, indicated by an acceleration of capital flight, is likely to have adverse consequences for growth. Beyond this, the response of the economy to policy measures may differ in several important ways, and be harder to predict, during episodes of macroeconomic crisis. These factors help to explain why a good track record of macroeconomic policies appears to make adjustment less costly.

Lower fiscal deficits affect the composition of demand by lowering the cost and increasing the availability of credit to the private sector. But these “crowding-in” effects, which would tend to offset the direct contractionary effects of fiscal consolidation, are likely to be weaker and slower to operate in conditions of economic uncertainty. In such circumstances, the rational response of private investors would be to increase the wedge they require between the cost of capital and their expected rate of return.25 As a result, the effects of interest rate and credit policies on private sector behavior may be especially difficult to predict in the short term. In cases where adjustment was undertaken in the context of a crisis (Chile, Ghana, and Mexico), it appears that typically it took several years for credibility to be established even when substantial fiscal adjustment was undertaken up front, which contributed to the generally longer duration of the output gap. The empirical importance of such influences is hard to test, but some partial evidence is discussed in the next section.

Macroeconomic instability and heavy-handed use of government regulations prior to, and during periods of crisis, can trigger the emergence of institutional arrangements that will influence the impact of particular policy measures. For example, in countries in which a legacy of high inflation had led to widespread wage indexation (for example, Chile in the 1970s), the impact of nominal devaluations on the real exchange rate was typically greatly diminished. By contrast, a tradition of low inflation in some other countries (for example, Morocco and Thailand) allowed a more effective use of nominal depreciations to facilitate necessary changes in the real exchange rate (Chart 11).26 Similarly, attempts to reduce inflation through a tightening of monetary policy are likely to have a more substantial contractionary effect when inflation inertia is high (for example, Chile during the money-based stabilization of 1974-75).

Chart 11.
Chart 11.

Nominal and Real Effective Exchange Rates and Inflation in Various Indexation Regimes1

Source: IMF staff estimates.1 Rate of end-period consumer price inflation (in percent) is plotted on the right-hand scale. For Morocco, period average consumer price inflation. Nominal and real effective exchange rate indices are plotted on left-hand scale with base 1990 = 100. Increase indicates an appreciation.

Less Time for Resource-Switching Policies to Take Hold

If aggregate demand declines rapidly, there is generally less time for resource-switching policies to operate sufficiently on supply, particularly of tradables, so as to minimize the contractionary effects on output. Although it is difficult to observe directly the extent of resource switching from the nontradable to the tradable goods sectors, developments in exports and imports provide some indirect indications. In most cases, the export response, although strong, typically occurred with a lag and was not sufficient to offset the initial contractionary impact on output of reductions in domestic absorption (Chart 12). Indicators of the extent and timing of resource switching in the eight countries—the strength of export and import volume growth and estimates of deviations from historical trends of the import intensity of GDP and of export market share—suggest, first, that export performance strengthened during the adjustment episodes in all countries except Senegal, but typically with a lag, so that it did not cushion the initial contractionary impact on output of reductions in domestic absorption. Second, beyond the initial period of demand squeeze, substantial increases in export volumes supported the strongest recoveries in output and investment in Chile (1985 onward), Ghana (1984 onward), and Thailand (1986 onward). Third, the intensification of import restrictions, which fell heavily on intermediate inputs, caused growth to suffer—in Ghana (1976-82), India (1991), and Mexico (1982). The longer-term export response is discussed in Section VIII, in the context of trade reform.

Chart 12.
Chart 12.

Changes in Domestic Absorption, Exports, and Imports During Periods of Demand Contraction

(In percentage points)

Source: IMF staff estimates.1 Compares change in domestic demand in relation to real GDP with contribution of exports over the contraction periods in Table 6.2 Compares change in real domestic demand to change in import I volumes over the contraction periods in Table 6.3 Domestic absorption excludes inventories.

Sustainability and Consistency of Policies

Expectations of policy reversal may induce private investors to wait for uncertainty to be resolved, potentially locking the economy into a low-investment, low-growth equilibrium. In this context, the individual country studies suggest that two aspects of policies are likely to be especially important: progress toward a sustainable fiscal position and the consistency of macroeconomic policies.

Sustainability of Fiscal Policies

The effects of fiscal adjustment on output, investment, and saving depend on the composition of expenditure and revenue measures and the mix of financing, which in turn influences the pattern of real interest rates and private sector access to credit. However, expectations about the future course of fiscal policy are critical to the transmission process. If private agents expect the fiscal adjustment program to succeed in reducing the deficit and therefore the need for inflationary or debt financing, crowding-in effects will help to offset the initial contractionary effects and set in motion a virtuous circle of investment and growth.

Did private sector concerns about the medium-term sustainability of fiscal policy dampen the investment response during adjustment? There is no unique standard of fiscal sustainability, but one possible benchmark is the level of the primary balance that would be consistent with maintaining a constant public debt-to-GDP ratio in the context of low inflation and no financial repression. The existence of a potential credibility problem could be signaled by a path of the actual primary deficit that greatly exceeded this “sustainable” one, implying either a continued increase in the public sector debt-to-GDP ratio (and therefore a rising servicing burden) or the need for continued reliance on the inflation tax or financial repression (Chart 13).27 In the latter case, the fiscal stance would be inconsistent with a low inflation objective or financial sector reform. The consistency with financial liberalization is important because a number of countries in the study (for example, India, Mexico, and Morocco) initially financed a large part of their deficits by requiring banks and other financial institutions to hold domestic government securities at below-market interest rates.28 Therefore, the partial or complete liberalization of interest rates implemented in these countries had a substantial impact on the fiscal deficit. Details of the exercise are presented in Appendix III.

Chart 13.
Chart 13.

Difference Between Actual and “Sustainable” Fiscal Primary Balances1, 2

(In percent of GOP)

Source: Appendix III.1 Difference between actual primary balance and the estimated primary balance that would be consistent with no increase in the government debt-to-GDP ratio, in the context of low inflation and no financial repression. A positive figure implies that the actual balance is above the sustainable level (see Appendix III).2 Primary balance includes grants.3 Figures for Chile include the quasi-fiscal deficit of the central bank.

The results suggest that Thailand’s fiscal stance was broadly sustainable from the very outset of adjustment, which probably contributed to the relatively rapid pace of the private investment response. Among the countries that began their adjustment with large or intermediate fiscal imbalances, all made some progress toward setting public debt on a more sustainable path, although in several cases (notably Morocco among those with large initial imbalances) such a position was not attained until several years into the adjustment period. Moreover, in a few countries some of the progress toward fiscal sustainability was subsequently reversed (notably in Ghana and India), which may have contributed to the delayed crowding in of private investment in these countries. Mexico is of particular interest because it achieved a decisive up-front shift to a more sustainable fiscal position, in the narrow sense used here, and maintained that position throughout the entire adjustment period; yet the crowding-in effects in the form of higher private investment were slow to materialize and were relatively weak, thereby exacerbating the initial recession. The reasons for this will be explored more fully in the next section, but the debt crisis itself—and the associated shift in net resource transfers—involved a major switch in public sector financing from external to domestic sources, which constrained the availability of financing for the private sector at least through the mid-1980s.

Judgments about the sustainability of fiscal policy based on a debt dynamics criterion however, do not necessarily imply that fiscal policy is consistent with other macroeconomic objectives, notably the avoidance of excessive external current account deficits. The linkages between the fiscal and external imbalances are difficult to quantify on an ex-ante basis, in view of possible shifts in private sector saving and investment behavior at a time of substantial changes in macroeconomic and structural policies. Consequently, the fiscal adjustment framework may need to include contingency provisions in case the private sector response diverges substantially from that expected. For example, the different fiscal policy responses to the surges in capital inflows that occurred late in the adjustment period of several of the countries illustrate that a narrow debt dynamics criterion may not be a sufficient guide to the stance of fiscal policy. For example, in Mexico, fiscal policy did not respond to the surge in capital inflows of the early 1990s and the associated sharp decline in private saving; the fiscal position (excluding privatization revenues) was, however, in surplus. In contrast, Thailand’s fiscal policy was more explicitly countercyclical, despite its comfortable public debt position. These issues are taken up again in Section VII.

Consistency of Macroeconomic Policies

Even during the transition toward a more sustainable medium-term fiscal position, an inconsistent mix of macroeconomic policies may have adverse consequences for investment and output growth. The experience of the eight countries suggests that two difficult areas are the mix of monetary and fiscal policies and the coordination of fiscal, exchange rate, and wage policies.

The Mix of Monetary and Fiscal Policies

When faced with a macroeconomic crisis and constraints on the immediate scope for fiscal action, policymakers often tend to rely excessively on contractionary monetary policies. Such tendencies are exacerbated when adjustment is delayed, and access to external financing is sharply curtailed. In such circumstances, even quite strong fiscal adjustment may involve higher public sector domestic borrowing and a consequent squeeze on private sector credit. In this section, the yardsticks used to assess the stringency of private sector credit conditions are (1) growth rates of real bank credit to the private sector, which will reflect both changes in the demand for, and the supply of, credit29 and (2) the level of real domestic interest rates compared with the real SDR interest rate, as an indicator of international financial market conditions (Chart 14).30

Chart 14.
Chart 14.

Real Interest Rates1

(In percent per annum)

Sources: International Monetary Fund, International Financial Statistics; and IMF staff estimates.1 National nominal rates are deflated by the contemporaneous inflation rate of the GDP deflator. The real SDR rate is calculated as the weighted average interest rate on three-month instruments in the five countries whose currencies comprise the SDR deflated by the contemporaneous annual inflation rate of the GDP deflator. The weights are the currency units used in calculating the value of the SDR.2 Real deposit (not lending) rate.

If interest rates are not market determined, excessive fiscal borrowing would tend to crowd out the private sector through a direct reduction in the amount of credit allocated by the banking system. Ghana, in the period prior to the Economic Recovery Program, is such a case when access to external financing was reduced sharply (Chart 15). Although some modest fiscal adjustment took place during this time, the main burden seems to have fallen on private sector credit, which was squeezed substantially in real terms (Table 7). Another example is Mexico during 1983-87, when, despite substantial fiscal adjustment, the share of private sector credit in total credit and in GDP declined, because of portfolio constraints designed to channel a substantial proportion of bank lending to the public sector, which had virtually no access to external financing after the debt crisis. Similar influences appear to have been at work in Morocco in 1986-88. Of course, in all these cases, the high degree of macroeconomic uncertainty probably also dampened the demand for credit.

Chart 15.
Chart 15.

Stock of Private Sector Credit1

(In percent of total domestic credit)

Sources: International Monetary Fund, International Financial Statistics; and IMF staff estimates.1 Fiscal year data for Bangladesh and India. Private sector includes public enterprises for Bangladesh, Morocco, and Senegal.2 Break in coverage of monetary accounts in 1984.

If interest rates are somewhat more flexible, public sector borrowing requirements may absorb a large share of loanable funds from domestic credit markets and exert upward pressure on real interest rates or reduce private sector access to bank credit in still segmented credit markets. This appears to have been an important factor in the early stages of the 1990-91 crisis in India, when the authorities had to rely primarily on monetary policy to restrain demand because of the political constraints on early fiscal action, which resulted in a sharp contraction in the volume of credit and a subsequent rise in interest rates. By contrast, the major fiscal consolidation in Thailand since 1987 contributed to a decline in real interest rates and the rapid rise in the share of private sector credit in total credit and in GDP.

A related issue is the problem of weak bank balance sheets and its implications for monetary policy. A high proportion of effectively nonperforming assets—although often not explicitly recognized as such—contributed to high interest margins and inefficient intermediation in a number of countries and appears to have been a major impediment to private investment in some (for example, Bangladesh). Beyond this, the continued extension of new credit to service bad loans, in a context of ineffective bank supervision, in some cases undermined the effectiveness of monetary policy in controlling aggregate demand and thereby contributed to the severity of the eventual crisis and recession. The starkest example of this is Chile prior to 1982 (see Section VIII).

Coordination of Fiscal, Exchange Rate, and Wage Policies

Perceived inconsistencies between exchange rate, wage, and fiscal policies may undermine the credibility of an adjustment program, increasing uncertainty and expectations of impending policy reversals. In such circumstances, adverse effects on investment and growth may materialize through up-ward pressures on real interest rates or on the real exchange rate. For example, given a predetermined path for the nominal exchange rate, a fiscal policy stance that fuels excess demand pressures risks leading to higher nontradable goods’ prices and thereby an appreciated real exchange rate, with potentially penalizing effects on the contribution of net exports to growth. Equally important, continued backward-looking indexation practices limit the effectiveness of discrete exchange rate changes in bringing about a reduction in real wages and improvements in external competitiveness.

The influence of inconsistent fiscal and exchange rate policies appear to have been important in Mexico (1988-89) and Senegal (post-1987). In Mexico, interest rates rose sharply in the first year of the exchange-rate-based stabilization, reflecting incomplete credibility of the exchange rate anchor and large capital outflows. These pressures appear to have originated in part because of uncertainties surrounding the fiscal policy stance prior to the 1988 elections, as well as the shift to domestic debt financing of public sector borrowing requirements discussed earlier.31 Moreover, in the later stages of the exchange-rate-based stabilization program (after 1992), the primary fiscal balance and public saving deteriorated. While it is doubtful that a strengthening of public finances sufficient to fully offset the impact of the massive capital inflows could have been feasible, a tighter fiscal stance could have helped to reduce the risks to external sustainability posed by the appreciation of the real exchange rate.

In Senegal, concern about the feasibility of the adjustment strategy led to a rise in the premiums on domestic over French franc interest rates after 1987. With a large persistent decline in the terms of trade, fiscal and public sector wage policy (especially in the early 1990s when the fiscal deficit increased and arrears were accumulated) became inconsistent with the fixed parity between the CF A franc and the French franc.32

Table 7.

Key Macroeconomic Indicators and Summary of Exchange Rate Policy

(In percent, unless otherwise specifiedt refers to year in parentheses)

article image

Excluding grants.

Average annual change over the three-year period (t through t + 2); deflated by GDP deflator. For Bangladesh, Morocco, and Senegal, includes credit to public enterprises.

Percentage change in real effective exchange rate between (t – 1) and (t + 2). A minus sign indicates a depreciation.

Revisions to national income accounts imply that ratios to GDP prior to 1975 may not be strictly comparable to later estimates.

Fiscal deficits excluding central bank losses.

Labor market and fiscal policies were also crucial in determining the trade-off in exchange-rate-based disinflation programs between inflation reduction and a loss of external competitiveness; both sides of this trade-off have potential implications for growth.33 This is illustrated by the examples of Mexico (post-1988) and Chile (1978-82). In Mexico, the exchange rate anchor was supported by successive forward-looking wage-price “pacts” agreed upon with the private sector, which succeeded, at least partially, in breaking inflation inertia.34 However, the real exchange rate did subsequently appreciate, under pressure from capital inflows and labor market policies that provided inadequate support for the exchange rate anchor (see also Section VIII). By contrast, in Chile (1978-82) there was no attempt to change the existing system of full backward-looking wage indexation during the preannounced nominal exchange rate period. This inconsistency contributed to excess demand pressures and a real exchange rate

In contrast, the potential benefits of coordinated exchange rate, fiscal, and labor market policies for providing adequate incentives to the tradable goods sector and eliciting a strong resource-switching response are well illustrated by the later adjustment episode in Chile and by Thailand. Chile’s strong recovery after 1984 owed much to the sustained real depreciation of the exchange rate that underpinned a sharp increase in the volume of exports other than of copper. The success with which nominal exchange rate depreciations were translated into a significant real depreciation reflected the suspension of compulsory wage indexation in 1982 and the large fiscal retrenchment. The persistence of considerable un-employment at least until 1987 was also an important factor in holding real wages in check. In Thai-land, depreciation of the nominal exchange rate contributed to a large sustained real depreciation after 1984 and induced large export market gains. The magnitude of the real depreciation closely matched the size of the nominal devaluation reflecting the flexibility of Thailand’s labor market, a tradition of relatively low inflation, and stable macroeconomic policies that kept inflationary expectations in check. The achievement of sizable fiscal surpluses helped contain inflationary pressures when economic activity surged and offset upward pressures on the exchange rate stemming from large capital inflows.

  • Collapse
  • Expand
Lessons from Adjustment Policies in Eight Economies
  • Chart 10.

    Fiscal Indicators1

    (In percent of GDP)

  • Chart 11.

    Nominal and Real Effective Exchange Rates and Inflation in Various Indexation Regimes1

  • Chart 12.

    Changes in Domestic Absorption, Exports, and Imports During Periods of Demand Contraction

    (In percentage points)

  • Chart 13.

    Difference Between Actual and “Sustainable” Fiscal Primary Balances1, 2

    (In percent of GOP)

  • Chart 14.

    Real Interest Rates1

    (In percent per annum)

  • Chart 15.

    Stock of Private Sector Credit1

    (In percent of total domestic credit)

  • Agarwala, Ramgopal, Price Distortions and Growth in Developing Countries,World Bank Staff Working Paper No. 575 (Washington: World Bank, July 1983).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Agénor, Pierre-Richard, The Labor Market and Economic Adjustment,IMF Working Paper No. 95/125 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, November 1995).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Agénor, and Joshua Aizenmen, Macroeconomic Adjustment with Segmented Labor Markets,NBER Working Paper No. 4769 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research, June 1994).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Anand, Ritu and Sweder van Wijnbergen, Inflation and the Financing of Government Expenditure: An Introductory Analysis with an Application to Turkey,World Bank Economic Review, Vol. 3 (January 1989), pp. 1738.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Asilis, Carlos M., and Gian Maria Milesi-Ferreti, On the Political Sustainability of Economic Reform,IMF Paper on Policy Analysis and Assessment No. 94/3 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, January 1994).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Atje, Raymond, and Boyan Jovanovic, Stock Markets and Development,European Economic Review, Vol. 37 (April 1993), pp. 63240.

  • Barro, Robert J., Economic Growth in a Cross-Section of Countries,NBER Working Paper No. 3120 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research, September 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Barro, Robert J., and Jong-Wha Lee, International Comparisons of Educational Attainment,Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 2 (December 1993), pp. 36394.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bennett, Adam, Behavior of Nominal and Real Interest Rates,in IMF Conditionality: Experience Under Stand-By and Extended Arrangements, Part II: Back-ground Papers, ed. by Susan Schadler, IMF Occasional Paper No. 129 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, September 1995).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bercuson, K. and L. Koenig, The Recent Surge in Capital Inflows to Three Asian Countries: Causes and Macro-economic Impact, South East Asian Central Banks, Occasional Paper No. 15 (Kuala Lumpur, 1993).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bisat, Amer, R. Barry Johnston, and V. Sundararajan, Issues in Managing and Sequencing Financial Sector Reforms: Lessons from Experiences in Five Developing Countries,IMF Working Paper No. 92/82 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, October 1992).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Boone, Peter, The Impact of Foreign Aid on Savings and Growth,Working Paper No. 1265 (London: Center for Economic Performance, London School of Economics, November 1994).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Borensztein, Eduardo, Jose De Gregorio, and Jong-Wha Lee, How Does Foreign Direct Investment Affect Economic Growth?NBER Working Paper No. 5057 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research, March 1995).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bosworth, Barry P., Rudiger Dornbusch, Laban, Raul eds., The Chilean Economy: Policy Lessons and Challenges (Washington: Brookings Institution, 1994).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bourguignon, François and Christian Morrisson, Adjustment and Equity in Developing Countries: A New Approach (Paris: Development Center, Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, 1992).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Branson, William H., and Carl Jayarajah, A Framework for Evaluating Policy Adjustment Programs: Lessons from a Cross-Country Evaluation,in Evaluation and Development: Proceedings of the 1994 World Bank Conference (Washington: World Bank, Operations Evaluation Department, 1995).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bruno, Michael, S. Fischer, E. Helpman, and N. Liviatan, eds., Lessons of Economic Stabilization and Its After-math (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press, 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bruno, Michael, and William Easterly, Inflation Crises and Long-Run Growth,NBER Working Paper No. 5209 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research, July 1995).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Calvo, Guillermo, and Carlos A. Végh, Inflation Stabilization and Nominal Anchors,IMF Paper on Policy Analysis and Assessment No. 92/4 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, December 1992).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Calvo, Guillermo, and Carlos A. Végh, Exchange-Rate-Based Stabilization Under Imperfect Credibility,in Open-Economy Macroeconomics, ed. by Helmut Frisch and Andreas Wörgötter (Houndsmill, Basingstoke, England: Macmillan Press, 1993).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Chhibber, Ajay, Mansoor Dailami, and Nemat Shafik, eds., Reviving Private Investment in Developing Countries: Empirical Studies and Policy Lessons (Amsterdam, New York: North-Holland, 1992).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Chopra, Ajay, Charles Collyns, Richard Hemming, and Karen Parker, India: Economic Reform and Growth, IMF Occasional Paper No. 134 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, December 1995).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Citrin, Daniel A., and Ashok K. Lahiri, eds., Policy Experiences and Issues in the Baltics, Russia, and Other Countries of the Former Soviet Union, IMF Occasional Paper No. 133 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, December 1995).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Claessens, Stijn, Daniel Oks, and Sweder van Wijnbergen, Interest Rates, Growth and External Debt: The Macroeconomic Impact of Mexico’s Brady Deal,CEPR Discussion Paper No. 904 (London: Center for Economic Policy Research, 1994).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Conway, Patrick, IMF Lending Programs: Participation and Impact,Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 45 (December 1994), pp. 36591.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Corbo, Vittorio, and Klaus Schmidt-Hebbel, Public Policy and Saving in Developing Countries,Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 36 (July 1991), pp. 89115.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Corbo, Vittorio, Stanley Fischer, and Steven B. Webb, eds., Adjustment Lending Revisited: Policies to Restore Growth (Washington: World Bank, 1992).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Currie, Janet and Ann Harrison, Trade Reforms and Labor Market Adjustment in Morocco,Labor Markets Workshop (Washington: World Bank, June 1994).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • De Gregorio, Jose, Economic Growth in Latin America,Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 39 (July 1992), pp. 5984.

  • Dixit, Avinash K., Investment and Hysteresis,Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 6, No. 1 (Winter 1992), pp. 10732.

  • Dixit, Avinash K., and Robert S. Pindyck, Investment Under Uncertainty (Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press, 1994).

  • Dornbusch, Rudiger, and Stanley Fischer, Moderate Inflation,World Bank Economic Review, Vol. 7 (January 1993), pp. 144.

  • Easterly, W., Endogenous Growth in Developing Countries with Government-Induced Distortions,in Adjustment Lending Revisited: Policies to Restore Growth, ed. by Vittorio Corbo, Stanley Fischer, and Steven B. Webb (Washington: World Bank, 1992).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Easterly, W., Carlos A. Rodriguez and Klaus Schmidt-Hebbel, eds., Public Sector Deficits and Macroeconomic Performance (New York: Oxford University Press, 1994).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Edwards, Sebastian, On the Sequencing of Structural Reforms,NBER Working Paper No. 3138 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research, October 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Edwards, Sebastian, Exchange Rates, Inflation and Disinflation: Latin American Experiences,NBER Working Paper No. 4320 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research, April 1993).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Elías, Victor J., Sources of Growth: A Study of Seven Latin American Countries, International Center for Economic Growth (San Francisco: ICS Press, 1992).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Faruqee, Hamid, and Aasim M. Husain, Saving Trends in Southeast Asia: A Cross-Country Analysis,IMF Working Paper No. 95/39 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, April 1995).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Feliciano, M., Workers and Trade Liberalization: The Impact of Trade Reforms in Mexico on Wages and Employment” (unpublished; Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University, 1994).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fischer, Stanley, Role of Macroeconomic Factors in Growth,Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 32 (December 1993), pp. 485512.

  • Hadjimichael, Michael T., Dhaneshwar Ghura, Martin Mühleisen, Roger Nord, and E. Murat Uçer, Sub-Saharan Africa: Growth, Savings, and Investment, 1986-93, IMF Occasional Paper No. 118 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, January 1995).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hadjimichael, Michael T., and Dhaneshwar Ghura, Public Policies and Private Savings and Investment in Sub-Saharan Africa: An Empirical Investigation,IMF Working Paper No. 95/19 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, February 1995).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Haque, Nadeem U., Kajal Lahiri, and Peter J. Montiel, Macroeconometric Model for Developing Countries,Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 37 (September 1990), pp. 53759.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Haque, Nadeem U., and Peter J. Montiel, Dynamic Responses to Policy and Exogenous Shocks in an Empirical Developing Model with Rational Expectations,in Macroeconomic Models for Adjustment in Developing Countries, ed. by Mohsin S. Khan, Peter J. Montiel, and Nadeem U. Haque (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Horton, Susan, Ravi Kanbur, and Dipak Mazumdar, eds., Labor Markets in an Era of Adjustment, Issues Papers, Vols. 1 and 2, EDI Development Studies (Washington: World Bank, 1994).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Husain, Ishrat and Rashid Faruqee, eds., Adjustment in Africa: Lessons from Country Case Studies, World Bank Regional and Sectoral Studies (Washington: World Bank, 1994).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, “The Experience of Successfully Adjusting Developing Countries,in World Economic Outlook, October 1992: A Survey by the Staff of the International Monetary Fund, World Economic and Financial Surveys (Washington: International Monetary Fund, October 1992).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, (1993a), “Convergence and Divergence in Developing Countries,in World Economic Outlook, May 1993: A Survey by the Staff of the International Monetary Fund, World Economic and Financial Surveys (Washington: International Monetary Fund, May 1993).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, (1993b), “Domestic and Foreign Saving in Developing Countries,in World Economic Outlook October 1993: A Survey by the Staff of the International Monetary Fund, World Economic and Financial Surveys (Washington: International Monetary Fund, October 1993).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, “Why Are Some Developing Countries Failing to Catch Up?in World Economic Outlook May 1994: A Survey by the Staff of the International Monetary Fund, World Economic and Financial Surveys (Washington: International Monetary Fund, May 1994).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, World Economic Outlook, May 1995: A Survey by the Staff of the International Monetary Fund, World Economic and Financial Surveys (Washington: International Monetary Fund, May 1995).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, Fiscal Affairs Department, Unproductive Public Expenditures: A Pragmatic Approach to Policy Analysis, IMF Pamphlet Series, No. 48 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1995).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Khan, Mohsin S., Macroeconomic Effects of Fund-Supported Programs,Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 37 (June 1990), pp. 195221.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Khan, Mohsin S., and Malcolm D. Knight, Fund-Supported Adjustment Programs and Economic Growth, IMF Occasional Paper No. 41 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1985).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Khan, Mohsin S., and Carmen M. Reinhart, Capital Flows in the APEC Region, IMF Occasional Paper No. 122 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, March 1995).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Khan, Mohsin S., Peter J. Montiel, and Nadeem U. Haque, eds., Macroeconomic Models for Adjustment in Developing Countries (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kiguel, Miguel A., and Nissan Liviatan, Business Cycle Associated with Exchange Rate-Based Stabilizations,World Bank Economic Review, Vol. 6 (May 1992), pp. 279305.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • King, Robert G., and Ross Levine, Financial Indicators and Growth in a Cross Section of Countries,Policy Research Working Paper WPS/819 (Washington: World Bank, 1992).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • King, Robert G., and Ross Levine, Finance and Growth: Schumpeter Might Be Right,Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 108 (August 1993), pp. 71737.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • King, Robert G., and Ross Levine, Capital Fundamentalism, Economic Development, and Economic Growth,Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, Vol. 40 (1994), pp. 259300.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kirmani, Naheed and others, International Trade Policies: The Uruguay Round and Beyond, Vols. I and II, World Economic and Financial Surveys (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1994).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kochhar, K., L. Dicks-Mireaux, B. Horvath, M. Mecagni, E. Offerdal, and J. Zhou, Thailand: The Road to Sustained Growth, International Monetary Fund (forthcoming).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kormendi, Roger C., and Philip G. Meguire, Macroeconomic Determinants of Growth: Cross-Country Evidence,Journal of Monetary Economics, Vol. 16 (September 1985), pp. 14163.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Krueger, Anne O., Maurice W. Schiff, and Alberto Valdés, The Political Economy of Agricultural Pricing Policy (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1992).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Levine, Ross, and David Renelt, A Sensitivity Analysis of Cross-Country Growth Regressions,American Economic Review, Vol. 82 (September 1992), pp. 94263.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Little, Ian M.D., R.N. Cooper, W. Corden, and S. Rajapatirana, Boom, Crisis, and Adjustment: The Macroeconomic Experience of Developing Countries (New York: Oxford University Press, 1993).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Loser, Claudio M., and Eliot Kalter, eds., Mexico: The Strategy to Achieve Sustained Economic Growth, IMF Occasional Paper No. 99 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1992).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mackenzie, George A., and others, Composition of Fiscal Adjustment and Growth, International Monetary Fund, (forthcoming).

  • Mankiw, N. Gregory, David Romer, and David N. Weil, A Contribution to the Empirics of Economic Growth,Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 107 (May 1992), pp. 40737.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mariano, Roberto S., Analytical Small-Sample Distribution Theory in Econometrics: The Simultaneous-Equations Case,International Economic Review, Vol. 23 (October 1982), pp. 50333.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Masson, Paul R., Tamim Bayoumi, and Hossein Samiei, Saving Behavior in Industrial and Developing Countries,in Staff Studies for the World Economic Outlook, by the Research Department of the International Monetary Fund, World Economic and Financial Surveys (Washington: International Moneary Fund, September 1995).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • McCarthy, F. Desmond, J. Peter Neary, and Giovanni Zanalda, Measuring the Effect of External Shocks and the Policy Response to Them: Empirical Methodology Applied to the Philippines,Policy Research Working Paper No. 1271 (Washington: World Bank, March 1994).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mecagni, Mauro, Experience with Nominal Anchors,in IMF Conditionality: Experience Under Stand-By and Extended Arrangements, Part II: Background Papers, ed. by Susan Schadler, IMF Occasional Paper No. 129 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, September 1995).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Meller, Patricio, Adjustment and Equity in Chile (Paris: Development Center of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, 1992).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Montiel, Peter J., The Transmission Mechanism for Monetary Policy in Developing Countries,Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 38 (March 1991), pp. 83108.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Montiel, Peter J., A Macroeconomic Simulation Model for India” (unpublished; Oberlin College, February 1993).

  • Mosley, Paul, Jane Harrigan, and John Toye, Aid and Power: The World Bank and Policy-Based Lending (London: Routledge, 1991; 2nd ed., 1995).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Nehru, Vikram, and A. Dhareshwar, A New Database on Physical Capital Stock: Sources, Methodology and Results,Revista de Andlisis Economico, Vol. 8, No. 1 (1993), pp. 3759.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Nowak, M., R. Basanti, B. Horvath, K. Kochhar, and R. Prem, Ghana, 1983-91,in Adjustment for Growth: The African Experience, International Monetary Fund (forthcoming).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Nsouli, Saleh M., Sena Eken, Klaus Enders, Van-Can Thai, Jörg Decressin, and Filippo Cartiglia, Resilience and Growth Through Sustained Adjustment: The Moroccan Experience, IMF Occasional Paper No. 117 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, January 1995).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ogaki, Masao, Jonathan D. Ostry, and Carmen M. Rein-hart, Saving Behavior in Low-and Middle-Income Developing Countries: A Comparison,Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 43 (March 1966), pp. 3871.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Oks, Daniel, and E. Luttmer, Mexico: Reform and Productivity Growth,World Bank Report No. 11823-ME (Washington: World Bank, May 1994).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Papageorgiou, Demetrios, Armeane M. Choksi, and Michael Michaely, Liberalizing Foreign Trade in Developing Countries: The Lessons of Experience (Washington: World Bank, 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Phillips, P.C.B., Exact Small Sample Theory in the Simultaneous Equation Model,in Handbook of Econometrics, Vol. I, ed. by Zvi Griliches and Michael D. Intrilligator (Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1983).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Pindyck, Robert S., Irreversibility, Uncertainty and Investment,Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 29 (September 1991), pp. 111049.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Rebelo, Sergio, and Carlos A. Végh, Real Effects of Exchange-Rate-Based Stabilization: An Analysis of Competing Theories,in NBER Macroeconomics Annual, 1995 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press, 1995).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Reinhart, Carmen M., Carlos A. Végh, Nominal Interest Rates, Consumption Booms, and Lack of Credibility: A Quantitative Examination,Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 46 (April 1995), pp. 35778.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Revenga, Ana, Employment and Wage Effects of Trade Liberalization: The Case of Mexican Manufacturing,Policy Research Working Paper No. 1524 (Washington: World Bank, 1995).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Roe, Alan, and Hartmut Schneider, Adjustment and Equity in Ghana (Paris: Development Center of the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, 1992).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Sachs, J., Wages, Profits and Macroeconomic Adjustment: A Comparative Study,Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (2/ 1979), pp. 269332.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Sarel, Michael, Demographic Dynamics and the Empirics of Economic Growth,Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 42 (June 1995), pp. 398410.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Sarel, Michael, Nonlinear Effects of Inflation on Economic Growth,Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 43 (March 1996), pp. 199215.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Savastano, Miguel A., Private Saving in IMF Arrangements,in IMF Conditionality: Experience Under Stand-By and Extended Arrangements, Part II: Back-ground Papers, ed. by Susan Schadler, IMF Occasional Paper No. 129 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, September 1995).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Schadler, Susan, Franek Rozwadowski, Siddharth Tiwari, and David O. Robinson, Economic Adjustment in Low-Income Countries: Experience Under the Enhanced Structural Adjustment Facility, IMF Occasional Paper No. 106 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, September 1993).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Schadler, Susan, Maria Carkovic, Adam Bennett, and Robert Kahn, Recent Experiences with Surges in Capital Inflows, IMF Occasional Paper No. 108 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, December 1993).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Schadler, Susan, Adam Bennett, Maria Carkovic, Louis Dicks-Mireaux, Mauro Mecagni, James H.J. Morsink, and Miguel A. Savastano, IMF Conditionality: Experience Under Stand-By and Extended Arrangements, Part I: Key Issues and Findings, IMF Occasional Paper No. 128 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, September 1995).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Schadler, Susan, ed., IMF Conditionality: Experience Under Stand-By and Extended Arrangements, Part II: Background Papers, IMF Occasional Paper No. 129 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, September 1995).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Schmidt-Hebbel, Klaus and Steven B. Webb, Public Policy and Private Saving,in Adjustment Lending Revisited: Policies to Restore Growth, ed. by Vittorio Corbo, Stanley Fischer, and Steven B. Webb (Washington: World Bank, 1992).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Serven, Luis and Andrés Solimano, eds., Striving for Growth After Adjustment: The Role of Capital Formation, World Bank Regional and Sectoral Studies (Washington: World Bank, 1994).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Tahari, A., J. de Vrijer, and M. Fouad, Senegal, 1978-93,in Adjustment for Growth: The African Experience, International Monetary Fund (forthcoming).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Thomas, Vinod, John D. Nash, and others, Best Practices in Trade Policy Reform (New York: Oxford University Press, 1991).

  • Thomas, Vinod, Ajay Chhibber, M. Dailami, Jaime de Melo, eds., Restructuring Economies in Distress: Policy Reform and the World Bank (New York: Oxford University Press, 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Tinakorn, Pranee and Chalongphob Sussangkarn, Productivity Growth in Thailand” (unpublished; Bangkok: National Economic and Social Development Board and Thailand Development Research Institute, 1994).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Woo, Wing Thye, Bruce Glassburner, and Anwar Nasution, Macroeconomic Policies, Crises, and Long-Term Growth in Indonesia, 1965-90, World Bank Comparative Macroeconomic Studies (Washington: World Bank, 1994).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • World Bank, “Adjustment Lending Policies for Sustainable Growth,Policy and Research Series, No. 14 (Washington: World Bank, 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • World Bank, World Development Report 1991 (New York: Ox-ford University Press, 1991).

  • World Bank, “Adjustment Lending and Mobilization of Private and Public Resources for Growth,Policy and Research Series, No. 22 (Washington: World Bank, 1992).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • World Bank, (1993a), Ghana 2000 and Beyond: Setting the Stage for Accelerated Growth and Poverty Reduction (Washington: World Bank, February 1993).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • World Bank, (1993b), The East Asian Miracle: Economic Growth and Public Policy (New York: Oxford University Press, 1993).

  • World Bank, (1994a), Adjustment in Africa: Reforms, Results, and the Road Ahead (New York: Oxford University Press, 1994).

  • World Bank, (1994b), “Mexico: Country Economic Memorandum—Fostering Private Sector Development in the 1990s,Report No. 11823-ME (Washington: World Bank, May 1994).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • World Bank, (1994c), “Kingdom of Morocco—Preparing for the 21st Century: Strengthening the Private Sector in Morocco,Report No. 11894-MOR (Washington: World Bank, June 1994).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • World Bank, World Development Report 1995 (New York: Ox-ford University Press, 1995).

  • World Bank, Operations Evaluation Department, Trade Reforms Under Adjustment Programs (Washington: World Bank, 1992).

  • World Bank, Operations Evaluation Department, Structural and Sectoral Adjustment: World Bank Experience, 1980-92 (Washington: World Bank, 1995).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation