X Tax Harmonization
Author:
International Monetary Fund
Search for other papers by International Monetary Fund in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close

Abstract

With the implementation of free mobility of commodities and factor inputs, the EC Commission has stressed the need for tax harmonization. The Commission has given top priority to harmonizing indirect taxes, since, at present, the administration of these taxes depends crucially on the existence of border controls, which are to be removed with the start-up of the internal market. As no removal of border controls between the EC and the EFTA is currently envisaged, the implication for the EFTA of indirect tax harmonization in the EC is limited. Moreover, the EC countries have tended to postpone decisions relating to tax harmonization. While an alignment of taxes may still result spontaneously through competitive pressure, it would proceed more slowly than a centrally administered harmonization. Harmonization of corporate and capital income taxes is potentially a more urgent problem because these taxes fall on a highly mobile base. However, at this point, the Commission has no plans for a general harmonization of taxes on labor income, reflecting the fact that the psychological and cultural barriers to international mobility of labor remain high.

With the implementation of free mobility of commodities and factor inputs, the EC Commission has stressed the need for tax harmonization. The Commission has given top priority to harmonizing indirect taxes, since, at present, the administration of these taxes depends crucially on the existence of border controls, which are to be removed with the start-up of the internal market. As no removal of border controls between the EC and the EFTA is currently envisaged, the implication for the EFTA of indirect tax harmonization in the EC is limited. Moreover, the EC countries have tended to postpone decisions relating to tax harmonization. While an alignment of taxes may still result spontaneously through competitive pressure, it would proceed more slowly than a centrally administered harmonization. Harmonization of corporate and capital income taxes is potentially a more urgent problem because these taxes fall on a highly mobile base. However, at this point, the Commission has no plans for a general harmonization of taxes on labor income, reflecting the fact that the psychological and cultural barriers to international mobility of labor remain high.

Indirect Taxes

At present the EC and EFTA countries maintain widely different value-added tax (VAT) rates (Table 9).100 Since the VAT systems are operated according to the “destination principle,” under which goods are taxed in the country of final consumption, adverse effects on any country’s competitiveness or tax base are avoided. Thus, a product carries the domestic tax rate whether it is produced domestically or imported, while exported products leave the country free of any VAT. In order to ensure that the domestic VAT is charged on imported products and that goods for which zero-rating is claimed are being exported, countries rely on tax adjustments at the border. Border controls are also used to monitor cross-border trade, so that consumers making direct purchases abroad are subject to the domestic VAT on purchases in excess of the personal exemption. Thus, the frontier formalities permit a member country to set its own tax rates without imposing adverse externalities on others.

Table 9.

EC and EFTA: VAT Rates1

(in percent)

article image
Sources: “Rates of VAT in the EC on January 1, 1989,” European Report, December 14, 1989, p. II, 4; “Value Added Taxation in Europe,” Guides to European Taxation, Vol. IV; and country authorities.

January 1, 1989, unless specified otherwise.

January 1, 1990.

Reduced rates are applied for construction and certain other services. A temporary increase to 25 percent took effect on July 1, 1990; it will expire on December 31, 1991.

No VAT. Turnover tax levied at 6.2 percent on consumers and 9.3 percent on retailers. Imports are taxed at 9.6 percent unless they are imports of a registered enterprise.

If the VAT system is to remain neutral after border controls are eliminated, an administrative substitute for fiscal checks at the frontier has to be devised. In addition, member states with higher rates of indirect taxation may have to reduce their tax rates in order to avoid a diversion of retail business (and tax revenue) to lower-tax member states. For the former purpose, the Commission has proposed that the system of zero-rating of exports from one member country to another be ended, that is, transactions between countries be treated as those within countries. Thus, exports would carry the exporting country’s VAT, which would be reimbursed as input VAT to the importer. Such a change would have implications for the international distribution of tax revenue.101 Accordingly, a clearing system would be set up to redistribute VAT revenues, so that they continue to accrue to the country consuming the products. In relation to nonmember countries, the EC would continue to operate a traditional system based on fiscal documentation at the border. Thus, the administrative aspects of the proposed VAT reform would have no consequences for the EFTA as long as border controls are maintained between the two blocks.

The issue of harmonization of tax rates arises primarily in the context of cross-border shopping. There is already a considerable amount of cross-border shopping in the EC (for example, between Denmark and Germany), and it is likely to increase with the removal of border controls. This may lead to competitive downward pressure on tax rates. Instead of such a market-driven alignment of rates, the Commission proposes harmonization by agreement, whereby the burden of adjustment is shared between high-tax and low-tax countries.

At present, all member countries except Denmark apply at least two VAT rates: a reduced rate for such necessities as food and medicine, and a standard rate for other goods. The Commission has proposed retaining a dual rate structure, while leaving the member countries some freedom in setting the tax rates in each category. According to the initial proposal announced in 1987, the standard rate should be set between 14 percent and 20 percent, with the reduced rate between 4 percent and 9 percent. The width of the bands was determined on the basis of the U.S. experience, suggesting that differences of about 5–6 percentage points in tax rates between neighboring states can be sustained without serious border trade problems.

Some countries objected to the Commission’s proposal because of the large changes in tax rates or tax coverage that it would have required. The United Kingdom would have had to eliminate the zero rate it uses on a variety of goods and services, while Denmark would have suffered a sharp cut in revenue from its VAT. In May 1989, therefore, the Commission modified its proposal, adopting a “pragmatic” approach to VAT harmonization. The modified proposal entailed, among other things, rescinding the upper limit on the standard rate. The Commission also accepted a zero rate for a limited number of commodities in countries that already provide for a zero rate. However, it retained the proposed band for the reduced rate.

Along with its proposals to align VAT systems, the Commission has also suggested harmonizing excise taxes. Excise tax systems of the EC countries are even more divergent than VAT systems, for example, in the treatment of manufactured tobaccos, alcoholic beverages, and mineral oils.

The Commission’s initial proposal was quite radical, involving complete harmonization of tax rates as well as of the tax base of excises. Full harmonization was justified on the grounds that the VAT is calculated on a product’s price including excise duty, so that any differences in excise duty rates would magnify the differences in effective VAT rates. Full harmonization was probably also considered essential to reducing the scope for indirect protection of national production of such products as tobacco and alcoholic beverages. On the other hand, the proposal has been criticized for not paying adequate attention to health, environmental, or other legitimate concerns of member countries. In May 1989, the Commission modified its proposal by setting only minimum rates for tobacco products and alcoholic beverages. For the longer run it also defined target rates of taxation; these target rates are 10 percent higher than the rates proposed in 1987. To administer excise taxes after lifting border controls, the Commission has proposed establishing a system of linked bonded warehouses. This involves suspending the excise duty until goods leave a warehouse to be sold on the domestic market.

Assuming that border controls between the EFTA and the EC are maintained, tax harmonization would not have important consequences for the EFTA. However, all the EFTA countries except Switzerland have tax rates in excess of the top rate originally proposed by the Commission. Since harmonization in the EC—whether by prior agreement or by competitive pressure—is bound to lead to a lowering of the higher rates, the incentives for cross-border shopping by EFTA nationals in the EC will increase. Thus, the Danish VAT rate is likely to fall, providing opportunities for profitable cross-border shopping by Swedish nationals. However, the difference in rates between the two countries is unlikely to exceed 5–6 percent, which is considered the maximum sustainable difference in the absence of border controls. On the other hand, Austria’s VAT rate on luxuries (32 percent) is likely to look very high following harmonization in the EC and would probably have to be brought closer to the EC standard rate. Iceland has the highest VAT rate in the EFTA, but the scope for cross-border shopping is limited, given Iceland’s geographic location.

While Switzerland’s dependence on its turnover tax is comparatively modest, most EFTA countries rely heavily on VAT revenue (Table 10). A removal of border controls between the EFTA and the EC and a concomitant harmonization of VAT rates would thus lead to sizable revenue losses for the EFTA countries. The latter may therefore opt to follow Denmark’s approach to harmonization, which is to give priority to the lowering of rates on goods that are important in cross-border trade.

Table 10.

EC and EFTA: Revenues from VAT and Excise Taxes1

(in percent)

article image
Sources: IMF, International Financial Statistics, March 1990; and IMF, Government Finance Statistics Yearbook, 1989.

The data refer to the most recent year for which data are available. In most cases the year is 1987 or 1988.

Capital Income Taxation

The liberalization of capital movements now in progress in the EC raises the issue of harmonization of corporate and portfolio income taxation. With capital liberalization in the EFTA countries also progressing at a rapid pace, the issue is equally important in their case. Indeed, the EFTA countries could be vulnerable to any major changes in EC capital income taxation. In practice, however, although capital income taxation has been on the EC agenda longer than the internal market, consensus has been particularly elusive.

At present, EC countries’ methods of taxing capital income differ widely. Calls for harmonization have been prompted by the fact that with full capital mobility in prospect, these differences are creating considerable scope for tax arbitrage and tax evasion. Moreover, when capital is free to flow to countries with a favorable tax regime or where it can escape taxation altogether, the capital will not necessarily be used to finance the most efficient investments.

The Commission has made a number of proposals in the area of corporate income taxation, with the first back in 1969. The proposals address such issues as harmonization of company tax systems, elimination of double taxation of foreign source company income, and crediting of shareholders for the tax on company profits. Thus, the main features of a directive proposed in 1975 included a single statutory rate of corporate income tax set in an interval between 45 percent and 55 percent; a common imputation system for distributed dividends with a single rate of tax credit to shareholders; and a common approach to the taxation of dividends crossing borders. The proposal was never adopted; it was officially withdrawn in April 1990.

On July 23, 1990, EC finance ministers adopted a package of three corporate tax directives that had been blocked at the Council level for several years. The directives aimed at eliminating most risks of double taxation for firms operating across borders within the Community. The package included a directive to prohibit member states from imposing a withholding tax on profits distributed by a subsidiary in its territory to a parent company located in another member state.

The Commission has formed a special group of experts to review the whole area of corporate taxation. It will analyze such issues as whether the differences in corporate taxation distort investment decisions, whether market forces and competition among national fiscal systems will suffice to eliminate these differences or whether Community legislation will be necessary, and so forth.

Interest income from foreign bank deposits or securities is potentially an easy conduit for tax evasion following removal of capital controls. Thus, a Commission proposal issued in February 1989 calls for a minimum 15 percent withholding tax on interest income of EC residents. In view of the risk of inducing capital outflows to third countries with adverse effects on interest rates in member countries, the proposal provides for numerous exemptions. Nevertheless, it has run into considerable opposition. As a result, the Commission has shifted the emphasis of its proposal from the withholding tax toward agreement on adoption of minimum reporting agreements and exchange of information on EC residents’ interest income.

Progress toward concerted harmonization of capital income taxes in the EC will apparently be slow, which may not give great comfort to the EFTA countries. First, with increasing capital mobility, the EFTA countries may be just as exposed as the EC countries to the risks of tax arbitrage, tax evasion, and distorted investment incentives posed by the current EC system. Second, concerted action may be replaced by harmonization through uncontrolled competitive pressure. The proliferation of tax reforms in both the EC and the EFTA in recent years may be an indication that this process is already under way. One problem with such a process is that the competition may in the long run drive tax rates down to suboptimal levels or create tax systems that are less efficient than if they had been the result of coordinated effort. In any event, the hardships are likely to be particularly great for such high-tax countries as Norway and Sweden, where substitute revenue sources may be difficult to find.

100

Switzerland has a turnover tax instead of a VAT.

101

Under this proposal, exporting countries with relatively high rates of VAT would gain, as would countries with export surpluses.

  • Collapse
  • Expand
  • Åkerholm, Johnny, and Juha Tarkka, “Kan de nordiska länderna föra en självständig penningpolitik,” Nordiska Ekonomiska Forskningsrådet Årsbok 1986 (Nordiska Ministerradets Skriftserie No. 1987:55).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Atkins, W.S., “The Cost of Non-Europe in Public Sector Procurement,” Costs of Non-Europe—Basic Studies: Executive Summaries, Vol. 1, Documents Series (Luxembourg: Office for Official Publications of the European Communities, 1988).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Baldwin, Richard, “Factor Market Barriers are Trade Barriers: Gains From Trade in 1992,” NBER Working Paper 2656. (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1988).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Baldwin, Richard, “The Growth Effects of 1992,” Economic Policy, Vol. 4 (1989), pp. 24881.

  • Basevi, Giorgio, “Monetary Cooperation and Liberalization of Capital Movements,” European Economic Review, Vol. 32 (Amsterdam: 1988), pp. 37281.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Begg, Lain, “European Integration and Regional Policy,” Oxford Review of Economic Policy, Vol. 5 (1989), pp. 90104.

  • Bovenberg, A. Lans, and Vito Tanzi, “Is There a Need for Harmonizing Capital Income Taxes Within the EC Countries,” IMF Working Paper WP/90/17 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Brander, James, and Paul Krugman, “A ‘Reciprocal Dumping’ Model of International Trade,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 15 (November 1983), pp. 31321.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Buraff Publications, 1992: The External Impact of European Unification (Washington: Buraff Publications, various issues).

  • Calingaert, Michael, The 1992 Challenge from Europe: Development of the European Communities’ Internal Market (Washington: National Planning Association, 1988).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Canzoneri, Matthew B., and Carol Ann Rogers, “Is the European Community an Optimal Currency Area? Optimal Taxation Versus the Cost of Multiple Currencies,” The American Economic Review, Vol. 80 (Nashville, Tennessee: June 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cecchini, Paolo, The European Challenge, 1992 (Aldershot, England: Gover, 1988).

  • Cohen, Daniel, and Charles Wyplosz, “The European Monetary Union: An Agnostic View,” in Macroeconomic Policies in an Interdependent World, ed. by Ralph C. Bryant (Washington: The Brookings Institution, 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Committee for the Study of Economic and Monetary Union, Report on Economic and Monetary Union in the European Community (Brussels: European Communities, 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Committee on Economic and Monetary Affairs and Industrial Policy, On the Proposal … on the procurement procedures of entities providing water, energy and transport services, European Parliament, Session Document A 20068/89, April 6, 1989.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Conseil Fédéral Suisse, Rapport sur la position de la Suisse dans le Processus d’Integration Europénne (Bern: Conseil Fédéral Suisse, 1988).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Corden, Max, “The Normative Theory of International Trade,” in Handbook of International Economics, ed. by Ronald Jones and Peter Kenen (Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1984).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Council of State, Report to Parliament Concerning Finland’s Attitude Towards the Western European Integration Process, Finland and the Western European Integration Process (Helsinki: Government Printing Office, 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Council of State, Finland och den Europeiska Ekonomiska Sfären (Helsinki: statens tryckericentral, 1990).

  • “Das EWS als Währungspolitische Alternative,” Neue Zürcher Zeitung, December 7, 1988. Reprinted in Deutsche Bundesbank, Auszüge aus Presseartikeln, No. 90 (December 9, 1988), pp. 79.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Deardorff, Alan, “Testing Trade Theories and Predicting Trade Flows,” in Handbook of International Economics, ed. by Ronald Jones and Peter Kenen (Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1984).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • DeCecco, Marcello, and Alberto Giovannini, eds., A European Central Bank? Perspectives on Monetary Unification after Ten Years of the EMS (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • De Grauwe, Paul, “Conditions for Monetary Integration—A Geometric Interpretation,” Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, Vol. 111 (Tübingen: 1975), pp. 63451.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Delors, Jacques, “Statement on the Broad Lines of Commission Policy,” Bulletin of the European Communities, Supplement 1/89, pp. 1718.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Delors, Jacques, “Address by President Delors to the European Parliament Presenting the Commission’s Programme for 1990” (unpublished, January 17, 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • “Der Schweizer Beitrag zur Europäischen Währungsunion,” Zu einem Referat von Markus Lusser, Präsident des Direktoriums der Schweizer Nationalbank, Neue Zürcher Zeitung, June 29, 1990.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dixit, Avinash, and A.S. Kyle, “The Use of Protection and Subsidies for Entry Promotion and Deterrence,” American Economic Review, Vol. 75 (Nashville, Tennessee: 1985), pp. 13952.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dornbusch, Rudiger, “Money and Finance in European Integration,” in Money and Finance in European Integration, EFTA Seminar (Geneva: European Free Trade Association, 1988).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • “Dr. Klauhs Presents an Austrian View of a European Currency and a European Central Bank,” Statement by the Governor of the Austrian National Bank, Dr. Helmut Klauhs, before the Working Group “European Currency” of the European Parliament on November 21, 1989 in Strasbourg. Reprinted in BIS Review, No. 236 (Basle: December 1, 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • “Dr. Lusser warns against exaggerated expectations as regards the ability to influence exchange rate levels.” Excerpts from an address by the President of the Swiss National Bank, Dr. Markus Lusser, at the University of St. Gallen on July 13, 1988 (unpublished, 1988).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Duisenberg, W.F., “Exchange Rate Stability in Europe,” in Money and Finance in European Integration, EFTA Seminar (Geneva: European Free Trade Association, 1988).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • “EC and EFTA to Strengthen their Relationship,” European Community 49/89, December 20, 1989.

  • EC Commission, Completing the Internal Market—White Paper from the Commission to the European Council (Brussels: EC Commission, 1985).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • EC Commission (1986a), Elimination of Distortions on Competition of a Fiscal Nature in the Transport of Goods by Road: Study of Vehicle Taxes, Fuel Taxes, December 10, 1986 (Brussels: COM (86) 750 final).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • EC Commission (1986b), Relations between the European Community and the EFTA Countries: Implementation of the Luxembourg Declaration (Brussels: COM (86) 298).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • EC Commission (1986c), “Single European Act,” Bulletin of the European Communities, Supplement 2/86.

  • EC Commission (1988a), A New Community’s Standards Policy (Brussels: EC Commission, 1988).

  • EC Commission (1988b), “Economics of 1992,” European Economy, No. 35 (March 1988).

  • EC Commission, European File (Brussels: EC Commission, various issues).

  • EC Council, Regulation No. 802/68, June 27, 1968.

  • “EC Outsiders Pursue Connection with the EMS,” Journal of Commerce (New York), January 30, 1990.

  • “Editorial—Two Tracks to Progress,” EFTA Bulletin (February 1989), pp. 13.

  • “EFTA Summit—We, the Heads of Government … ,” EFTA Bulletin (February 1989), pp. 47.

  • Emerson, Michael, “The European Monetary System in the Broader Setting of the Community’s Economic and Political Development,” in The European Monetary System: Its Purpose and Prospects, ed. by Philip Trezise (Washington: The Brookings Institution, 1979).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ernst and Whinney, “The Cost of Non-Europe: Customs Formalities,” Costs of Non-Europe—Basic Studies: Executive Summaries, Vol. 1, Documents Series (Luxembourg: Office for Official Publications of the European Communities, 1988).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ethier, Wilfred, and Henrik Horn, “A New Look at Economic Integration,” in Monopolistic Competition and International Trade, ed. by H. Kierzkowski (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1984).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • European Community, News, No. 39/89, November 1, 1989.

  • European Documentation, Europe Without Frontiers—Completing the Internal Market (Luxembourg: Office for Official Publications of the European Communities, 1988).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • European Documentation, The European Financial Common Market (Luxembourg: Office for Official Publications of the European Communities, 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • European Documentation, European Unification: The Origins and Growth of the European Community (Luxembourg: Office for Official Publications of the European Communities, 1986).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • European Free Trade Association (1987a), The European Free Trade Association (Geneva: EFTA, 1987).

  • European Free Trade Association (1987b), “Statement by EFTA Ministers in response to the EC Council on December 3, 1986,” 26th Annual Report of EFTA (Geneva: EFTA, 1987).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • European Free Trade Association, Consultative Committee, Economic and Social Subcommittee, The Transport Study, EFTA/CSC/ES 1/88 (Geneva: EFTA, March 1988).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • European Free Trade Association, Consultative Committee, Report by the Economic and Social Sub-Committee on the Creation of a European Financial Area (Geneva: European Free Trade Association, 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • “Europe’s Air Cartel,” The Economist, November 11, 1989, pp. 1923.

  • “Europe’s Internal Market,” The Economist, July 9, 1988, supp., p. 36.

  • Flam, Harry, and Henrik Horn, “Ekonomiska konsekvenser för Sverige av EGs inre marknad,” in Svensk ekonomi och Europaintegrationen (Stockholm: Ekonomiska rådet, 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fleming, J. Marcus, “Domestic Financial Policies Under Fixed and Under Floating Exchange Rates,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 9 (1962), pp. 36979.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fleming, J. Marcus, “On Exchange Rate Unification,” Economic Journal, Vol. 81 (1971), pp. 46788.

  • Folkerts-Landau, David, and Donald J. Mathieson, The European Monetary System in the Context of the Integration of European Financial Markets, Occasional Paper 66 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Frenkel, Jacob A., and Assaf Razin, “The Mundell-Fleming Model a Quarter Century Later: A Unified Exposition,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 34 (1987), pp. 567620.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gardener, Edward P.M., and Jonathan L. Teppett, “The Impact of 1992 on the Financial Services Sectors of EFTA Countries,” EFTA Occasional Paper 33 (Geneva: European Free Trade Association, 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Genberg, Hans, Monetary Targeting: Theory, Experiences and Implications for the EFTA Countries, EFTA, Occasional Paper 17 (Geneva: European Free Trade Association, 1986).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Genberg, Hans, “Exchange Rate Management and Macroeconomic Policy: A National Perspective,” Scandinavian Journal of Economics, Vol. 91 (1989), pp. 43969.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Genberg, Hans, “In the Shadow of the Mark: Exchange Rate and Monetary Policy in Austria and Switzerland,” in Choosing an Exchange Rate Regime: The Challenge for Smaller Industrial Countries, ed. by Victor Argy and Paul De Grauwe (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1990), pp. 179219.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Giavazzi, Francesco, and Marco Pagano, “The Advantage of Tying One’s Hands: EMS Discipline and Central Bank Credibility,” Centre for Economic Policy Discussion Paper No. 135 (October 1986).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Giavazzi, Francesco, and Marco Pagano, and Alberto Giovannini, Limiting Exchange Rate Flexibility: The European Monetary System (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press, 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Giavazzi, Francesco, and Marco Pagano, and others, eds., The European Monetary System (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1988).

  • Gislason, Hjörtur, “Iceland’s Life-Blood,” EFTA Bulletin (March 1987), pp. 113.

  • Gros, Daniel, and Niels Thygesen, “The EMS: Achievement, Current Issues and Directions for the Future,” CEPS Paper, No. 35 (Brussels: Center for Economic Policy Studies, 1988).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Guitián, Manuel, “The European Monetary System: A Balance Between Rules and Discretion,” Part I in Policy Coordination in the European Monetary System, Occasional Paper 61 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1988).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gylfason, Thorvaldur, “Exchange Rate Policy, Inflation, and Unemployment: The Nordic EFTA Countries,” in Choosing an Exchange Rate Regime: The Challenge for Smaller Industrial Countries, ed. by Victor Argy and Paul De Grauwe (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Haaland, Jan, and Victor Norman, EFTA and the World Economy, EFTA Occasional Paper 19 (Geneva: European Free Trade Association, 1987).

  • Haberler, Gottfried, “The International Monetary System: Some Recent Developments and Discussion,” in Approaches to Greater Flexibility of Exchange Rates, ed. by George Halm (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1970), pp. 11523.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Haltunen, Hannu, Stabilization Policies in the EFTA Countries, EFTA Occasional Paper 4 (Geneva: European Free Trade Association, 1984).

  • Hauser, Heinz, and others, “Die Schweiz vor dem EG-Binnenmarkt,” Aussenwirtschaft, Vol. 43 (1988), pp. 32766.

  • Helm, Dieter, and Stephen Smith, “The Assessment: Economic Integration and the Role of the European Community,” Oxford Review of Economic Policy, Vol. 5 (1989), pp. 119.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Helpman, Elhanan, “The Factor Content of Foreign Trade,” The Economic Journal, Vol. 94 (1984), pp. 8494.

  • Helpman, Elhanan, and Paul Krugman, Market Structure and Foreign Trade (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press, 1985).

  • Helpman, Elhanan, and Paul Krugman, Trade Policy and Market Structure (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press, 1989).

  • Herin, Jan, Rules of Origin and Differences between Tariff Levels in EFTA and in the EC, EFTA Occasional Paper 13 (Geneva: European Free Trade Association, 1986).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ingram, James C, “Comment: The Currency Area Problem,” in Monetary Problems of the International Economy, ed. by Robert A. Mundell and Alexander K. Swoboda (Chicago: Chicago University Press, 1969).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, Exchange Arrangements and Exchange Restrictions Annual Report 1989 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, Direction of Trade Statistics (Washington: International Monetary Fund, various issues).

  • International Monetary Fund, Government Finance Statistics Yearbook 1989 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1989).

  • International Monetary Fund, International Financial Statistics (Washington: International Monetary Fund, various issues).

  • “Joint Communiqué of the Meeting between EFTA Ministers and the EC Commission of June 15, 1988,” in Twenty-Eighth Annual Report of the European Free Trade Association (Geneva: European Free Trade Association, 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • “Joint Conclusions of the Meeting between EFTA Ministers and the EC Commission on June 15, 1988 in Tampere,” Europa-Archiv, Folge 19/1988, Doc. 569.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • “Joint Declaration of Ministers of the EFTA and EC Countries,” EFTA Bulletin (February 1988).

  • “Keine Alternative zu EWS-Beitritt der EFTA,” VWD-Finanz und Wirtschaftsspiegel, (April 13, 1988); reprinted in Deutsche Bundesbank, Auszüge aus Presseartikeln, No. 25/15, April 1989.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kelly, Margaret, and others, Issues and Development in International Trade Policy, Occasional Paper 63 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1988).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kenen, Peter B., “The Theory of Optimum Currency Areas: An Eclectic View,” in Monetary Problems of the International Economy, ed. by Robert A. Mundell and Alexander K. Swoboda (Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, 1969).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kenen, Peter B., “Macroeconomic Theory and Policy: How the Closed Economy was Opened,” in Handbook of International Economics, Vol. 2, ed. by Ronald W. Jones and Peter B. Kenen (Amsterdam: Elsevier, 1985).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Key, Sidney, “Financial Integration in the European Community,” International Finance Discussion Papers 349 (Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kleppe, Per, “Prospects for a New Type of EFTA-EC Cooperation,” Economic Review, Kansallis-Osake-Pankki (Finland: February 1989), pp. 510.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kotilainen, Markku, and Tapio Peura, “Finland’s Exchange Rate System and European Integration,” Economic Review, Kansallis-Osake-Pankki (Finland: January 1989), pp. 3644.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kremers, Jeroen J.M., “Gaining Policy Credibility in the EMS: The Case of Ireland,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 37 (1990), pp. 11645.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Krugman, Paul, “Economic Integration in Europe: Some Conceptual Issues,” in Efficiency, Stability, and Equity: A Strategy for the Evolution of the Economic System of the European Community. A Report by Tommaso Padoa-Schioppa (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1987).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Krugman, Paul, EFTA and 1992, EFTA Occasional Paper 23 (Geneva: European Free Trade Association, 1988).

  • Lane, Timothy, and Liliana Rojas-Suarez, “Credibility, Capital Controls, and the EMS,” IMF Working Paper WP/89/9 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Markusen, James, and Anthony Venables, “Trade Policy with Increasing Returns and Imperfect Competition: Contradictory Results from Competing Assumptions,” Journal of International Economics, Vol. 24 (1988), pp. 299316.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • McKinnon, Ronald I., “Optimum Currency Area,” American Economic Review, Vol. 53 (Nashville, Tennessee: 1963), pp. 71725.

  • Melitz, Jacques, “Monetary Discipline and Cooperation in the European Monetary System: A Synthesis,” in The European Monetary System, ed. by Francesco Giavazzi, Stefano Micossi, and Marcus Miller (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1988).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Moe, Thorvald, “Economic Policies for the 1990s: Can Scandinavian Values and Policy Objectives Be Sustained?” in Festskrift in Honour of Kjell Andersen, ed. by John Llewellyn and Stephen Potter (forthcoming 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mundell, Robert A., “A Theory of Optimum Currency Areas,” American Economic Review, Vol. 51 (Nashville, Tennessee: 1961), pp. 65765.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mundell, Robert A., International Economics (New York: Macmillan, 1968).

  • Nicolas, Florence, Common Standards for Enterprises (Luxembourg: Office for Official Publications of the European Communities, 1988).

  • Noel, Emile, Working Together: The Institutions of the European Community (Luxembourg: Office for Official Publications of the European Communities, 1988).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Norberg, Sven, “The European Economic Space—Some Legal and Institutional Aspects as seen from the EFTA Point of View” (unpublished, Geneva: European Free Trade Association, May 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Norges Offentlige Utredninger, “Penger og kreditt i en omstillingstid. Norsk penge- og kredittpolitikk i aårena som kommer (Oslo: Forvaltningstjenestene Statens Trykningskontor, 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Norman, Victor, “EFTA and the Internal European Market,” Economic Policy, Vol. 4 (1989), pp. 42365.

  • Norwegian Government Committee on EC Matters, Statusrapport: EFTA-EF forhandlingerne (Oslo: Regjeringsutvalget for EF saker, 1990).

  • “Norwegians May Seek EMS Entry,” Financial Times, December 11, 1989.

  • “Officials Agree on Framework for Negotiating Future Ties,” 1992: The External Impact of European Unification, Vol. 1 (Washington: Buraff Publications, November 1989), pp. 23.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Olafsson, Thorsteinn, “Iceland and the European Community,” speech delivered at the Financial Times Conference on Europe and the Nordic Countries, in Stockholm, October 910, 1989.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development, Foreign Trade by Commodities (Paris, various issues).

  • Pelkmans, Jacques, and Alan Winters, Europe’s Domestic Market, Royal Institute of International Affairs, Chatham House Paper 43 (London: Toutledge, 1988).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Pintado, Xavier, and others, Economic Aspects of the European Economic Space, EFTA Occasional Paper 25 (Geneva: European Free Trade Association, 1988).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Pomfret, Richard, “The Theory of Preferential Trading Arrangements,” Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, Vol. 122, (Tubingen: 1986), pp. 43965.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Romer, Paul, “Crazy Explanations for the Productivity Slowdown,” NBER Macroeconomics Annual (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1987).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Russo, Massimo, “Cooperation and Coordination in the EMS—The System at a Crossroad, in The International Monetary System and Economic Development. A Challenge to the International Economic Cooperation. Proceedings from Malente Symposion VII, ed. by Christian Dräger and Lothar Späth (Baden-Baden: Nomos Verlagsgesellschaft, 1988).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Russo, Massimo, and Giuseppe Tullio, “Monetary Coordination Within the European Monetary System: Is There a Rule?” in Policy Coordination in the European Monetary System. Occasional Paper 61 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1988).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Sachverständigenrat zur Begutachtung der gesamt-wirtschaftlichen Entwicklung, Jahresgutachten 1989/90 (“Weichenstellungen für die Neunziger Jahre”) (Stuttgart: Metz-ler-Poeschel, 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Schinasi, Garry T., “European Integration, Exchange Rates and Monetary Reform,” The World Economy, Vol. 12 (December 1989), pp. 389413.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Schlussfolgerungen derEG-EFTA-Steuergruppe, NeueZürcher Zeitung, November 22, 1989.

  • “Schweizerische Notenbank: Absage an Beitritt zum EWS,” Frankfurter Allgemeine Zeitung, October 26, 1988. Reprinted in Deutsche Bundesbank, Auszüge aus Presseartikeln, Nr. 79/27, October 1988, p. 10.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Sedlabanki Islands, “Valutakursudvikling og Valuta—Kurspolitik i de Nordiske Lande,” Det Nordiske Centralbankmode (Reykjavik: June 1988).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Siegler, Heinrich, Dokumentation der europaeischen Integration 1946–61, unter besonderer Beruecksichtigung des EWG-EFTA Verhaeltnisses (Bonn-Wien-Zuerich: 1961).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Skånland, Hermod, “Comment,” in Money and Finance in European Integration, EFTA Seminar (Geneva: European Free Trade Association, 1988).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • “Some Aspects of the EMS,” Excerpts from an Address by the Deputy Governor of the Bank of Sweden, Mr. Thomas Franzén. Reprinted in Review of the Bank for International Settlements, June 15, 1990.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Spencer, Barbara, and James Brander, “International R&D Rivalry and Industrial Strategy,” Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 50 (1983), pp. 70722.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Swedish Ministry of Foreign Affairs, Sweden and West European Integration, Extracts from the Swedish Government’s Bill 1987/88:66, December 1987 (unofficial translation).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Swedish Ministry of Foreign Affairs, Sverige-EFTA-EG 1989: Det vdsteuropeiska integrationsarbetet (Stockholm: Utrikesdepartementet, 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • “The Social Dimension of the Internal Market,” Bulletin of the European Communities, No. 9 (1988), pp. 810.

  • Tower, Edward, and Thomas D. Willett, “The Theory of Optimum Currency Areas and Exchange-Rate Flexibility,” Special Papers in International Economics, No. 11, (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1976).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ungerer, Horst, “The European Monetary System,” IMF Survey, Supplement, (Washington: International Monetary Fund, March 1979).

  • Ungerer, Horst, “The EMS—The First Ten Years. Policies—Developments—Evolution,” European University Institute, Working Paper ECO No. 90/2 (Florence: 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ungerer, Horst, The European Monetary System: The Experience, 1979–82, Occasional Paper 19 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1983).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ungerer, Horst, and others, The European Monetary System: Recent Developments, Occasional Paper 48 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1986).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ungerer, Horst, and others, The European Monetary System: Developments and Perspectives, Occasional Paper 73 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Végh, Carlos A., and Pablo E. Guidotti, “Optimal Taxation Policies in the EMS. A Two-Country Model of Public Finance,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 37 (June 1990), pp. 31137.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Venables, Anthony, “Customs Unions, Tariff Reform, and Trade in Differentiated Products,” CEPR Discussion Paper 38 (1985) (London: Centre for Economic Policy Research, 1985).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Venables, Anthony, and Alisdair Smith, “Completing the Internal Market in the European Community: Some Industry Simulations,” CEPR Discussion Paper 233 (London: Centre for Economic Policy Research, 1988).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Virén, Matti, Interest Rates, Capital Movements and Monetary Autonomy in the EFTA Countries, EFTA Occasional Paper 26 (Geneva: European Free Trade Association, 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Wieser, Thomas, Price Differentials in the European Economic Space (EES), EFTA Occasional Paper 29 (Geneva: European Free Trade Association, 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Wijkman, Per Magnus, Policy Options Facing EFTA, EFTA Occasional Paper 22 (Geneva: European Free Trade Association, 1988).

  • Winters, Alan, Completing the European Internal Market: Some Notes on Trade Policy, CEPR Discussion Paper 222 (London: Centre for Economic Policy Research, 1988).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation