1 Public Expenditure Management as a Composite Culture
Author:
A. Premchand https://isni.org/isni/0000000404811396 International Monetary Fund

Search for other papers by A. Premchand in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close

Abstract

The last word on how we may live or die

The last word on how we may live or die

Rests today with such quiet

Men, working too hard in rooms that are too big,

Reducing to figures

What is the matter, what is to be done

W. H. AUDEN, The Managers

Expenditure management in government has received substantial additional stimulus in recent years, particularly during the eighties, as a result of the fiscal crises experienced by a number of governments. Although the factors contributing to such fiscal crisis vary from one country to another, two broad trends are discernible. In some, it is the growing disparity between expenditures and revenues and the consequent increase in the fiscal deficit that is generally financed by sources that tend to be inflationary. In others, this trend has been further exacerbated because economic growth was based on heavy public sector spending that in turn was financed by massive external borrowing. In both cases, however, the result, with varying intensity, was a large fiscal deficit and the associated monetary imbalances. These together contributed to an interruption in the flow of external savings (when the level of external debt became unsustainable) and to a collapse of exchange rates. A more detailed analysis of these trends suggests that a vicious circle prevailed during the decade. Fiscal deficits, large external debts, overregulation, and protectionism appear to have contributed to inflation, exchange rate instability, and higher interest rates, which in turn contributed to macroeconomic uncertainty. Such uncertainty led to low investment or stagnation, which then paved the way to larger fiscal deficits, and so on. As an alternative, to break the stranglehold of the vicious circles, virtuous circles were proposed. A key element of the virtuous circle was the strengthening of public finances by mobilizing additional revenues or by containing expenditures or both. This approach, together with strategies aimed at debt reduction and social pacts to moderate the growth rates of wages, was expected to lead to lower inflation, increased confidence, lower interest rates, higher investment, and higher growth.

Public expenditures continued to grow faster than revenues so long as employment in the government sector grew at a faster pace, wages in the public sector were ahead of the rate of inflation, productivity in the public sector was low, subsidies and associated transfers to the household sector were both routine and open-ended, and interest payments were the highest outlays. This awareness contributed to the explicit recognition that a structural change in the economy was needed. A major element of such structural adjustment was the acceptance that macroeconomic stability would be elusive without a major and profound correction in public finances in general, and in expenditures in particular. Such an emphasis also naturally contributed to examining the composition of public expenditures and to reviewing the adequacy of the system of expenditure management in government.1 A consideration of the former aspect is beyond the scope of this book; the focus here is on the latter. But in examining the public expenditure management system, the interaction between the changes in the composition of expenditures and related aspects of management are also considered.

In the review, an attempt is made to consider some of the major questions that are often raised about the nature and approaches of management in government and how they differ from those in the commercial or private sector. In addition, the features that characterize expenditure management in government as well as its components and processes and the guiding principle that is valid for not only the tumultuous times of the previous decade but also more placid times are considered in the following sections.

Comparison of Public and Private Practices

(Lewis 1955) observed succinctly that “nearly everything that governments do private companies have done at some time or other, not excluding providing roads, police, fire services, or arbitration. Indeed, in most of the spheres of public service the pioneering has been done by private entrepreneurs, and governments have come in only at a relatively late stage” (p. 412). Also, “they have, however, everywhere come in to take these services over from private entrepreneurs, since it has everywhere seemed preferable to have the ‘public’ services operated by ‘public’ authorities.” Regardless of the origin of an activity, whether the private or the public sector, several areas are clearly similar, and some are not. Some argue that these differences are narrowing and that the distinction itself may have been exaggerated in some disciplines such as public administration. Gunn (1988) argues, for example, that the view generally held as part of public administration discipline that the two types of activities are fundamentally separate from each other is oversimplistic. But the intent here is not to examine in detail the claims and counterclaims on the existence or otherwise of a great divide between the two sectors, much less to resolve the debate, but to illustrate it in preparation for a more detailed discussion in later sections and chapters of the applicability to the public sector of some private sector practices. This discussion is facilitated by extensive literature in this area.2

The characteristics of modern bureaucracy as envisaged by Weber were common to the state and an enterprise regardless of ownership. He envisaged three characteristics as relevant for an organization: (1) the regular activities are assigned as official duties; (2) the authority to give commands for these duties is distributed in a balanced way; and (3) methodical provision is made for the regular and continuous fulfillment of these duties and for the exercise of corresponding rights. These elements constituted an agency in “the sphere of the State” and a bureaucratic enterprise in “the sphere of the private economy.” Subsequent debate, however, went into greater detail, and several words with different connotations have come into use. Notwithstanding the general impression that such words as public, government, and private are clear, it is prudent to specify them carefully before embarking on an extended discussion of the implications of the practices of each.

An essential first step is to define the terms used in discussion: “public” or “government” are used more often than not synonymously, and so are “private” or “commercial.” “Public” has a specific connotation when used in public finance, where public sector would include general government (central plus regional, state, or local governments), their enterprises, and, sometimes, social security funds. “Government” is somewhat more restrictive; it refers to the state organs and its administrative agencies, and generally excludes enterprises, social security funds, and the numerous quasi-autonomous organizations that are established, funded, and operated by the government but are not included in the government proper. But the definitions in practice vary depending on the purpose and the user. For example, in some practices (as with the Bureau of Labor Statistics in the United States, or the approaches of the Manual on Government Finance Statistics published by the IMF), the postal service is treated as a commercial or private sector activity. Similarly, credit extended to public enterprises is usually shown as part of credit to the private sector in monetary statistics. From an organizational point of view (as already noted from Weber’s approach), the differences between the two may be less clear. In fact Galbraith suggests that many privately owned firms have so much market power and influence on the public that they may no longer be “private.” Weidenbaum also suggests that some corporations are so dependent on government work that they may take on certain attributes of government agencies.3 Indeed, in a number of sectors, government may be the sole consumer of some private companies, which, while adjusting to the interests of their clients, may acquire some of their features. Ownership apart, the two types of organization appear to differ more in specific features than in structural and environmental factors. It is recognized that the principles of modern management POSDCORB (planning, organizing, staffing, directing, coordinating, reporting, and budgeting) have a universal applicability that transcends the natural or artificial barriers between government organizations and private sector organizations.4 This, however, views management as the practice of planning, organizing, leading, and controlling the operations of an agency, organization, or firm so that the best possible results may be obtained in achieving its objectives with the given monetary, material, and manpower resources. (The last two are dependent on the first.) In reality, however, there are differences between private and government agencies.

From a structural point of view, a number of writers5 suggest that public scrutiny and the relative openness of decision making in the public sector create more constraints on the public organization. Primarily because of this, and in comparison with private sector organizations, policy directives tend to be broad, frequently ill-defined, and contradictory, thereby restricting the public administrator. The organizations may not be given a proper charter and may have excessively fragmented responsibilities. Their time horizons tend to be shorter; policy coalitions are less stable and are usually not sustained during the implementation stage. The high level of unionization, difficulty of withdrawal, lack of specificity in organizational performance, and absence of incentives for effective performance have their own impact on the organizational processes and functioning.

From an environmental point of view, excessive political influence, uncertainty about the roles of civil servants, ministers, and their relationships, the need for fairness, responsiveness, accountability, and honesty, and numerous legal and formal constraints (in particular, judicial) add additional dimensions to a public organization relative to those of a private organization. If, as argued by one strand of management theory, the creation of a proper working climate6 enhances productivity in that organization, then a public organization is susceptible to a greater variety of influences than a private organization. Unlike the private sector with an identified stakeholder, politicians, taxpayers, voters, and expenditure beneficiary groups in the public sector constitute a wider group of stakeholders. In addition, there is the frequent problem of identifying also the customer in the public sector, and of determining which specific issue will assume what practical or political importance in a constantly changing environment. For the private sector, there is a bottom-line appraisal in terms of profit, market performance, and survival. Consequently, its strategic management is aimed at serving these goals. In the public sector, there is often a conflict between the objective and its feasibility on the one hand, and the need for accountability on the other. As a result, strategic management has been more evident in terms of limits on inputs (manpower, etc.) than in what needs to be accomplished.

Although the unique features of the public organization therefore need to be taken into account in designing systems and techniques, economists did not pay much attention to many of these crucial aspects until recently. As Wicksell noted at the turn of the century, much of fiscal theory implicitly assumes that society is ruled by a benevolent despot.7 Even a benevolent despot cannot afford to neglect the contribution of organization to his effort. Allocative efficiency—the key ingredient of public expenditure management—cannot in practice be achieved on the familiar notion of economic rationality. Decision makers are rational, it is held, and individuals are the best judges of their own welfare. But individual choice may not necessarily reflect collective choice, as voters may often have an incentive to misrepresent their true preferences. Indeed, no voting scheme (as shown in Arrow’s “impossibility” theorem) yet permits a perfect aggregation of individual preferences into the will of the people. More recent forays into these aspects by the public choice theory suggest that welfare economics had by and large not analyzed the full implications of the political process. To them, bureaucrats are maximizers of their own objective function, and therefore there is little to sustain the dictum that governments will improve the allocative efficiency of markets through policy interventions. These aspects, it is contended, contribute to bureaucratic failure. To avoid this failure, public choice theory offers a fiscal constitution that sets limits on spending and on tax rates. Any constitution, however, requires an organization to sustain it. Public choice theory has so far addressed only a few of the aspects that are dealt with by public organizations, particularly in areas of the design of contract and incentive structures.

The debate on the need for the public organization to learn from the private sector continues to build, because of the problems associated with bureaucratic failure and the urgent need to reduce them. Some contend that the problems of the public organization are inherent in the situation as reflected in the “democracy is messy” argument.8 Drucker argues, reflecting some of the features of public organizations described earlier, that the lofty objectives, attempting to do too many things at the same time, the debatable belief that large organizations achieve their goals because of their size, and the inability both to abandon programs that are no longer useful and to learn from experience accentuate the failure. It could be argued, on the other hand, that human failures occur in all types of organizations and because of particular situations rather than because of the design of the institution.

Specifically, in the area of public expenditures, auditors have frequently pointed out the problems of failures in the “oldest and newest social institution”—government. For example, Bourn (1989), reviewing the experience of the United Kingdom, points out that most common problems were in the areas of asset management, application of commercial insights, project management, monitoring and control, provision of services to clients, and observance of management standards. Similarly, Naderx (1988) argues that government has to follow the practices of corporations, liberate its mind from bureaucracy-induced inhibitions, develop strategic planning over a longer time horizon, manage its assets properly, and transform itself into a “citizen-driven government.”

All the above approaches have some validity on an abstract level. On a more specific level, it is the organization—its processes, systems, techniques, and operational procedures—that will have to strive to internalize all the constraints that form an integral part of the features of a government. As Wilson (1989) noted, “the key difference between more and less successful bureaucracies… has less to do with finances, client populations, or legal arrangements than with organizational systems” (p. 23; emphasis added).

Governance and Transparency

These concepts, which have over the years framed the discourse on financial management in government, have once again begun to dominate public debate during the last two years. The renewal of this debate may even imply that the normal presumptions associated with public accountability have not been fulfilled. Such nonfulfillment may however be relative in that public expectations have increased and have not been affected by corresponding public scrutiny, or it may be that accountability has been less than it was. The debate may have revived for several reasons. The customary care that a state is expected to provide to its citizens has not materialized. In personal life, each individual saves money and builds up related assets not merely for himself but for his progeny and future generations. Indeed, the main goal for many householders, after middle life, is to gather adequate resources for their offspring so that they can have a more secure future than their parents enjoyed. Similarly, a state should take an intertemporal view and build up security for future generations. In a context where governments are substantially indebted, the physical assets left for future generations are in disrepair and require massive investment to be restored to full operation, the cumulative environmental pollution threatens to reduce life spans despite medical progress, and families find that the value of their savings is eroded by the imprudent, inflationary financing policies followed by governments, this expectation has not materialized. The lack of a legal framework conducive to economic development, the existence of too many procedural layers and regulations that tend to promote rent-seeking behavior among civil servants, the lack of consistency in policies, and the inability to identify priorities and implement them have all raised doubts about governance.

These terms have several connotations, however, and it is appropriate therefore to define and distinguish them so that their influence on public expenditure management can be assessed.

Definitions and Distinctions

Governance, like obscenity, is difficult to define as a legal phrase. The lack of it seems to be more easily felt than governance itself. Although that may sometimes be a virtue, the term refers very broadly to the use of political and economic authority on behalf of and over a society on the management of resources for such purposes as are deemed appropriate by that society. The choice of such purposes or the goals of that society are prerogatives vested in the society itself, as is the choice of institutions and systems used as instruments to achieve those goals. Governance implicitly guarantees the civil and human rights needed for effective participation and the information flows that enable the members of society to make their choices. In this broad perspective, however, it has several dimensions, which, although important, are not a part of the focus of discussion here. From the more limited perspective of public expenditure management, the three components of governance are rule of law, transparency or openness, and accountability.

The rule of law (regardless of its form and philosophical orientation) implies the existence and operation of a system based on rules, approved by appropriate authority, and generally justifiable in a court of law. Such a system presupposes that the set of laws governing the conduct of expenditure management is known in advance both to those administering the rules and to those administered, that the rules are applied in practice objectively, and that adequate mechanisms exist to resolve conflicts. Specifically for expenditure management, as explained in detail in Chapter 2, such laws have been codified as part of either common or civil law and have been available for a number of years. Thus, if the existence of rules were the only criterion for judging the adequacy of governance, it might be safe to say that that condition is fulfilled. But this fulfillment does not necessarily imply that governance is complete.

Two major limitations need to be considered here. First, not every aspect of a government’s working can be codified precisely or unequivocally. The work of government is so dynamic that in numerous ways laws lag behind events. Thus, laws are being made tentatively to react to changes in the economy and the responses thereto. The second limitation is the extent of the codification and the interpretation of law. Experience of expenditure management over the years illustrates that excessive codification makes every manager a robot—with little flexibility of his own. The administration of law takes precedence over the administration of policy. Although no policy that is prima facie illegal should be implemented, in practice a number of gray areas require specification. Associated with this is the interpretation of law. Experience in the United States and elsewhere suggests that as laws of equity and allocation of resources are interpreted by courts of law, expenditure management takes a backseat because of the necessary obligation of the law. But as most of the interpretation of law is at a nascent stage, the verdict of one court becomes the subject of review of another.9 This also suggests the possibility of a conflict between those responsible for expenditure management and those responsible for interpretation of the law. Thus, an area of concern still to be resolved in any discussion of governance is not the need for or the form of it but the practical experience of expenditure management in a legally circumscribed framework.

Transparency or openness is a characteristic of governance. It refers to the availability of information to the public on the transactions of the government and the transparency of decision-making processes. Two interrelated issues are inherent in this phenomenon. One is the nature of information and the other is the use of that information; the latter is largely dependent on the former. The general experience with the first is that much information is provided to the public and the legislature. Thus, in addition to the voluminous budget documents (except for the centrally planned economies), periodic information is published on the status of public finances, and the submission of completed accounts, (with varying lags) at the close of the fiscal year, completes the cycle. The issue, however, is not the amount, but the content and form of the information. It seems that the information is arranged not to be transparent but to draw a veil over it. Although this tendency is by no means new,10 the feeling is growing that the language used is clear only to those professionally engaged in financial management, with one expert communicating with another. It is even suggested that when voters exercise their franchise they do not necessarily do so on an objective assessment of the pros and cons of government programs. More often, they may be influenced by image, anecdote, metaphor, or even a bit of engineered ignorance11 (the result of deliberate deception by political groups). Moreover, even when information is available and clear, members of the community may prefer not to “voice” their grievances and may prefer not to “exit” because of uncertainty about alternatives. The argument of a “free rider” is also relevant, as the cost of exercising the franchise may be higher than any benefits that the voter is receiving. Thus, a voter may take comfort in what he has rather than face the ordeal of either changing it or searching for an alternative. The virtue of a democratic form of government consists in enabling a free flow of information so that appropriate choices, if desired, can be made.

As discussed in the section on public and private sector practices, the characteristics of the former are that they have to work in a framework of legal and formal constraints and under the presumed constant glare of public scrutiny and the associated public expectations of fairness, responsiveness, and honesty. Accountability is a shorthand expression for these expectations and in general refers to the mechanisms by which decision makers are held responsible for performance by those affected by their decisions. The demand for such accountability appears to increase as fiscal problems persist, as discussed earlier. Indeed the demand for panaceas and instant solutions is growing. It has to be recognized, however, that each budget (assuming that it includes all the financial transactions of the government) is in itself an expression of approved, and to a very large extent, continuing policies. The policies reflected in the budget may therefore have been in effect for some time and the budget estimates merely reflect them. If accountability had been complete or productive, some of the problems associated with fiscal crisis may not have arisen. On the other hand, because policies were approved and made accountable, the final result should have been a foregone conclusion.

Accountability, however, although simple in intent, is complex and is envisioned differently at different levels. Here, three approaches are relevant. First, a democracy may not always be successful in making the right choices and formulating the right policies or in rejecting the palpably wrong ones. In such a context, accountability should really be concerned with exploring three aspects: What criteria should govern expenditure choices? What type of procedure would be appropriate to facilitate those choices? What kind of information would be needed?12

Determining social choices has never been easy. Despite enormous scholarly work, there are still no conclusive answers about reconciling individual values with collective desires and decisions. The Pareto criterion, which is one of the icons of economics, deals with improvements (or incremental efficiency) in a community that is already considered just. The more recent public choice theory, however, contends (as noted earlier) that frequently there is collusion between the predatory self-interests of administrators and politicians and that the best means of breaking this hold on expenditure decision making is to promote a constitutional order that ensures a balanced budget. Expenditure choices are not restricted only to the overall balance, but extend to, and indeed may be primarily concerned with, the balance in the composition of expenditures. The issue then is the procedure appropriate for reflecting society’s choices in selecting programs. In principle, it can be argued that such a choice is made by the elected representatives, or by the civil servants in a framework of delegated authority. But the expression of the people may be less specific, leaving considerable flexibility to the administrators. Moreover, the representative who is expected to exercise his options reflecting the needs of the people has to combine in himself two functions—a representative of people—and a trustee of the nation’s interests. Reconciliation of these two aspects has not yet been accomplished, thereby leading to a muddling through approach. Moreover, because the normal increment in a budget is rather small, what discretion can be expected from the legislator, or his proxy, the administrator? Implied acceptance of the continuing programs provides them with a degree of legitimacy, and in due course the stamp of approval. Also, in dealing with new proposals for expenditure that accord with the wishes of the people represented, a balance has to be struck with the overall stability of the country, which requires a more judicious approach in exercising the trusteeship role.

The information aspect aims at ensuring that the choices are made with full knowledge of the facts available (that may and indeed often differ from the “full” facts) and that the decisions taken can be easily ascertained by the public. In short, it refers to the transparency aspect discussed above. Although all the three issues raised may at first seem formidable, choices are made regularly and benefits are provided from the public moneys. The patterns of expenditure management machinery (discussed in the following section and in Chapter 2) reflect these aspects.

Another approach to accountability has been to test the feasibility of “exit” and “voice” in dealing with the services to be provided by the government. In a free market, an individual has the right to exercise his preference for one product over another, or to articulate his preferences so that the provider of the product can moderate or adjust it to conform with the consumer’s preferences. An extension of this approach suggests that a citizen should similarly have an opportunity to express his view either through an exit or through his voice. This exercise would not apply to pure public goods like national defense but would be restricted to other goods and services that are marketable. In that context, and if the government is not a monopoly provider of the goods and services, exit by the buyers who then seek an alternative source of supply would adversely affect the working of the government. The final test of accountability in this situation is the market failure of a nonmarket organization. Alternatively, if the service provided is not utilized because of lack of consumer orientation, the government would normally be obliged to amend its product or service. The voice then can be both a market response mechanism as well as a political response mechanism. The second approach becomes more important in dealing with pure public goods as the normal market tests would not be applicable.

A third and more practical approach to accountability is to view it as an expression of hierarchical control. Such control may be viewed on various levels—between the legislature and government; between ministers and the civil service; between central agencies and spending agencies; and between departments and their subordinate bureaus or offices. Accountable management implies that individuals and organizations are responsible for specified levels of performance. This relationship between, for example, the legislature and the executive, is illustrated in Figure 1. But restricting accountability to the final performance, however specific and detailed, would be narrow and would not provide satisfactory answers to the issues of criteria of spending, procedure for making choices, and adequacy of information. Thus, accountability will have to be broader and cover all the aspects of the expenditure management cycle. The components of such accountability are illustrated in Table 1.

The existence of the institutions or the systems does not necessarily ensure accountability. Governance, transparency, and accountability are not absolutes but are relative to the demands made on the expenditure management machinery. As these demands vary, so also does accountability from time to time and relative to those demands. In practice, however, several factors appear to narrow fulfillment of accountability in the current situation. In a number of countries, the budgets represent only a portion of the public transactions. Policies are pursued through a range of enterprises, quasi-fiscal accounts, and other instruments. These aspects also have to be made accountable. However, where budgets are approved by the legislature after little consideration, or where completed accounts are not submitted, and when submitted, are not considered by the legislature, accountability is likely to remain a hollow shell. The effectiveness of accountability in the end depends on the willingness of the public to use the instruments available, on the adequacy of hierarchical controls, and on the openness of society and its ability to display its strengths and deal with its sores and bruises with determination.

Figure 1.
Figure 1.

Accountability Relationship

Table 1.

Accountability Framework

article image

Expenditure Management

Expenditure management systems have evolved over the years, reflecting the increasing tasks of the government, and, as a consequence, its budget. In the early stages, the budget was treated as a financial plan that emphasized the mechanisms of payment, accounting, and reporting. Later, the economic implications of the budget were recognized, and the budget itself came to be perceived as a major instrument of economic planning and macroeconomic stabilization and growth. More recently, and as illustrated in Table 1, the budget has come to be viewed, inter alia, as a comprehensive exercise in resource allocation and management with emphasis on relating costs to performance.

The expenditure management system therefore recognizes, in the current setting, the resource constraint in the various stages of governmental decision making, from the determination of the total magnitude to the allocation and management of expenditures. Here, expenditure management is viewed as a composite process contributing to timely and effective decision making on the use of public money. The operational framework of expenditure management comprises a three-stage administrative process: (1) determination of the policies and objectives and the resources needed to attain them; (2) allocation of resources needed to attain the objectives; and (3) assurance that specific tasks are carried out economically, efficiently, and effectively. In practical terms, these correspond to formulating a fiscal plan (thinking process), formulating a budget (operational legal framework), and implementing a budget (doing process). These three phases can also be examined in terms of resource allocation planning, resource use management, and information systems.

Resource allocation planning involves a reasonable assessment of prospective receipts and the costs associated with raising receipts, and an explicit recognition of the linkages between government budgets and the economy. It includes setting priorities and policy goals, with adjustments for allocating resources to continuing and new services and formulating contingency plans to accommodate unexpected changes. This process is, however, far more complex than may at first appear.

Traditionally, there has been a good deal of debate about policy and objectives.13 “Policy” is used here as a term to describe a set of interrelated and consistent objectives, plans, and decision rules. The organizational responsibility for specifying such policy is a different matter; it can be interpreted as the collective responsibility of the whole government, or, at a more disaggregated level, as the responsibility of specific agencies such as finance or planning. The first task is to assess the macroeconomic framework. Such an assessment facilitates the specification of objectives relating to stabilization, growth, and, as integral parts thereof, of balance of payments, domestic and external credit, level of employment, and other factors. The macroeconomic framework permits an evaluation of the continuous interrelationship between the macroeconomic model and the aggregate as well as the components of expenditure. The determination of aggregate expenditure (and for this purpose, it should include all expenditures, whether formally included in the budget or organized outside it) in turn depends in practice on the present commitments to relevant ongoing activities and the threshold needed to accommodate policy decisions already made, or those likely to be made. Within those present commitments, the programs where stepped-up activity is indicated and the costs thereof should be considered. These programs, in turn, are assessed in terms of the economics and politics of the aggregate revenue and expenditure balance, the constraints of the commitments already made and the resources available, and the trade-offs among them. As an integral part of this assessment, the status of public investment plans (where such plans are in operation) is also evaluated.

A more detailed review of the programs and their components is then made. The various steps involved in this review can be stated in terms of the following general principles (some of which have been adapted from Lewis (1988)).

  • All expenditures should be formulated in terms of program packages.

  • Every program package should be supported by cost estimates.

  • Cost estimates should be built in terms of objects of expenditure—wages and salaries, equipment, etc.

  • Control of spending could be in terms of both programs and objects and should not, in large organizations, be highly centralized.

  • Programs should be supported by data on productivity indices, unit costs, and other indicators of efficiency if such data are relevant.

  • Programs should be evaluated in terms of costs and benefits before being undertaken.

  • Such evaluation should include analysis of political, social, legal, and administrative issues.

  • Program objectives should be expressed in terms of outputs and anticipated benefits.

  • Program packages should also specify the organizational responsibilities.

  • Special aggregation of programs crossing organizational lines may be made for analytic purposes without disturbing structures aligned with organizational responsibilities.

  • Before preparing detailed budget estimates, executives should provide policy guidance on the objectives to be achieved in that year; set specific target amounts deemed reasonable for programs rather than arbitrary percentages of the budgets; allow agencies to formulate second-priority programs if initial estimates are higher than targets; and request studies to be made in special cases before final decisions are made.

  • Coordination between revenues and expenditures should be continuous so that the changes in the former and their impact on the latter can be identified.

  • Expenditure plans should generally include contingency provision for unforeseen events.

  • The above principles should also be adhered to in reallocating funds during the resource utilization phase.

The principles—which cover the theoretical and practical developments in the art of budgeting and management during the last three decades—are considered generally applicable to public authorities. Their actual application, however, is different, and several problem areas exist, as discussed below. These problems result not from any built-in inadequacies of the principles but from the interaction between systems, individuals, and events.

Resource use management involves applying three principles—propriety, accountability, and adequacy of the systems for the delivery of services. Propriety, as indicated in Table 1, refers to the application of funds for the purposes approved by the legislature. During this phase, the process controls or accounting controls have full play in that through various instruments, releases, commitments, payments, and use of acquired goods and services, the flows of money are controlled. These controls, in turn, may be operating within a management environment that specifies the role of audit and the observance of credit ceilings, if any.

Accountability, as noted earlier, refers to the implementation of policy prudently and transparently; adequacy refers to the capacity to produce results commensurate with outlays. During these phases, different types of controls aimed at achieving efficiency may also be deployed.

Information systems involve the production of data for use by decision makers inside government and to an extent outside government. Such information needs to be consistent and comparable over time and should facilitate the matching of income, output, and cost of services to the specified time frame.

These three phases of expenditure management summarized in Chart 1 should be considered part of an overall composite culture in which each phase leads to another to facilitate the implementation of approved fiscal policies. Each phase has its own terms of reference, which are rendered meaningful not in an independent or isolated fashion but only as a composite culture. The phases may be operated by people drawn from professional cultures; thus, resource allocation planning may be dominated by economists or budgeteers, and resource use and information systems by accountants and efficiency experts, reflecting the considerations that come into play at each stage. The fulfillment of the policy goals depends on the continuity shown in the transition from one stage to another.

The overall expenditure management system, judged by the results, reveals a number of problem areas. Although the areas as well as the magnitude of the problems vary from one country to another, there is little congruence between fiscal plan, formulated budget, and implementation of the budget. In each phase aims are pursued that are independent of the strategy underlying formulation of the fiscal plan. Because a resort to expediency is often convenient from a political viewpoint, the budget formulated differs from the fiscal plan, and, in implementation, what is implemented tends to differ from the fiscal plan and the budget. In reality, there appear to be three budgets, each with a different purpose. The first is a commitment budget, where commitment refers to the political promises made to introduce a program here and to undertake a project there, and not to the placing of an order to deliver goods and services for which payment may be made later. Such programs and projects, which are promised in the day-to-day life of a government, transcend the self-imposed parameters of a formal development plan and are more like lists to be accommodated either in the ongoing or in one of the future budgets. The existence of such an informal budget constitutes a powerful influence on the formulation of the regular or legally approved annual budget. In addition, it may also have a powerful announcement impact.

Chart 1.
Chart 1.

Public Expenditure Management Resource Allocation Planning

This commitment budget is followed by a budget for the year, which is a statement of proposed policies and the associated financing, intended for discussion and approval by the legislature. It is a framework based on assumptions and scenarios about the additional mobilization of resources and the foreign aid (which is substantial in several countries) to be received. Once the fiscal year starts, however, the scenarios underlying the budget may have been too rosy, and the expenditure reductions (indicated more in the form of asterisks or footnotes, particularly when the proposals are highly tentative) less than feasible. At that stage, a cash-based budget emerges, in which the predominant consideration is to achieve some congruence between inflows and outflows of cash. This congruence is achieved by limiting payments so that specified credit policies can be observed. Such a cash or disbursement-oriented budget can be, and often is, at variance with both the fiscal plan and the legal budget. The existence of these three types of budgets largely represents the absence of a coherent expenditure management strategy. Also, the quality and content of economic forecasting and the manner in which economic uncertainty is internalized are less than desirable. Moreover, more precise identification and measurement of the budget deficit and its impact are also necessary. In most cases, the budgetary outcomes differ from the amounts planned because of the allocations to approved expenditure programs that prove to be unsustainable during the year. Higher-than-estimated outlays on debt, subsidies, and entitlements seem to have become routine. Development projects show considerable cost escalation.

An analysis of the budgetary outcome shows that it is different not only because of the volume-price relationships but also because of the introduction of new policies and projects with little consideration for their resource requirements. When the impact of these initiatives is recognized, and to achieve a semblance of adherence to intended budgetary ceilings, payments are controlled. Such approaches appear to lead to the buildup of arrears and unpresented checks. More important, the resource use phase reveals that the instruments chosen could not anticipate contingent liabilities. Further, as centralization of payments was frequently utilized to avoid possible misuse of funds, an avoidable increase in transaction costs arose. This phase also reveals the futility of accounting controls when the leakage was primarily from the policy formulation phase. Where spending overruns represent a rebound in spending compressed during early periods or commitments that are far in excess of available resources, payment restrictions, instead of appropriate policy changes, are unlikely to prove rewarding. Moreover, the considerable lags in the collection of data on payments to and by governments have also obstructed the pursuit of appropriate economic policies. Experience also shows that any failure, however small, in implementing expenditure programs introduces distortions into the economy. Although not all the above areas are the results of a system or a technique, the absence of a strategy to use the composite culture may also have contributed to the plethora of problems.

Control Framework

To state that control is to expenditure management what oxygen is to the human body is to understate its importance. Over the years, control has been a paradox in that it appeared to be known and verifiable in one form or another, yet very little was known about some aspects of it. To use a churchillian expression, it was for many, “an enigma wrapped in mystery.” The language used to describe controls may also have exacerbated the situation: for example, “accounting controls,” “administrative controls,” “management controls,” “program controls,” and “budget controls.” Are they different categories? Are they substitutable? Which type of controls does what? These are only some of the many issues that arise in comprehending and analyzing controls.

Control is by no means new and indeed is as old as statecraft. Early attention was paid to organizing the state treasury. Thus, more than two millennia ago, Book of the Rites of Zhou (China), a manual describing the tasks or the functions, explained the responsibilities of officials in managing finance:

Waifu were in charge of receiving and paying money; Sihui supervised revenue and expenditures; Sishu kept records of the amount of land, number of residents, and spending; Zhinei were in charge of revenue, Zhishui supervised expenditures and Zhibi managed surplus money handled by departments and units.... Any expenditure was to be reported to one of them....14

After that, Sihui checked them out and kept the accounts. The control function was then a twofold exercise—verifying the transaction and ascertaining the authority that enabled the expenditure to be undertaken. These functions were undertaken by a single agency—whether it was part of the royal office or part of the treasury that came to be organized later as a separate agency under royal supervision. Thus, until recently, control was conceived essentially in “singular” terms reflecting the control exercised by the treasury or later the ministries of finance. Control also meant verification—a connotation that persists in some European management systems. Later, however, it acquired another dimension—as a constant oversight on appropriations—obtaining and spending funds—and came to be viewed as consisting of line-item control of those appropriations.15

Control is not singular, and used in the plural, controls represent rational systems designed to enhance the performance of organizations and, specifically in regard to expenditure management, are processes that enable the specification of objectives, the allocation of resources, and the economic, efficient, and effective utilization of resources while pursuing the objective of stability. These functions are to be performed in an accountable manner. Control also has another dimension—as an expression of power and of hierarchical relationships in an organization. Consideration of both these aspects provides an overview that in turn helps to identify problem areas.

Management Process

Control should be viewed as a network in which at various times and administrative processes several techniques are used to ascertain that government transactions are undertaken in pursuit of a coherent strategy or objective. Thus, in its broad contours, and following Anthony’s (1965 and 1988) approach, the control process, as illustrated in Chart 2, may consist of strategic planning, management control, and operational control. The first phase refers to the formulation of objectives and corporate plans, the second to the process by which resources are obtained and policies determined governing the use of those resources, and the last to the process of ensuring that the tasks are carried out as intended. In all these phases, two elements are mixed in varying proportions to achieve the desired objectives: planning and control. Planning is specific and narrow in that it requires either an organization or a chief executive, or in government, an agency head, who is viewed here as the decision maker or policymaker. In strategic planning, the focus is on determining the issue, how it can be addressed, the consequences of each approach, and the feasibility of each assessed in terms of the implementation capacity of the organization. Control, on the other hand, refers to the implementation of the decisions arrived at in the preceding stage, where each objective and related assignment is divided into manageable parts. The task of planning implementation remains, however. Thus, progressively, as the implementation stage is reached, there will be a preponderance of control to ensure compliance of specified tasks. Control varies from one stage to another.

Chart 2.
Chart 2.

Expenditure Management Cycle

Controls in an agency can be external and internal. External controls represent those exercised outside the agency. Specifically, in expenditure management, they may be exercised by the legislature, central agencies, the president’s office, the central bank, or others. (Legislative controls are not considered here.) Internal controls represent those that are part of the organizational structure of the agency itself and thus amenable to its decisions and discretion. Both these types of controls are illustrated in Chart 3. The external controls, depending on the organizational legacy and culture of the country concerned, can be vast and cover practically every aspect of public expenditure management. They may no longer be considered homogeneous, except that they have the same underlying themes of economy, efficiency, effectiveness, and stabilization; they are heterogeneous, as the focus differs from one stage to another. Controls so exercised by external agencies tend to have government-wide applicability and may therefore be considered macro controls, but they have to be supplemented by the micro or operational controls exercised by the agency itself. Both types of controls complement each other and have a symbiotic relationship. Thus, neither is meaningful or effective without the sustenance of the other.

The external controls start with the determination of macroeconomic policies and of the permissible magnitudes of expenditures and their various components and deficits. These global targets are translated into expenditure plans through an iterative process that results in budgets that, in turn, provide the needed legal and administrative authority for the annual cycle. In addition, central agencies also have the powers to exercise several regulatory functions. They specify the regulations governing internal accounting systems, earmarked funds, expenditure norms and standards, and the types, forms, and timing of reporting. Further, depending on the tradition of administration, certain payment functions may be centralized and performed directly by the central agencies. Where such payments are centralized, the tasks of the agencies are restricted to processing relevant documentation. These controls, which are structured and have recognized places in the process, are supplemented (when warranted) by ad hoc controls (so considered because they have a defined period of life), which on occasion even supersede the regular controls. Thus, macro controls may even become micro controls when the number of personnel to be hired or terminated, the amount of travel, the acquisition of assets, and payments become subject to quantitative restrictions. Concluding the cycle is the evaluation of completed programs and projects undertaken by central agencies.

Chart 3.
Chart 3.

External and Internal Control Framework of an Agency

Ideally internal controls are the operational controls that supplement the macroeconomic strategy outlined by the central agencies. Thus agencies are typically required to undertake their own strategic thinking concerning their sector of operations and to prepare relevant budgets. Relative to the bureaus and other organizations under its own control, the agency and its top echelon would be engaged in strategic planning, with the difference between the central and other agencies being that the former is concerned with the whole economy and the latter with a sector in the economy or a part thereof. Once the expenditure plans are formulated and approved, however, the focus of the agency turns to management and operational control phases. Thus, the agency will be concerned with personnel management (a constant in any administration) as well as with the management of specific areas that are unique to it and therefore have to be determined by it. These areas may relate to the activities of enterprises under its control or to determining the grant and loan proportion of its transfers to other agencies. This is preceded by determining those expenditures to be incurred by the agency itself and those transferred to other agencies and that are therefore under their control. Controls exercised in regard to bidding and contracting (features applicable to procurement, construction, and contracting out are considered in Chapter 8) are different, because the regulations are specified by the central agencies for uniform application but are ensured by the agencies. Next are controls in regard to payments where the primary consideration is to verify accuracy and requisite authority and the safe custody of public moneys. If payrolls are centralized, however, they may be administered by the central agencies on behalf of the entire government. As an associated aspect, contingent liability management may be undertaken either centrally or by the agencies. Where it is a responsibility of the agencies, the contingent liabilities may be consolidated by the central agencies. The agencies are also responsible for maintaining the assets and liabilities under their management. They also undertake evaluations of programs and projects, but the framework of evaluation is specified by the central agencies.

The central agencies are thus broadly responsible for stabilization by ensuring that the aggregate level of expenditure is appropriate and that the allocations to sectors and programs are balanced. The agencies are responsible for achieving economy, efficiency, and effectiveness in the implementation of programs.

Nature of Controls

The smooth functioning of expenditure management depends substantially on the nature of the control exercised. Organizational specialists and literary writers have written extensively over the years about control. It is generally associated with the exercise of power either legally vested in an agency or alternatively claimed as part of tradition. Without that presumed power, controls may vary in their effectiveness. History shows that the same control technique can have a vastly different impact when deployed by strong or by weak rulers. Power in turn is drawn from two essentials—motive and resources. In an organizational setup, the legal and explicit motive is drawn from the assignment of a specific responsibility to that agency. If such assignment is backed by the power to manage resources—allocation and utilization—that would truly forge a citadel of power, thereby enforcing its own approach. As Weber (1978) observed, “Power is the probability that one actor within a social relationship will be in a position to carry out his own will despite resistance, regardless of the basis on which this probability rests” (p. 152). Canetti (1981), however, makes a distinction between power and force—the former operating in a wider space and less dynamic, while the latter is close and immediate in its effect. For Canetti, the exercise of power and force implies a breakdown in the social relationship. He observed that “the man-made distinction between those who give orders and those who have to obey them implies that they have no common language between them” (p. 294). Reflecting on the exercise of power in a unilateral organization, he added, “the most characteristic thing about a soldier is that he lives in a permanent state of expectation of commands, which is expressed in his bearing and his very shape” (p. 315).

But power is not unidimensional. It can be formal, specific, and organized. It can also be informal, subtle, ubiquitous, and multifarious. In either case, however, it has a core or central value—a purpose or an objective that specifies the generation or achievement of some intended effects. Without that core value, power tends to be personal and vindictive; with it, it becomes a legitimate authority. In abstract, however, those who are bestowed with this authority may recognize core value only if it is necessary to achieve their own goals. But in reality in an organization—despite the obvious need for leadership—prima donnas alone cannot deliver the services expected. Rather, the success of the organization is dependent on coalescing the different interests and making them into a coherent whole. Such coherence is affected by the vitality shown in the exercise of power and in recognizing the controllee’s own needs.

The exercise of power, even when backed fully by motive and resources, may take more than one form. It can, for example, be in the form of a command—a form that is deep-rooted in every society and in every walk of life. Such commands, however, have obvious limitations, for they change, to borrow Canetti’s words, the very bearing and shape of both the controller and the controllee.16 In expenditure management, as experience illustrates, such power has contributed to centralizing financial power in the treasury, which was then expected to keep a “ceaseless vigil over the buccaneering proclivities” of the spending agencies. But this has not been found appropriate for a growing organization that in turn needed policy and financial considerations to be integrated at an agency level. Over the years, therefore, command power had to move away from threats (sticks) to inducements (carrots) or a combination thereof. A variant of this combination is the technique of concertation, which involves the exercise of power and control in consultation with the agencies. Yet another variant is “cooptive power,” which is a soft version of power and consists of persuading others to accept the ideas, objectives, and related organizational agenda.

Control, which is a manifestation of power, depends on the pursuit of an agenda and of making others accept that agenda, through a command, or an incentive, or through cooptive power approaches. Organizationally, then, control becomes the vehicle for the translation of a strategy to assure that the desired results are obtained. Control is also seen, as discussed in Chapter 4, as a network of contracts between agencies in a government.

In government, the power and related control are not absolutes. No single agency has a monopoly on the subject assigned to it. Although policies may be set by that agency, resources have to be allocated by others, procurement and contracting carried out by specified agencies and subject to a variety of restrictions stemming from the exercise of powers and functions assigned to other agencies. Thus, power is shared—and in some cases it can be structurally centralized or decentralized or centralized during some periods of economic upheaval or similar developments.

Expenditure Controls

To illustrate how external and internal controls are exercised, they are reclassified in terms of functional categories depending on the purposes to be served. Thus they may be divided into policy controls (formulation of macroeconomic policies and agency strategies), process controls (personnel, procurement, construction, and payment controls), and efficiency controls (measurement of performance and evaluation). These three groups are then examined by relating them to the type of controls—command, cooptive, and incentive; the results are illustrated in Table 2.

Policy controls, which relate to the formulation of government-wide macroeconomic strategies and related global targets, tend to be primarily the responsibility of the central agencies. Although, as noted earlier, policy formulation is an iterative process, influencing the final outcome depends on the role of the central agencies. Where the resource ceilings are specified by the central agencies, policy controls tend to become commands, as they cannot be unilaterally altered by the agencies. But, if there is broad communication about resources and transparency about how the estimates were reached, they can also be the results of a cooptive approach.

Table 2.

Exercise of Controls

article image

Process controls refer to the fulfillment of legal obligations. Laws or related regulations have to be observed in regard to personnel, procurement, and construction, as well as payments. In addition, in some cases, payments may be centralized. In both cases, the exercise of the controls will be viewed as centrally determined or centrally regulated.

Specification of efficiency standards is largely viewed as an exercise in cooptive power as these standards are jointly determined by the central and the spending agencies. Further, to ensure compliance, agencies may also be given incentives. But such incentives will be centrally determined to ensure uniform application. The framework of controls is largely dominated, therefore, by the central agencies, as they are responsible for policy and for specifying methods to achieve it and for regulating the expenditure management activities of the agencies. This exercise is not unilateral, however, for central and spending agencies participate jointly in every aspect.

Exercise of these controls has given rise to several issues. It is generally noted that the intervention of the central agencies is intrusive and therefore counterproductive, that the structures tend to promote dysfunctional behavior, and that the rules devised are inefficient. At issue also is why some of the less useful practices have persisted over time. Some of these aspects are considered in more detail in the following chapters. Three major criticisms of the structures and systems of control are considered here.

First, most of the controls and activities of the central and spending agencies seem to operate in a reactive, rather than a proactive, mode, occupied by crisis or other short-term agendas, and with little or no focus on policy and strategy over the medium and long term. Basically, this condition is attributable to the way governments view problems and issues and make expenditure and related management decisions. As one futurologist noted, “we know in our hearts that we are in the world for keeps, yet we are still tackling 20-year problems with 5-year plans, staffed by 2-year personnel working with 1-year appropriations. It is simply not good enough.” This reactive mode has contributed to specified intervention, unspecified interference, and even to the centralization of some tasks. The lack of clarity at the helm is compensated by interference whenever the situation warrants.

Second, the structure is dominated by process controls that tend to be deterrent, and they are not matched by positive controls that also have a degree of “compellence,” to use Schelling’s phrase. As David Hume noted a long time ago, “balance is a constant rule of prudent politics.” It is also a prudent rule applicable to organizations. But balance is difficult to apply, because more than anything else it is a matter of perception. When intrusion replaces policy guidance, such perceptions about the lack of balance become stronger and tend to become obsessions. More important, process controls can hardly compensate for the absence of policies.

Third, the controls exercised have obvious limitations. For state purposes, specified rules are not applied to some expenditures. Some policies that are determined politically are exempt from controls, as are expenditures for security. Obvious attempts at circumvention and prominent leakages such as accumulation of payment arrears and ghost employees tend to undermine confidence in the system. It is difficult, however, to pinpoint which particular factor is more responsible for the present debilitated state of expenditure control in public bodies. The words of the poet T.S. Eliot, “and as in time results of many deeds are blended/so good and evil in the end become confounded” have a unique applicability to expenditure management.

Toward the Seee Paradigm

The central issues that emerge from the preceding description and discussion of issues are why are some systems successful and why do some fail? Since the issues are likely to persist and to become more complex in the future, what type of systems would be appropriate? Although details of various aspects and experience with each system are considered in later chapters, a combination of factors seems to be at work behind the success or failure of each. Broadly, the determinants of any system are dependent not merely on its components or the attention given to policy, process, and efficiency controls, but on the other factors illustrated in Figure 2. Although identifying and anticipating problem areas is a normal function of management, its ability is put to the test in evolving policy measures and supporting administrative measures that secure political and public support. No package can be expected to succeed unless it reflects public consensus, and no consensus can be built without disseminating information on the components of the package and its potential benefits as well as its relevance in tackling the problem. Available experience suggests, however, that in addition to the absence of efforts to build a consensus the packages frequently lack administrative preparedness. This area needs to be addressed in strengthening expenditure management.

Figure 2.
Figure 2.

Determinants of a System’s Success

Expenditure management will continue to be concerned with securing stabilization, economy, efficiency, and effectiveness (SEEE). Their roles differ from one stage to another. It is a dynamic combination in that the relative roles will vary. Chart 4 illustrates these aspects. Stabilization is primarily concerned with the aggregate level of expenditures, and, to a lesser extent, with the composition of expenditures. Thus, all efforts aimed at securing stabilization will be focused on determining that level, and thereafter, the expenditure management machinery will have to ensure that that level is sustained and that in observing that limit, there are no diseconomies. Considerations of economy and efficiency and of stabilization are not mutually exclusive but are interdependent. It is difficult to view stabilization as successful if it is achieved at considerable cost and with avoidable idleness of resources; on the other hand, achieving economy and effectiveness would be little compensation if destabilization results.

Chart 4.
Chart 4.

Pursuit of Stabilization, Economy, Efficiency, and Effectiveness (SEEE)

Pursuit of economy moves in tandem with pursuit of stabilization. It consists in less resources being used than planned. It implies that while a good deal of attention is given to this aspect at the resource allocation stage, more resources may well have been allocated than needed, and that with judicious attention to the details of implementation, agencies could be induced to be vigilant in achieving economy. If, on the other hand, the allocation of resources is based on what could be considered inviolate norms or standards, agencies would have little incentive to look for economies. The scope of the economies also depends on the composition of expenditures and on the role allotted to procurement and contracting out.

Efficiency—the use of resources in relation to outputs—or the ability to produce more with the resources allocated—is dependent primarily on the efforts of the spending agencies and their awareness of the interests of their clients as well as of the utilization of the services provided. Specifying the measures of efficiency and incentives for retaining the savings procured in the process is likely to provide a powerful stimulus to the agencies.

Effectiveness—the degree of fulfillment of program objectives—forces the agencies to adopt a managerial attitude in specifying the objectives to be achieved and in monitoring the progress in tasks assigned. In a common and transparent framework of evaluation, the agencies would have opportunities to look back and learn the lessons of experience for future application.

The pursuit of this SEEE paradigm involves a differentiated focus and application of the components. Thus, if the problem is one of adhering to the budget estimates, greater attention may be needed both at the estimation as well as at the implementation stage. If, on the other hand, the issue is one of excessive use of resources in relation to needs, the emphasis will have to be on economy. Greater savings through efforts at economy may even suggest laxity at the allocation stage, or may have been the result of cumulative neglect. But if the system is developing leakages, and inefficient operations tend to dominate the fiscal landscape, greater efforts to restore efficiency would be needed. If, despite all these efforts, no demand for the services is generated, or, in other words, the operation is ineffective, the policy itself may need to be reviewed. Thus, instead of having a management system that is on auto pilot without any particular destination in view, management should provide a unifying and overriding theme(s) for all the phases and points of expenditure management to develop and implement a differentiated and situation-specific approach.

The pursuit of the SEEE paradigm should not be considered either easy or always productive. It is unlikely to prove rewarding where, for example, deliberate overmanning is undertaken as a policy measure, or where the expenditures are dominated by transfer payments (that are money intensive and reflect previous commitments). As a minimum, however, the pursuit will reveal the rigidities of the system, and, if properly conceived and judiciously implemented, offers considerable potential.

1

A report of the U.S. Genera) Accounting Office (1985) noted, for example, that “the processes by which we decide how much to spend, and for what purposes, are cumbersome, repetitive, and time-consuming. Controls over how federal money is spent are detailed and burdensome, but they are routinely found to be ineffective in preventing abuses. Budgeting, accounting, and management information systems often yield data that are unreliable, inconsistent, and all too often irrelevant” (Vol. I, p. 1).

In a similar vein, a more recent report of the Committee on Reforms of the Budget and Expenditure Control in Bangladesh (1992, unpublished) noted that the problems experienced related to “discrepancies of budget estimates and budget out-turn with respect to both receipts and expenditure; weak control over expenditure flows, weaknesses in recording and reporting of expenditure; absence or inadequacy of information regarding public sector enterprises in the national budget; absence of procedures and information in the budget and accounting data which would enable assessment of outcomes of public expenditure” (p. 1). These instances are not by any means unique. Rather, they illustrate the range of common problems.

3

For an extended discussion of these aspects, see Rainey, Backoff, and Levine (1976), and specifically for Galbraith and Weidenbaum, see pp. 234 and 241, respectively.

4

Indeed, even the more recent advances in management theory and practice could be said to be applicable to both sectors in numerous areas. For example, Porter’s paradigm for competitive advantage suggests that the infrastructure (finance, planning, etc.), human resource management, technology development, procurement, inbound logistics, operations, outbound logistics, marketing and sales, and after-sales service that determine the competitive advantages of a firm may also be said to be applicable to the government’s operations except that marketing and after-sales service have different variations in government; see Porter (1990). In economic theory, government is treated as a firm with its own type of inputs and outputs that have unique characteristics.

6

For an interesting approach in this regard, see Dye (1990).

9

For an illustrative discussion of these aspects, see Axelrod’s paper on budget law in Premchand (1990).

10

Max Weber wrote that “treasury officials of the Persian shah have made a secret doctrine of their budgetary art and even use secret script.” Quoted in Donahue (1989, p. 33).

11

Donahue (1989, p. 32).

12

See Donahue (1989, p. 23 ff.).

13

The implications of policy and administration have been well captured, for example, in the fictitious character of Permanent Secretary in the British Broadcasting Corporation’s comedy series, Yes Minister. He says, “I do think there is a dilemma here, in that while it has been government policy to regard policy as the responsibility of ministers and administration as the responsibility of officials, questions of administrative policy can cause administrative confusion between the administration of policy and the policy of administration, especially when responsibility for the administration of the policy of administration conflicts or overlaps with responsibility for the policy of the administration of policy” (Lynn and Jay, 1984, p. 232).

15

See, for example, Schick (1966), who considers the control orientation in terms of line-item appropriations and associated procedures.

16

Kline and Martin (1958) noted that the “chief characteristic of the command hierarchy, or any group in our society, is not knowledge but ignorance” (emphasis added), and, “it seems possible, then, that in organizing ourselves into a hierarchy of authority for the purpose of increasing efficiency, we may really be institutionalizing ignorance. While making better use of what the few know, we are making sure that the great majority are prevented from exploring the dark areas beyond our knowledge” (p. 70).

  • Collapse
  • Expand
Author:
  • Adanolekun, Ladipo, “Institutional Perspectives on Africa’s Development Crisis,” International Journal of Public Sector Management (1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Allison, Graham T., Jr., “Public and Private Management, Are They Fundamentally Alike in All Unimportant Respects?” in Current Issues in Public Administration, ed. by Frederick S. Lane (New York: St. Martin’s Press, 1982), pp. 1333.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Anshen, Melvin, “The Federal Budget as an Instrument for Management and Analysis,” in Program Budgeting: Program Analysis and Federal Budget, ed. by David Novick (Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press, 1965), pp. 323.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Anthony, Robert N., Planning and Control Systems: A Framework for Analysis (Boston: Harvard University, Graduate School of Business Administration, 1965).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Anthony, Robert N., The Management Control Function (Boston: Harvard Business School Press, 1988).

  • Arab Organization of Administrative Services, The Unified Government Accounting System for Arab Countries (Cairo, 1980).

  • Arkadie, Brian van, “The Role of Institutions in Development,” in Proceedings of the World Bank Annual Conference on Development Economics (Washington, 1989), pp. 15391.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Artis, Michael, and Sylvia Ostry, International Economic Policy Coordination, Chatham House Papers No. 30, Royal Institute of International Affairs (London: Routledge and Kegan Paul, 1986).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ascher, Kate, The Politics of Privatization: Contracting Out Public Services (New York: St. Martin’s Press, 1987).

  • Ball, Ian (1990a), “Financial Management Reform of New Zealand’s Public Sector: The Treasury’s Role” (New Zealand: The Treasury, 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ball, Ian (1990b), “Financial Management Reform of New Zealand’s Public Sector” (New Zealand: The Treasury, 1990).

  • Behn, Robert D., “Leadership for Cut-Back Management: The Use of Corporate Strategy,” Public Administration Review (November/December 1980).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bery, K., “Economic Policy Reform in Developing Countries: The Role and Management of Political Factors,” World Development, Vol. 18 (August 1990), pp. 112331.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bhatia, Rattan J., The West African Monetary Union: An Analytical Review, Occasional Paper 35 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1985).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Boum, John., “Helping the Nation Spend Wisely,” International journal of Government Auditing (October 1989), pp. 1 and 6.

  • Break, George F., Federal Lending and Economic Stability (Washington: Brookings Institution, 1965).

  • Brewer, John, The Sinews of Power: War, Money and the English State, 1688–1783 (New York: Knopf, 1989).

  • Bryant, Ralph, and others, eds., Macroeconomic Policies in an Interdependent World, Brookings Institution, Center for Economic Policy Research, and International Monetary Fund (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Buchanan, James M., Fiscal Theory and Political Economy: Selected Essays (Chapel Hill, North Carolina: University of North Carolina Press, 1960).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Burns, James M., Leadership (New York: Harper & Row, 1979).

  • Campbell, Harrison S., “Procurement and Management of Spares,” in Defense Management, ed. by Stephen Enke (New York: Prentice-Hall, 1967), pp. 187229.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Canada, Auditor General of Canada, Constraints to Productive Management in the Public Service (Ottawa, 1983).

  • Canada, Auditor General of Canada, Well-Performing Organizations (Ottawa, 1988).

  • Canada, Auditor General of Canada, Values, Service and Performance (Ottawa, 1990).

  • Canada, Auditor General of Canada, The Treasury Board, Guide on the Program Evaluation Function (Ottawa, 1981).

  • Canetti, Elias, Crowds and Power, translated by Carol Stewart (New York: Continuum, 1981).

  • The Chartered Institute of Public Finance and Accountancy, Cash Limits in Operation (London, 1982).

  • Chaudhuri, K.N., Asia Before Europe: Economy and Civilization of the Indian Ocean from the Rise of Islam to 1750 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Danziger, James N., and Peter Smith Ring, “Fiscal Limitations: A Selective Review of Recent Research,” Public Administration Review (January/February 1982).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dean, Peter N., and Cedric Pugh, Government Budgeting in Developing Countries (London: Routledge, 1989).

  • Deming, W. Edwards, Out of the Crisis (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press, 1986).

  • Devons, Ely, Planning in Practice: Essays in Aircraft Planning in Wartime (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1950).

  • Diamond, Jack, “Measuring Efficiency in Government: Techniques and Experience,” in Government Financial Management, ed. by A. Premchand (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dixit, Avinash K., and Barry Nalebuff, Thinking Strategically: The Competitive Edge in Business, Politics, and Everyday Life (New York: Norton, 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Donahue, John D., The Privatization Decision: Public Ends, Private Means (New York: Basic Books, 1989).

  • Dopson, Sue, and Rosemary Stewart, “Public and Private Sector Management: The Case for a Wider Debate,” Public Money and Management, Vol. 10 (Spring 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Douglas, Patricia P., and Robert N. Anthony, “An Analysis of the Government Accounting Model,” The Government Accountant’s Journal (Summer 1991), pp. 2534.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Drucker, Peter F., “The Deadly Sins in Public Administration,” in Current Issues in Public Administration, ed. by Frederick S. Lane (New York: St. Martin’s Press, 1982).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Drucker, Peter F.,, The New Realities; in Government and Politics, in Economics and Business, in Society and World View (New York: Harper & Row, 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Durham, Paul, ed., Output and Performance Measurement in Central Government: Some Practical Achievements (London: H.M. Treasury, 1987).

  • Dye, Kenneth M., “Value for Money: Toward Improved Organizational Functioning,” in Government Financial Management, ed. by A. Premchand (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Eden, Colin, and Chris. Huxham, “Action-Oriented Strategic Management,” Journal of Operational Research Society, Vol. 39, No. 10 (1988), pp. 88999.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Enke, Stephen, Defense Management (Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey: Prentice-Hall, 1967).

  • Fisher, Stanley, and Alan Gelb, “Issues in the Reform of Socialist Economies,” in Reforming Central and Eastern European Economies, ed. by Vittorio Corbo, Fabrizio Coricelli, and Jan Bossak (Washington: World Bank, 1991), pp. 6583.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fox, Ronald J., and James L. Field, The Defense Management Challenge: Weapons Acquisition (Boston: Harvard Business School, 1988).

  • Fukuyama, Francis, The End of History and the Last Man (New York: The Free Press, 1992).

  • Germany, Federal Ministry of Finance, Federal German Budget Legislation (Bonn, 1988).

  • Goode, Richard, Government Finance in Developing Countries (Washington: The Brookings Institution, 1984).

  • Grace, Peter J. (Chairman), War on Waste, President’s Private Sector Survey on Cost Control (New York: Macmillan, 1984).

  • Granick, David, Chinese State Enterprise: A Regional Property Rights Analysis (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1990).

  • Gunn, L., “Public Management: A Third Approach?” Public Money and Management, Vol. 8 (Spring/Summer 1988), pp. 2125.

  • Hage, Jerald, and Kurt Finsterbusch, Organizational Change as a Development Strategy: Models and Tactics for Improving Third World Organizations (Boulder, Colorado: Lynne Rienner, 1987).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hage, Jerald, and Kurt Finsterbusch, “Three Strategies of Organizational Development, Organizational Theory and Organizational Design,” International Review of Administrative Sciences, Vol. 55 (1989), pp. 2957.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hartle, Douglas G., The Expenditure Budget Process of the Government of Canada: A Public Choice—Rent-Seeking Perspective (Toronto: Canadian Tax Foundation, 1988).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hayek, Friedrich A. von, The Constitution of Liberty (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1960).

  • Heald, David, “The Political Implications of Redefining Public Expenditure in the United Kingdom,” Political Studies (1991), pp. 7599.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Healey, Denis, The Time of My Life (London: Michael Joseph, 1989).

  • Heymann, David B., “Input Controls in the Public Sector: What Does Economic Theory Offer?” IMF Working Paper No. 59 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1988).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hiromoto, Toshiro, “Another Hidden Edge—Japanese Management Accounting,” Harvard Business Review, Vol. 66 (July-August 1988), pp. 2226.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Home, Jocelyn, and Paul R. Masson, “Scope and Limits of International Economic Cooperation and Policy Coordination,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 35 (June 1988), pp. 25984.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hyde, Albert C., ed., Government Budgeting, Theory, Process, Politics (Pacific Grove, California: Brooks/Cole, 1992).

  • International Monetary Fund, World Economic Outlook, May 1992 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1992).

  • International Monetary Fund, The World Bank, Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, and European Bank for Reconstruction and Development, The Economy of the U.S.S.R. (Washington: World Bank, 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, A Study of the Soviet Economy, 3 vols. (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1991).

  • Jackson, P.M., “Economics of Public Services: Public Choice and Public Sector Management,” Public Money and Management, Vol. 10 (Winter 1990), pp. 1320.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Jackson, Peter, and Bob Palmer, First Steps in Measuring Performance in the Public Sector: A Management Guide (London: Public Finance Foundation, 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kapur, Ishan, Michael T. Hadjimichael, Paul Hilbers, Jerald Schiff, and Philippe Szymczak, Ghana: Adjustment and Growth, 1983–91, Occasional Paper 86 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Keating, Michael, and David Rosalky, “Rolling Expenditure Plans: Australian Experience and Prognosis,” in Government Financial Management, ed. by A. Premchand (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Keeling, Desmond, Management in Government (London: Allen & Unwin, 1972).

  • Kelman, Steven, Procurement and Public Management (Washington: American Enterprise Institute Press, 1990).

  • Kline, Bennett E., and Norman H. Martin, “Freedom, Authority and Decentralization,” Harvard Business Review, Vol. 36 (May-June 1958), pp. 6975.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Korff, Hans Clausen, “Planning and Budgeting in the Federal Republic of Germany,” in Comparative International Budgeting and Finance, ed. by A. Premchand and Jesse Burkhead (New Brunswick, New Jersey: Transaction Books, 1984), pp. 3953.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kraqan, D.J., “Towards More Flexibility of Government Expenditure: Some Recent Developments in the Netherlands,” Policy Sciences, No. 17 (1984), pp. 41327.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Leonard, David K., “The Political Realities of African Management,” World Development, Vol. 15 (July 1987), pp. 899910.

  • Levine, Charles H., “Organizational Decline and Cutback Management,” Public Administration Review (July/August 1978), pp. 33316325.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lewis, Verne B., “Reflections on Budget Systems,” Public Budgeting and Finance, Vol. 8 (Spring 1988), pp. 419.

  • Lewis, W. Arthur, The Theory of Economic Growth (London: Allen & Unwin, 1955).

  • Likierman, Andrew, “Government Accounting in the United Kingdom,” in Government Financial Management, ed. by A. Premchand (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1990), pp. 307325.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Likierman, Andrew, and Alison Taylor, Government’s New Departmental Reports: Challenges and Potential Problems (London: Certified Accountants Publications Ltd., 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lindblom, Charles E., “Decision-Making in Taxation and Expenditures,” in Public Finances; Needs, Sources and Utilization, ed. by James M. Buchanan (Princeton, New Jersey: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1961), pp. 295336.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lynn, Jonathan, and Anthony Jay, ed., The Complete Yes Minister (London: British Broadcasting Corporation, 1984).

  • McCaffery, Jerry, “Canada’s Envelope Budget: A Strategic Management System,” Public Administration Review (July/August 1984), pp. 31623.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mack, Ruth P., Planning in Uncertainty—Decision Making in Business and Government Administration (Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey: Prentice-Hall, 1970).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Macmullen, Ramsay, Corruption and the Decline of Rome (New Haven, Connecticut: Yale University Press, 1988).

  • Math, Paul, “Acquisition Reform: Three Guiding Principles,” The G.A.O. Journal, No. 7 (Fall 1989).

  • Mautz, R.K., “Generally Accepted Principles,” Public Budgeting and Finance (Winter 1991), pp. 311.

  • Metcalfe, Les, and Sue Richards, Improving Public Management (London: Sage Publications, 1987).

  • Miah, Nuruz Zaman, “Attempts at Developing a Conceptual Framework for Public Sector Accounting in New Zealand,” Financial Accountability and Management, Vol. 7 (Summer 1991), pp. 8397.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Montgomery, John D., “Probing Managerial Behavior: Image and Reality in Southern Africa,” World Development, Vol. 15, No. 7 (1987), pp. 91129.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mosley, Paul, Jane Harrigan, and John Toye, Aid and Power: The World Bank and Policy-Based Lending, 2 vols. (London; New York: Routledge, 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mowl, Colin, and Philippa Todd, Central Government Funds and Accounts and the Central Government Borrowing Requirement (London: H.M. Treasury, 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Nader, Ralph, “Run the Government Like the Best American Corporations,” Harvard Business Review, Vol. 66 (November-December 1988), pp. 8186.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • New Zealand, The Public Finance Act (Wellington: Government Printing Works, 1989).

  • New Zealand, Putting It Simply—An Explanatory Guide to Financial Management Reform (Wellington: The Treasury, 1990).

  • Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, The Control and Management of Government Expenditure (Paris, 1987).

  • Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, Public Management Developments, Survey 1990 (Paris, 1990).

  • Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, Accounting Reform in Central and Eastern Europe (Paris, 1991).

  • Paul, Samuel, Institutional Development in World Bank Projects: A Cross-Sectoral Review, Working Paper 392 (Washington: World Bank, 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Paul, Samuel, Accountability in Public Services: Exit, Voice, and Capture, Working Paper 614 (Washington: World Bank, 1991).

  • Polanyi, Michael, The Logic of Liberty (London: Allen & Unwin, 1951).

  • Porter, Michael E., The Competitive Advantage of Nations (New York: Free Press, 1990).

  • Premchand, A., Performance Budgeting (Bombay: Academic Books, 1969).

  • Premchand, A., “Budgetary Reforms in Developing Countries: Need for Renewal,” Finance & Development (1973).

  • Premchand, A., “Government Lending Programs in OECD and Selected Developing Countries,” IMF Survey, Vol. 11 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, August 2, 1982).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Premchand, A., Government Budgeting and Expenditure Controls (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1983).

  • Premchand, A., “Government Budgeting and Productivity,” Public Productivity Review, No. 41 (1987) (reprinted in Government Budgeting, Theory, Process, Politics, ed. by Albert C. Hyde (Pacific Grove, California: Brooks/Cole, 1992)).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Premchand, A., “Financial Management in Government: Are We Really Serious?” Public Fund Digest, Vol. 11, No. 2 (1988), pp. 6770.

  • Premchand, A., “Coordination of Expenditure Policies in GCC Member States,” paper presented at a roundtable organized by the Arab Monetary Fund (Abu Dhabi, September 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Premchand, A., ed., Government Financial Management (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1990).

  • Premchand, A., and Jesse Burkhead, ed., Comparative International Budgeting and Finance (New Brunswick, New Jersey: Transaction Books, 1984).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Premchand, A., and A. L. Antonaya, ed., Aspectos del presupuesto publico (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1988).

  • Premchand, A., and A. L. Antonaya, Premchand, A., and L. Garamfalvt, “Government Budget and Accounting Systems,” in Fiscal Policies in Economies in Transition, ed. by Vito Tanzi (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1992).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Quinn, J.B., Strategies for Change: Logical Incrementalism (Romewood, Illinois: Irwin, 1980).

  • Rainey, Hal G., Robert W. Backoff, and Charles H. Levine, “Comparing Public and Private Organizations,” Public Administration Review (March/April 1976).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Rehfuss, John A., Contracting Out in Government: A Guide to Working with Outside Contractors to Supply Public Services (San Francisco: Jossey-Bass, 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Richardson, Eliot L., “The Value of Evaluation,” The G.A.O, Journal, No. 12 (Spring 1991), pp. 3742.

  • Rist, Ray C, ed., Program Evaluation and the Management of Government (New Brunswick, New Jersey: Transaction Publishers, 1990).

  • Robinson, Ann, and Bengt-Christer Ysander, “Re-establishing Budgetary Flexibility,” Public Budgeting and Finance, Vol. 2 (Autumn 1982), pp. 2134.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Robinson, David J., and Peter Stella, “Amalgamating Central Bank and Fiscal Deficits,” in Measurement of Fiscal Impact: Methodological Issues, ed. by Mario I. Blejer and Ke-Young Chu, Occasional Paper 59 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1988), pp. 2031.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Roe, Emery M., “The Ceiling as Base: National Budgeting in Kenya,” Public Budgeting and Finance, Vol. 6 (Summer 1986), pp. 87103.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Rogers, H.G., M.A. Ulrich, and K.L. Traversy, “Evaluation in Practice: The State of the Art in Canadian Governments,” Canadian Public Administration, Vol. 24 (Fall 1981), pp. 37186.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Samuels, Warren J., ed., Institutional Economics, 3 vols. (London: Edward Elgar, 1988).

  • Sappington, David E.M., “Incentives in Principal-Agent Relationships,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 5 (Spring 1991), pp. 4566.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Schick, Allen, “The Road to PPB: The Stages of Budget Reform,” Public Administration Review (December 1966), pp. 24358.

  • Schick, Allen, “Incremental Budgeting in a Decremental Age,” Policy Sciences, No. 16 (1983), pp. 125.

  • Schick, Allen, “Macro-Budgeting Adaptations to Fiscal Stress in Industrialized Democracies,” Public Administration Review (March/April 1986), pp. 12434.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Schick, Allen, “Why the Deficit Persists as a Budget Problem: Role of Political Institutions,” in Government Financial Management: Issues and Country Studies, ed. by A. Premchand (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1990), pp. 3852.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Schultze, Charles L., “Of Wolves, Termites, and Pussycats: Or, Why We Should Worry About the Budget Deficit,” The Brookings Review, Vol. 7 (Summer 1989), pp. 2633.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Scott, Graham, Peter Bushnell, and Nikitin Sallee, “Reform of the Core Public Sector: The New Zealand Experience,” Public Sector, Vol. 13, No. 3 (1990), pp. 1124.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Sensenbrenner, Joseph, “Quality Comes to City Hall,” Harvard Business Review, Vol. 69 (March-April 1991), pp. 6475.

  • Shanghai University of Finance and Economics and Center for International Accounting Development, Accounting and Auditing in the People’s Republic of China: A Review of its Practices, Systems, Education, and Developments (Dallas: University of Texas, 1987).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Simon, Herbert A., “Organizations and Markets,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 5 (Spring 1991), pp. 2544.

  • Staats, Elmer B., “Government Accounting: Promise and Performance,” in Government Financial Management: Issues and Country Studies, ed. by A. Premchand (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1990), pp. 12834.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Stiglitz, Joseph E., and others, The Economic Role of the State, ed. by Arnold Heertje (Oxford: Basil Blackwell, 1989).

  • Stockman, David, “The Crisis in Federal Budgeting,” in Crisis in the Budget Process: Exercising Political Choice, by Allen Schick with papers by David Stockman, Rudolph Penner, Trent Lott, Leon Panetta, and Norman Orstein (Washington: American Enterprise Institute, 1986), pp. 5766.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Tanzi, Vito, “Fiscal Issues in Economies in Transition,” in Reforming Central and Eastern European Economies, ed. by Vittorio Corbo, Fabrizio Coricelli, and Jan Bossack (Washington: World Bank, 1991), pp. 22128.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Tarschys, Daniel, “Curbing Public Expenditure: Current Trends,” Journal of Public Policy, Vol. 5 (February 1985), pp. 2367.

  • Tarschys, Daniel, “From Expansion to Restraint: Recent Developments in Budgeting,” Public Budgeting and Finance, Vol. 6 (Autumn 1986), pp. 2537.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Thomas, John W., and Merilee S. Grindle, “After the Decision: Implementing Policy Reforms in Developing Countries,” World Development, Vol. 18 (August 1990), pp. 116381.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Uchiteile, Louis, “But Just Who Is That Fairy Godmother?” New York Times, September 29, 1991, Sec. 4, p. 1.

  • United Kingdom, Financial Management in Government Departments, Cmnd. 9058 (London: H.M. Stationery Office, 1983).

  • United Kingdom, The Financing and Accountability of Next Steps Agencies, CM 914 (London: H.M. Treasury, 1989).

  • United Kingdom (1991a), Competing for Quality, CM 1730 (London: H.M. Treasury, 1991).

  • United Kingdom (1991b), Improving Management in Government: The Next Steps Agencies, Review 1991, CM 1760 (London: H.M. Treasury, 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • United Kingdom, National Audit Office (1991a), Annual Report (London, 1991).

  • United Kingdom (1991b), A Framework for Value for Money Audits (London, 1991).

  • United Kingdom (1991c), NHS Outpatient Services (London, 1991).

  • United Kingdom (1991d), Presenting Data Reports (London, 1991).

  • United Kingdom (1991e), Promoting Value for Money from Grants (London, 1991).

  • United Kingdom, Privy Council, Efficiency in the Civil Service, Cmnd. 8293 (London: H.M. Stationery Office, 1981).

  • United States, Congress, Management Theories in the Private and Public Sectors, 98th Cong., 2nd Sess., September 1984 (Washington: Government Printing Office, 1984).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • United States, Congress, Congressional Budget Office, Trends in Public Investment (Washington, 1987).

  • United States, Congress, Congressional Budget Office, Executive Office of the President, Office of Management and Budget, Management of the United States Government, Fiscal Year 1989 (Washington: Government Printing Office, 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • United States, Congress, Congressional Budget Office, Executive Office of the President, Office of Management and Budget (1992a), Budget of the United States Government, Fiscal Year 1993 (Washington: Government Printing Office, 1992).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • United States, Congress, Congressional Budget Office, Executive Office of the President, Office of Management and Budget (1992b), Form and Content of Agency Financial Statements, Bulletin No, 93–02 (Washington: Government Printing Office, October 22, 1992).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • United States, Congress, Congressional Budget Office, Executive Office of the President, Office of Management and Budget, Federal Accounting Standards Advisory Board, Financial Resources, Funded Liabilities, and Net Financial Resources of Funded Entities (Exposure Draft) (Washington, November 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • United States, Congress, Congressional Budget Office, Executive Office of the President, Office of Management and Budget, General Accounting Office, Designing Evaluation, Methodology Transfer Paper 4 (Washington: Government Printing Office, 1984).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • United States, Congress, Congressional Budget Office, Executive Office of the President, Office of Management and Budget, Managing the Cost of Government; Building an Effective Financial Management Structure, 2 vols. (Washington: Government Printing Office, 1985).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • United States, Congress, Congressional Budget Office, Executive Office of the President, Office of Management and Budget, Federal Government Reporting System (Washington: Government Printing Office, 1986).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • United States, Congress, Congressional Budget Office, Executive Office of the President, Office of Management and Budget, Managing the Cost of Government (Washington: Government Printing Office, 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • United States, Congress, Congressional Budget Office, Executive Office of the President, Office of Management and Budget, Public Debt: Management Actions Needed to Ensure More Accurate Accounting (Washington: Government Printing Office, 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • United States, Congress, Congressional Budget Office, Executive Office of the President, Office of Management and Budget, Federal Credit and Insurance Programs: Actions That Could Minimize a Growing Risk (Washington: Government Printing Office, 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • United States, Congress, Congressional Budget Office, Executive Office of the President, Office of Management and Budget, Comptroller General’s 1991 Annual Report (Washington: Government Printing Office, 1992).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • United States, Congress, Congressional Budget Office, Executive Office of the President, Office of Management and Budget, Governmental Accounting Standards Board, Objectives of Financial Reporting (Washington, 1987).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Visscher, Christian De, “The Modernization of Budgetary Techniques and Financial Control,” International Review of Administrative Sciences, Vol. 55 (September 1989), pp. 32164.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Wattle worth, Michael, “Credit Subsidies in Budgetary Lending: Computation, Effects, and Fiscal Implications,” in Measurement of Fiscal Impact: Methodological Issues, ed. by Mario I. Blejer and Ke-Young Chu, Occasional Paper 59 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1988), pp. 5769.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Weber, Max, Economy and Society, ed. by Guenther Roth and Claus Wittich, 2 vols. (Berkeley, California: University of California Press, 1978). (See, in particular, Chapter XI on “Bureaucracy,” pp. 9561005.)

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Wesberry, James P., Jr., “Government Accounting and Financial Management in Latin American Countries,” in Government Financial Management: Issues and Country Studies, ed. by A. Premchand (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1990), pp. 345–74.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Wholey, Joseph S., Kathryn E. Newcomer, and Associates, Improving Government Performance: Evaluation Strategies for Strengthening Public Agencies and Programs (San Francisco: Jossey-Bass, 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Wilson, James Q., Bureaucracy: What Government Agencies Do and Why They Do It (New York: Basic Books, 1989).

  • World Bank, Toward Sustained Development in Sub-Saharan Africa: A Joint Program of Action (Washington: World Bank, 1984).

  • World Bank (1988a), Adjustment Lending: An Evaluation of Ten Years of Experience (Washington: World Bank, 1988).

  • World Bank (1988b), World Development Report (Washington: World Bank, 1988).

  • World Bank, World Development Report: The Challenge of Development, 1991 (Washington: World Bank, 1991).

  • Yates, Douglas, Bureaucratic Democracy (Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press, 1982).

  • Ysander, Bengt-Christer, and Ann Robinson, “The Inflexibility of Contemporary Budgets,” Public Budgeting and Finance, Vol. 2 (Autumn 1982), pp. 720.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Zussman, David, and Jak Jabes, The Vertical Solitude: Managing in the Public Sector (Halifax, Nova Scotia: Institute for Research on Public Policy, 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation