Notes
Chapter 2 Global Cycles: Toward a Better Understanding
Gross domestic product (GDP) is the total value of output (that is, all goods and services) produced within a country during a given period. GDP per capita is the average income of a citizen in a country and is often used as a measure of a country’s standard of living (Callen 2008). Coyle 2014 provides a detailed history of the concept of GDP and discusses its strengths and weaknesses. We use “output” and “GDP” interchangeably. Appendix A includes a glossary of acronyms and abbreviations used in the book.
The definition of the national business cycle goes back to the seminal study conducted by Arthur Burns and Wesley Mitchell in the 1940s. Arthur Burns served as the chairman of the U.S. Council of Economic Advisers (1953–1956), chairman of the U.S. Federal Reserve (1970–1978), and ambassador to West Germany (1981–1985, see the New York Times, 1987). Wesley Mitchell was one of the founders of the National Bureau of Economic Research—NBER (Burns 1952). The book by Burns and Mitchell Measuring Business Cycles was published in 1947 and became the seminal study describing the statistical methods of business cycle analysis employed by the NBER.
Economists have studied a wide range of real and financial factors that can drive national business cycle fluctuations: technological developments (productivity shocks), policies (shocks associated with fiscal, monetary, financial, and structural policies), movements in factors of production (labor and capital), disturbances in financial markets, fluctuations in commodity prices, political developments, news, changes in consumer confidence, and uncertainty. In a similar fashion, these same factors can play important roles in driving global business cycles because national shocks transmit across borders. We survey different branches of the literature on the global business cycles in a FOCUS box later in this chapter, the linkages between globalization and business cycle synchronization in Chapter 7, and the transmission of business cycles in Chapter 11.
Prior to the global financial crisis, there was fierce debate about whether business cycles in emerging market economies could “decouple” from advanced economies and keep global growth at a reasonable rate. This debate led to a number of studies about the growth potential of emerging market economies and their dependence on advanced economies (Kose and Prasad 2010; King 2010; Magnus 2011; Spence 2011; World Bank 2011; O’Neill 2011; Sharma 2012).
Rather than analyze the evolution and implications of the global financial crisis, we consider a broader topic here and study the global recessions and recoveries since 1960. The 2007–09 global financial crisis has been studied from different vantage points (Bosworth and Flaaen 2009; Swagel 2009; Krugman 2009a; Wessel 2010; Lewis 2010; Paulson 2011; Rajan 2011; Roubini and Mihm 2011; Sorkin 2011; Gorton 2012; Obstfeld, Cho, and Mason 2012; Blinder 2013; Bernanke 2013; Obstfeld 2013; Geithner 2014; Claessens and others 2014). Lo (2012) reviews a set of 21 books on the global financial crisis. Swagel (2013) also presents a short survey of a selected list of books on the financial crisis.
Understanding the similarities of business cycle fluctuations across countries has long been a subject of interest to macroeconomists. See Hirata, Kose, and Otrok 2013 for a review of recent studies and Zarnovitz 1992 for a survey of the earlier research program. Leamer (2009) presents a nice description of the U.S. business cycles.
Stock and Watson 2005; Canova, Ciccarelli, and Ortega 2007; Mumtaz, Simonelli, and Surico 2011; Kose, Otrok, and Whiteman 2003, 2008; and Kose, Otrok, and Prasad 2012 analyze the importance of global factors in explaining business cycles. Other studies consider the role of international business cycle linkages using a variety of approaches (Gerlach 1988; Norrbin and Schlagenhauf 1996; Gregory, Head, and Raynauld 1997; Gregory and Head 1999; Lumsdaine and Prasad 2003; Yilmaz 2010; Diebold and Yilmaz 2014).
Ambler, Cardia, and Zimmermann 2004; Imbs 2004; Bordo and Helbling 2004; Baxter and Kouparitsas 2005; and Kose, Prasad, and Terrones 2003a, 2009a document the highly correlated nature of national business cycles.
For a detailed analysis of these findings and a review of the literature on regional cycles, see Hirata, Kose, and Otrok 2013. For research on European business cycles, see de Haan, Inklaar, and Jong-A-Pin 2008. For research on the North American, Latin American, and Central American cycles, see Bergman, Bordo, and Jonung 1998; Kose, Meredith, and Towe 2005; Kose and Rebucci 2005; and Aiolfi, CatÃo, and Timmermann 2011. For research on the Asian business cycles, see Moneta and Rüffer 2009 and He and Liao 2012; and on the African cycles, see Tapsoba 2009 and Ncube, Brixiova, and Meng 2014.
Chapter 3 Tools of the Trade
We emphasize the global nature of our database since most of the earlier studies focus only on a smaller set of countries when they consider global business cycles. In fact, our study is the first to include such a large number of countries and a rich collection of variables.
A number of studies analyze the similarities and differences between the 2009 global recession and the Great Depression, such as Eichengreen and O’Rourke 2009; Romer 2009a; Helbling 2009; and Eichengreen 2015. These studies draw attention to the surprising similarities between the two episodes, especially during the early stages of the Great Recession.
The emerging market economies in our sample roughly correspond to those in the MSCI Emerging Markets Index. The main differences between our sample and that of the MSCI are that, due to the data limitations, we drop some countries, while we include other, relatively more “mature” emerging market economies since the sample starts in 1960. Emerging market economies on average had higher incomes per capita and experienced faster growth rates than other developing economies over the last two decades. In addition, the trade openness ratio for emerging market economies has risen rapidly over the past two decades (Kose and Prasad 2010).
The IMF often uses this measure of world growth in its World Economic Outlook. It is possible to consider alternative measures using different types of weighting schemes, but those generally portray qualitatively similar dynamics to the one we have here. One could also directly construct a series of world GDP (in purchasing-power-parity or market exchange rates), but it would be difficult to relate such a series to the growth rates of national GDP. Our measure is intuitively appealing because it provides a natural parallel between national and global growth.
We present the decadal averages of these weights for each country group in Appendix C. The temporal evolution of the weights shows the rising role of emerging market economies in the world economy, and this is especially pronounced for purchasing-power-parity weights. Callen 2007 explains the implications of purchasing-power-parity- and market-rates-based measures of GDP.
Bry and Boschan (1971) first introduced this method. Harding and Pagan (2002) extended it to identify the turning points in quarterly series. This dating algorithm is widely used in the cross-country context (Artis, Kontolemis, and Osborn 1997; Artis, Marcellino, and Proietti 2003; Cotis and Coppel 2005; Hall and McDermott 2007; and Claessens, Kose, and Terrones 2008a, 2009, 2012). The algorithm is also used in the analysis of cycles in credit and asset prices (Claessens, Kose, and Terrones 2008b, 2011a, 2011b; Pagan and Sossounov 2003). It is possible to employ a different algorithm, such as a Markov Switching (MS) model (Hamilton 1989), to date the turning points. Harding and Pagan (2002) compare this method with their algorithm and conclude that their algorithm is preferable because the MS model depends on the validity of the underlying statistical framework. Hamilton (2003) also presents a discussion of this issue.
Other methodologies consider how a variable fluctuates around its trend and then identify the cycles (or output gaps) as deviations from this trend. The addition of new data, however, can affect the estimated trend, and thus the identification of a cycle in these methodologies. Many studies have also documented that the features of growth cycles can depend on the detrending method used (Canova 1998). In addition, it is difficult to determine the deviation from trend (the output gap) in real time. Blanchard and Fischer (1989) explain the benefits of the Burns-Mitchell approach: “Much of the recent work has proceeded, instead, under the assumption that variables follow linear stochastic processes with constant coefficients… this has had the advantage of allowing for better integration of macroeconomic theory and econometrics. In return for this integration and for well-understood statistical properties, some of the richness of the Burns-Mitchell analysis, such as its focus on asymmetries between recession, and expansions or its notion of business cycle time (as opposed to calendar time) may well have been lost.”
We also employ this statistical method when we consider the dates of business cycles in the quarterly frequency in some of the chapters. We provide additional information on this whenever we discuss these results.
The NBER (2013) notes that its Business Cycle Dating Committee does not accept the two-quarter definition because “The committee’s procedure for identifying turning points differs from the two-quarter rule in a number of ways. First, we do not identify economic activity solely with real GDP and real GDI (gross disposable income), but use a range of other indicators as well. Second, we place considerable emphasis on monthly indicators in arriving at a monthly chronology. Third, we consider the depth of the decline in economic activity. Recall that our definition includes the phrase, ‘a significant decline in activity.’ Fourth, in examining the behavior of domestic production, we consider not only the conventional product-side GDP estimates, but also the conceptually equivalent income-side GDI estimates. The differences between these two sets of estimates were particularly evident in the recessions of 2001 and 2007–2009.”
The NBER (2003) defines a recession as “a significant decline in activity spread across the economy, lasting more than a few months, visible in industrial production, employment, real income, and wholesale-retail trade. A recession begins just after the economy reaches a peak of activity and ends as the economy reaches its trough.” The CEPR (2003) employs similar language: “a significant decline in the level of economic activity, spread across the economy of the euro area, usually visible in two or more consecutive quarters of negative growth in GDP, employment and other measures of aggregate economic activity for the euro area as a whole; and reflecting similar developments in most countries.”
The simple rule of “two consecutive quarters of decline in real GDP” at the national level follows the definition by Julius Shiskin in the New York Times in 1974 (Abberger and Nierhaus 2008). Claessens and Kose (2009) present a detailed explanation of national recessions. Blanchard (2001) briefly analyzes different types of recessions and argues that “Three types of recessions exist. The first type are those caused by major shocks, say an outbreak of war or a sudden, sharp increase in the price of petroleum. Recall that the OPEC [Organization of the Petroleum Exporting Countries] oil shocks of the 1970’s incited two world recessions. The second category of recessions arises by chance, for example when consumer confidence dips, or businesses become uneasy and cut back on investment and/or inventory. This was the cause of America’s recession in the early 1990’s. The third type of recession occurs when imbalances in an economy build up to unsustainable levels before exploding. This form of recession is sometimes characterized by vast increases in debt (corporate or consumer), or by dizzying stock market or capital asset speculations that eventually come crashing down. The ‘popping’ of such an asset bubble is what happened in Japan 10 years ago, an event from which that country has not yet recovered. Recessions of the first type are, almost by definition, largely unpredictable. Those of the second type are minor and relatively easy to repair if not to avoid. All that they usually require is a reduction in interest rates or a bit of reflation. Recessions of the third kind are the most worrying.” Lucas (2012) presents a simpler view about the sources of recessions: “I now believe that the evidence on post-war recessions (up to but not including the one we are now in) overwhelmingly supports the dominant importance of real shocks. But I remain convinced of the importance of financial shocks in the 1930s and the years after 2008. Of course, this means I have to renounce the view that business cycles are all alike!”
In the context of national cycles, a number of studies examine the dynamics of recoveries (Eckstein and Sinai 1986; Balke and Wynne 1995; Mussa 2009; Terrones, Scott, and Kannan 2009; Claessens, Kose, and Terrones 2012). Some define the recovery as the time it takes for output to rebound from the trough to the peak level before the recession. Others associate recovery with the growth achieved after a certain period, such as four or six quarters, following the trough (Sichel 1994).
See Rogoff, Robinson, and Bayoumi 2002 for the study. Rogoff (2002a) announced the findings of their study at the World Economic Outlook press conference.
Kose, Loungani, and Terrones (2009, 2012) extend the study by Rogoff, Robinson, and Bayoumi (2002) and provide a framework for analyzing global recessions and recoveries. Kose and Terrones (forthcoming) build on these earlier studies and summarize the main features of global recessions and recoveries.
Chapter 4 Dates and Events: What Happened When?
See Claessens, Kose, and Terrones 2012.
Some have employed the definition of global recession that relied on a simple threshold over the years. For example, The Economist (2001b) noted that “there is no precise definition of ‘world recession’ (global output has risen every year since the 1930s), but it is generally taken to be growth of less than 2–2.5 percent.” There was confusion about the definition of global recession used by the IMF, as The Economist (2008a) noted: “according to the IMF’s most recent World Economic Outlook, published on October 8th, the world economy is ‘entering a major downturn’ in the face of ‘the most dangerous shock’ to rich-country financial markets since the 1930s. The Fund expects global growth, measured on the basis of purchasing power parity, to come down to 3 percent in 2009, the slowest pace since 2002 and on the verge of what it considers to be a global recession. (The IMF’s definition of global recession takes many factors into account, including the rate of population growth.)”
Those 14 years include the following episodes: 1974–75, 1980–83, 1991–93, 1998, 2001–02, and 2008–09. If one uses market weights, the list includes 1974–75, 1980–83, 1990–93, 1995, 1998, 2001–03, 2008–09, and 2011–13.
With purchasing-power-parity weights and a 1 percent threshold, the list of global recessions includes 1974–75, 1980–82, 1991–93, and 2009. With market weights and a 1 percent threshold, the list contains 1974–75, 1980–82, 1991–93, 1998, 2001–02, and 2008–09. The Economist (2008b) notes the difficulty of identifying global recessions with a single threshold tied to global GDP growth: “When tracking such diverse economies, it does make much more sense to define a global recession not as an absolute fall in GDP, but as when growth falls significantly below its potential rate. This can cause anomalies, however. Using the IMF’s definition (i.e., growth below 3 percent), the world economy has been in recession for no fewer than 11 out of 28 years. This sits oddly with the fact that America, the world’s biggest economy, has been in recession for only 38 months during that time, according to the National Bureau of Economic Research (the country’s official arbiter of recessions), which defines a recession as a decline in economic activity. It is confusing to have different definitions of recession in rich and poor economies.” It is important to note that the IMF does not have an institutional definition of global recession endorsed by its Executive Board. Although the IMF’s World Economic Outlook has occasionally studied the topic, the publication reflects the views of the IMF staff and, hence, should not be attributed to IMF executive directors or their national authorities.
In our sample, growth of world GDP was positive in all years except 2009. During the 2009 global recession, a market observer, Philip Suttle, correctly noted that “We have got the world economy contracting by just under a half percentage point, which really does not sound like very much… But it is really, really important to recognize the world economy basically never contracts. Somewhere in the world economy there is always enough [growth] to offset recessions even in the major industrial countries” (Voice of America 2009).
Blanchard (2008) argued that “it is not useful to use the word ‘recession’ when the world is growing at 3 percent. In the normal definition of things, recession is a negative number, and that is not the case. This being said, 3 percent is a very low number for world growth, and in the past, indeed, this might have been defined as on the borderline of a global recession. I think the words, ‘global downturn with still positive growth,’ are a better description of what we are facing.”
Rogoff, Robinson, and Bayoumi (2002) also concluded that a global recession took place in 1975, 1982, and 1991. Rogoff (2002a) announced the findings of their study at the World Economic Outlook press conference: “… we looked closely at the question of what constitutes a global recession, and concluded—looking at per capita output growth as well as many other variables such as world trade and industrial production—that the years 1975, 1982, and 1991 did, officially, constitute global recessions.”
According to the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) chronology, since 1960, the United States experienced eight recessions: 1960:Q2–1961:Q1, 1969:Q4–1970:Q4, 1973:Q4–1975:Q1, 1980:Q1–1980:Q3, 1981:Q3–1982:Q4, 1990:Q3–1991:Q1, 2001:Q1–2001:Q4, and 2007:Q4–2009:Q2.
Knoop 2004, Reinhart and Rogoff 2009, and Allen 2010 discuss the events during these episodes. For a detailed analysis of the surrounding macroeconomic and financial developments, see the IMF’s World Economic Outlook, Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development’s (OECD’s) Global Economic Outlook, and World Bank’s Global Economic Prospects published in the years of the global recessions.
We list the countries that experienced financial crises around global recessions and downturns in Appendix D.
The 1975 episode was also compared with the Great Depression. The Economist (1974b) noted that “As in 1929, collapses have come first in precisely the sectors where it was thought during the boom that it was easiest for any idiot to become a millionaire. In early 1972, it would have been thought ridiculous to say that bankruptcy would hit first at beef barons, property speculators, stockbrokers, whizz-kids’ new sorts of banks. But stock market crashes have now already gone further than those in 1929. Property prices have collapsed, transmitting strain to the financial system through the fringe banks and towards banks within the fringe… Paradoxically the most important difference produced the greatest similarity. Inflation is doing to the world economy of 1970s what falling prices did in the 1930s—causing unemployment and company failures… One big difference between 1929 is that this slump has been signaled well in advance, and still a real crash has not come… Remember that in 1929 the federal government’s purchases of goods and services amounted to a tiny 1.25 percent of America’s (gross national product), so that a big Keynesian fiscal restimulation was not easy then. But in a slump accompanied by huge price inflation big fiscal restimulation is not going to be easy either.”
During the stagflation era of the 1970s, debates raged about the likelihood of a deep recession. As it is now, “depression” was a sensitive term then and led to a humorous search to replace it with an attractive alternative, as described by Time (1978): “Maverick Economist Alfred Kahn has a penchant for candor that is both refreshing and dangerous in Washington. When he said that there is the possibility of a ‘deep, deep depression’ if inflation continues to soar, the President was furious. Kahn responded by purging the word depression from his vocabulary and instead using ‘banana.’ So he now says: ‘We’re in danger of having the worst banana in 45 years.’” Kahn was an economist who worked in the Carter Administration as chairman of the Civil Aeronautics Board and chairman of the Council on Wage and Price Stability (Lang 2010). Golden (1975) and Shabecoff (1975) discuss whether the 1975 episode was a recession or a depression. Mullaney (1977) documents the debates about the weak recovery following the 1975 global recession.
Hamilton (2009a) claims that oil prices increased prior to all global recessions, including the latest. Hamilton (2009b) examines the role played by oil price increases before the last recession in the United States. Blinder and Rudd (2012) present evidence that supply shocks stemming from significant movements in oil and food prices during 1973–74 and 1978–80 played important roles in driving inflation in the United States (and the recessions associated with these episodes). Barsky and Kilian (2004) and Hamilton (2011) present surveys of the history of oil shocks and the downturns that followed these shocks. Baffes and others (2015) analyze the sharp decline in oil prices over the period June 2014-January 2015 and compare the latest episode with the earlier ones.
Even before its start, media articles compared the 1982 global recession with the Great Depression: “This month sees the fiftieth anniversary of the international economic crisis of September, 1931, when the world suddenly threw away its main safeguard against long-term inflation and its principal previous weapon against short-term slump. There may not be full recovery from 1981’s slumpflation until this safeguard and weapon are in some degree reestablished, so it is awkward that most of today’s statesmen do not remember what they were” (The Economist 1981a).
In the United States, the implementation of contractionary monetary policies was led by Paul Volcker, who became the chairman of the Federal Reserve Board in August 1979 (Meltzer 2010). The Volcker disinflation reduced annual inflation from 9 percent in 1979 to 5 percent by the end of 1983. The United States experienced two consecutive recessions with large declines in output and employment during the same period (Goodfriend and King 2005). Kenen (1983) links the debt crisis to the high-interest-rate policies of the advanced economies.
Kuczynski (1982) presents a nice narrative of the events leading up to the Latin American debt crisis: “The music has stopped. In August, Mexico, the largest single recipient of Eurocurrency bank credits in recent years, announced that it could not for the time being meet its scheduled repayments of principal on the external debt of the public sector. Service on the Mexican private sector and banking system debt is sporadic or interrupted because of the shortage of foreign exchange. Argentina has in effect been unable to meet its scheduled debt service since the time of the South Atlantic conflict. And, since mid-1982, international bank lending to Latin American countries has all but ground to a halt. As a result, Brazil may find it very difficult to meet its scheduled debt service, since, like the other countries in the area, it needs a constant inflow of funds to pay off old debt.”
The following Latin American countries experienced financial crises around the 1982 global recession: Argentina, Bolivia, Brazil, Chile, Costa Rica, the Dominican Republic, Ecuador, Guyana, Honduras, Mexico, Nicaragua, Panama, Paraguay, Uruguay, and Venezuela. Dornbusch, Johnson, and Krueger 1988 and Edwards 1995 provide reviews of the Latin American debt crisis. Since many developing economies in other regions also experienced crises, some observers called this episode the Less Developed Country Debt Crisis.
In 1991, some speculated that the recession would be a milder one because of the differential growth prospects across countries. “Similarly, the so-called ‘desynchronization’ of the big economies, which has helped to prevent global recession, may now moderate the recovery. As America and Britain sank into recession last year, Japan and Germany continued to boom, helping to prop up world demand. But, as America and Britain start to recover, the former locomotives are losing steam. With growth in both Germany and Japan in 1991 likely to be barely half that in 1990, this will trim the growth in their imports from the rest of the world” (The Economist 1991). Fuerbringer (1991) discusses the implications of the U.S. recession for the global economy. The impact of the global recession was indeed felt across Europe in 1992, with a number of countries falling into recessions because of the European Exchange Rate Mechanism (ERM) crisis.
For detailed discussions of the savings and loan crisis in the United States, see FDIC 1997; Curry and Shibut 2000; and Barth, Trimbath, and Yago 2004.
Bernanke and Lown (1991) provide a careful study of the evolution of credit markets during this episode. For a discussion of the importance of household debt during this episode, see Altig, Byrne, and Samolyk 1992. Walsh 1993; Blanchard 1993; Hall 1993; and Hansen and Prescott 1993 analyze the sources of the 1990:Q3–1991:Q1 recession in the United States. Mian and Sufi (2014) analyze how the accumulation of large household debt followed by a sharp drop in household spending led to a deep global recession in 2009.
The ERM was established in 1979 by eight members of the European Economic Community (Belgium, Denmark, France, Germany, Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg, Netherlands) to minimize exchange rate fluctuations within a band by fixing their exchange rates relative to one another and floating jointly against the U.S. dollar. Spain, Portugal, and the United Kingdom joined the ERM later. The ERM was designed as an intermediate step before the introduction of the euro. Higgins (1993) and Buiter, Corsetti, and Pesenti (1998) analyze the sources and implications of the ERM crisis.
Fischer, Sahay, and Végh 1996; IMF 2000; and Orlowski 2001 present detailed accounts of the many challenges the transition economies experienced in the early 1990s.
In late 1992, amid intense debate about growth forecasts, comparisons with the Great Depression were back in the headlines: “Needless to say, all this may turn out to be—like most forecasts during the past year—too optimistic. But that is still very far from saying that a depression like the one in the 1930s may be on the way. For a slowdown to become a slump, extra things need to go badly wrong—and governments can make this unlikely. Lessons from the Depression have been learnt, as the response to the global stock market crash of October 19th, 1987 showed. First and foremost, today’s central bankers understand their duties as lenders of last resort. That makes a contagious financial collapse of the sort that preceded the depression of the 1930s much less likely… Moreover, today’s governments account for a far bigger share of their countries’ national incomes than they did 60 years ago. A trend that is in many ways regrettable should console those inclined to slit their wrists just in case: these days much more of the economy is slump-proof. Thanks to the welfare state when output falls and unemployment rises, the victims (and the economy at large) are cushioned. In the 1930s, some governments raised taxes and cut public spending as the Depression grew worse. That is a mistake which is unlikely to be repeated, less because no government would try to do it than because their electorates would not let them… A third lesson from the 1930s, though familiar, demands the undivided attention of governments in the coming days and weeks: perhaps the best way to turn a recession into something far worse is to arrange an outbreak of protectionism. Off and on for months, the governments have seemed likely to do just that… If, despite everything, governments let the Uruguay round slip through their fingers, they will be helping to make the world’s worst economic nightmare come needlessly true” (The Economist 1992b).
Claessens, Kose, and Terrones (2010) and Mendoza and Terrones (2012) discuss the evolution of financial markets during the last episode.
Even in late 2008, discussions about the severity of the coming global recession started appearing in the media: “Where does that leave us today? America’s GDP may have fallen by an annualized 6 percent in the fourth quarter of 2008, but most economists dismiss the likelihood of a 1930s-style depression or a repeat of Japan in the 1990s, because policy makers are unlikely to repeat the mistakes of the past. In the Great Depression, the Fed let hundreds of banks fail and the money supply shrink by one-third, while the government tried to balance its budget by cutting spending and raising taxes. America’s monetary and fiscal easing this time has been more aggressive than Japan’s in the 1990s. However, these reassurances come from many of the same economists who said that a nationwide fall in American house prices was impossible and that financial innovation had made the financial system more resilient. Hopefully, they will be right this time. But this crisis was caused by the largest asset-price and credit bubble in history—even bigger than that in Japan in the late 1980s or America in the late 1920s. Policymakers will not make the same mistakes as in the 1930s, but they may make new ones (The Economist 2008b).
Many articles documented the spread of the recession in early 2009: “Manufacturing deteriorated around the world in December, signaling a worsening global recession… The euro-area’s gauge fell to a record low, while industry in China contracted for a fifth month. Indicators for the U.K., Sweden, Hong Kong and Australia also showed factories in decline. The ISM’s (Institute of Supply Management’s) gauge of new orders dropped to the lowest level since records began in 1948” (Chandra 2009).
The latest episode was also compared with the Great Depression, and a number of similarities were documented, especially for the early stages of these two episodes. For example, Eichengreen and O’Rourke (2009) note that “the world is currently undergoing an economic shock every bit as big as the Great Depression shock of 1929–30.” For an extended discussion of similarities and differences between the episodes, see Almunia and others 2010 and Bordo 2012b. For more information on the Great Depression, see Temin 1991 and Eichengreen 1996. Solomou (1998) discusses economic cycles since 1870 and lists many studies on various aspects of the Great Depression.
Rowen (1974) nicely articulates this observation in the Washington Post: “In the immediate future, the policy makers will have to be worrying not about demand and how to sustain it or moderate it, but also shortages of supply. It is much more difficult to shape policies that deal with a recession produced not because people fail to buy goods—but because the factories cannot get enough fuel to keep things going.”
Lucas and Sargent (1978) provide a perceptive critique of Keynesian economics in light of the events of the 1970s and explain the fundamentals of the “rational expectations revolution” in macroeconomics that became influential during the late 1970s. Miller (1994) presents a rich list of essays that describe the origins and growth of this revolution. Romer and Romer (2002) and Sargent (2002) examine the evolution of stabilization policies over the past 50 years. Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City 2002 provides a set of insightful papers on the design, objectives, and implications of fiscal and monetary policies. Blanchard (2009a) presents a brief summary of the major changes in macroeconomics during the 1970s.
Rotemberg (2013) notes that the 1960s and 1970s were often called the “Great Inflation” period because of the Federal Reserve’s inflation tolerance. He argues that this period ended with the famous Volcker disinflation of 1979–1982. The period that followed, 1982–2007, was a period of inflation intolerance.
Economists extensively debated the sources of the decline in the volatility of macroeconomic fluctuations in a number of advanced economies (Blanchard and Simon 2001; Ahmed, Levin, and Wilson 2004; Bernanke 2004; Davis and Kahn 2008).
There has been vigorous debate over the past seven years about macroeconomists’ inability to predict the global financial crisis and develop the necessary policy measures to mitigate its adverse effects. Krugman (2009b) criticizes the macroeconomics literature for its failure to recognize the strong linkages between the financial sector and the real economy: “During the golden years, financial economists came to believe that markets were inherently stable—indeed, that stocks and other assets were always priced just right… Meanwhile, macroeconomists were divided in their views… Unfortunately, this romanticized and sanitized vision of the economy led most economists to ignore all the things that can go wrong. They [economists] turned a blind eye to the limitations of human rationality that often lead to bubbles and busts; to the problems of institutions that run amok; to the imperfections of markets—especially financial markets—that can cause the economy’s operating system to undergo sudden, unpredictable crashes.” Cochrane (2009a) provides a critical response to Krugman’s views: “First, he [Krugman] argues for a future of economics that ‘recognizes flaws and frictions,’ and incorporates alternative assumptions about behavior, especially towards risk-taking. To which I say, ‘Hello, Paul, where have you been for the last 30 years?’… Pretty much all we have been doing for 30 years is introducing flaws, frictions and new behaviors, especially new models of attitudes to risk, and comparing the resulting models, quantitatively, to data. The long literature on financial crises and banking… has also been doing exactly the same.” Rodrik (2015) emphasizes the importance of selecting the “correct model” to analyze the question at hand and notes that “the profession’s internal critics are wrong to claim that the discipline has gone wrong because economists have yet to reach consensus on the “correct” models (their preferred ones of course). Let us cherish economics in all its diversity – rational and behavioral, Keynesian and Classical, first-best and second-best, orthodox and heterodox – and devote our energy to becoming wiser at picking which framework to apply when.” Caballero 2010, Woodford 2010, and other papers in the fall 2010 issue of the Journal of Economic Perspectives analyze how the recent crisis may affect research on the intersection between macroeconomics and finance. Gordon 2009; Kocherlakota 2010; Turner 2012; Blanchard, Dell’Ariccia, and Mauro 2010, 2013; and Blanchard and others 2012 discuss in detail the impact of the financial crisis on the design of macroeconomic policies. Claessens and Kose (2014a, 2014b) analyze the linkages between the financial sector and real economy in light of the debates after the global financial crisis.
For extensive discussions of the similarities and differences between the last and earlier crises, see Claessens, Kose, and Terrones 2010. Blanchard 2009b; Brunnermeier 2009; Calomiris 2009; Cecchetti 2009; Reinhart and Rogoff 2008; Shin 2009; Mankiw 2012; Gourinchas and Obstfeld 2012; and Calomiris and Haber 2014 analyze the evolution of the crisis from various angles. Claessens and Kose 2014c present a synthesis of the sources and implications of various types of crisis.
Chapter 5 Global Recessions: Sad Stories of Collapse
Other names were also given to the latest episode: Krugman (2011a) called it the “Lesser Depression,” DeLong (2011a) the “Little Depression,” and Reinhart and Rogoff (2009) the “Second Great Contraction.”
The relatively low rate of global unemployment prior to the 1974 episode is mostly due to very low unemployment in advanced economies.
Baldwin and Evenett 2009; BussiÈre and others 2010; Henn and McDonald 2011; and Bown 2011 study various aspects of protectionist measures introduced during the 2009 global recession.
The collapse of trade (relative to output) during the global recession is puzzling, in that it was much larger than predicted by the standard business cycle models. For potential explanations of the trade collapse, see Levchenko, Lewis, and Tesar 2010; Bems, Johnson, and Yi 2010; Chor and Manova 2012; Alessandria, Kaboski, and Midrigan 2010; Amiti and Weinstein 2011; Freund 2009; and BussiÈre and others 2013. Gourinchas and Kose 2010, 2011; and Bems, Johnson, and Yi 2012 summarize these explanations.
Milesi-Ferretti and Tille (2011) and Lane (2012) study the links between declines in flows and country-specific features during the global financial crisis. Forbes and Warnock (2012) analyze the sources of large fluctuations in international financial flows.
For the evolution of global and national labor markets since the global recession, see International Labour Organization 2013, 2014.
A number of recent studies have examined the reasons for cross-country differences in the impact of the 2009 global recession (Berkmen and others 2009; Blanchard, Faruqee, and Das 2010; Lane and Milesi-Ferretti 2011; Giannone, Lenza, and Reichlin 2011; Rose and Spiegel 2011; De Gregorio 2014). Kose and Prasad (2010) provide a detailed account of these reasons and surveys the relevant literature.
Jeanne 2007; Durdu, Mendoza, and Terrones 2009; and Independent Evaluation Office of the IMF 2012 discuss the sources and implications of reserve accumulation in emerging market economies.
For a narrative of events that took place around these two downturns, see IMF 1998a, 1998b, 2001a, 2001b, 2001c; and Fischer 1998.
Some declared that all evidence pointed to a looming global recession in 1998: “Is the world headed for recession? Look at the evidence, and it’s difficult to draw any other conclusion. Asia is under water, Russia has collapsed, Latin America is shaky, and the United States and Britain look weaker than expected. When financial panic begins to spread—as it has in recent months, now hitting U.S. shocks—little can be done to stop it. The only tool available to governments is a cut in interest rates to try to stoke the economy. Central banks in the United States and Europe should be ready to take that step if things get much worse” (Journal of Commerce 1998).
In August 2001, The Economist (2001a) claimed that the global economy was already experiencing a recession: “The world economy is probably already in recession. How bad might it get? One by one, economies around the world are stumbling. By cutting interest rates again this week—for the seventh time this year—the Federal Reserve hopes it can keep America out of recession. But in an increasing number of economies, from Japan and Taiwan to Mexico and Brazil, GDP is already shrinking. Global industrial production fell at an annual rate of 6% in the first half of 2001… The picture may soon look even worse. Early estimates suggest that gross world product, as a whole, may have contracted in the second quarter, for possibly the first time in two decades. Welcome to the first global recession of the 21st century.”
See Rogoff, Robinson, and Bayoumi 2002. Rogoff (2002b) presents a nice narrative of the mood of financial market participants and policymakers in early 2002: “Amid increasing signs of recovery, there seems to be a growing denial that the global economy was ever in any real danger. Many private forecasters have stopped asking when the US economy is going to pick up and started asking when it is going to slow down. A popular refrain is that ‘it’s the recession that wasn’t.’ Europeans congratulate themselves that the eurozone only barely experienced negative growth in one quarter. Meanwhile, some in Japan still seem to believe that their country’s third recession in a decade is just a passing phase that can be forgotten as soon as US-led export growth picks up. The reality is that the sharp downturn of the past year was almost a global recession.”
It is difficult to predict the exact date of the beginning of national recessions. Mankiw (2007) notes that “The economy is teetering on the edge. Many economists, as well as online betting sites, put the risk of recession next year at about 50 percent. Once we get the final numbers, we might even learn that a recession has already begun.”
Chapter 6 Global Recoveries: Tales of Revival
The graphs showing the behavior of the macroeconomic and financial variables during global recessions and recoveries in Figures 5.1–5.3 and Figures 6.1–6.3 emphasize the differences in the evolutions of these variables around these episodes. We focus on the period prior to recessions in Figures 5.1–5.3 and the postrecession recoveries in Figures 6.1–6.3. The year prior to the recession is the reference point in the former; in the latter, this is the global recession year.
Specifically, we study the elasticities of world consumption per capita, investment, and trade to world output by estimating a basic regression of the growth rate of each of these variables on the growth rate of world GDP per capita. We report the results of these regressions in Appendix G. Our findings with respect to trade elasticity are consistent with those in Freund 2009.
The first year of the ongoing recovery was strong, but it has since been subject to various headwinds, nicely illustrated by the evolving narrative in the IMF’s World Economic Outlook: “The global recovery is off to a stronger start than anticipated earlier but is proceeding at different speeds in the various regions” (IMF 2010a). “The two-speed recovery continues. In advanced economies, activity has moderated less than expected, but growth remains subdued… In many emerging economies, activity remains buoyant” (IMF 2011a). “The global recovery is threatened by intensifying strains in the euro area and fragilities elsewhere” (IMF 2012a). “Policy action is needed to secure the fragile global recovery” (IMF 2013a). “Global growth is still weak, its underlying dynamics are changing, and the risks to the forecast remain to the downside” (IMF 2013a). “Global activity strengthened during the second half of 2013… But downward revisions to growth forecasts in some economies highlight continued fragilities, and downside risks remain” (IMF 2014a). “Global activity has broadly strengthened and is expected to improve further in 2014–15 with much of the impetus for growth coming from advanced economies. Although downside risks have diminished overall, lower-than-expected inflation poses risks for advanced economies, there is increased financial volatility in emerging market economies, and increases in the cost of capital will likely dampen investment and weigh on growth” (IMF 2014b). “Global growth in 2014 was a modest 3.4 percent, reflecting a pickup in growth in advanced economies relative to the previous year and a slowdown in emerging market and developing economies. Medium-term prospects have become less optimistic for advanced economies, and especially for emerging markets, in which activity has been slowing since 2010. At the same time, the distribution of risks to global growth is now more balanced relative to the October 2014 WEO, but is still tilted to the downside” (IMF 2015a). “Global growth is projected at 3.3 percent in 2015, marginally lower than in 2014, with a gradual pickup in advanced economies and a slowdown in emerging market and developing economies. In 2016, growth is expected to strengthen to 3.8 percent… The distribution of risks to global economic activity is still tilted to the downside. Near-term risks include increased financial market volatility and disruptive asset price shifts, while lower potential output growth remains an important medium-term risk in both advanced and emerging market economies. Lower commodity prices also pose risks to the outlook in low-income developing economies after many years of strong growth” (IMF 2015b).
Kose, Otrok, and Prasad (2012) present a detailed account of the many differences in cyclical performance between advanced and emerging market economies over the past two decades.
For discussions of different aspects of the ongoing weak recovery, see Sachs 2008; Boskin 2009; Shiller 2009; Blanchard 2010; Calvo and Loo-Kung 2010; Wolf 2010b; Feldstein 2010; Davies 2011; DeLong 2011b; Rogoff 2011; Lagarde 2011; Samuelson 2012, 2014; and Fischer 2014.
In other words, Okun’s law, which describes an empirical relationship between GDP growth and changes in the unemployment rate, appears to hold quite well (Ball, Leigh, and Loungani 2013). Industry-by-county-level data on employment in the United States also suggest that the drop in aggregate demand (and income) driven by shocks to household balance sheets was a key factor driving the rise in unemployment during 2007–09 (Mian and Sufi 2012). The global recession had a profound impact on the U.S. labor market as it led to the highest level of long-term unemployment in the postwar period. Elsby, Hobijn, and Sahin (2010) and Elsby and Valletta (2011) describe the evolution of the U.S. labor market during the global recession. Rothstein (2012) argues that cyclical factors, such as shortfalls in aggregate demand for labor, rather than structural factors play an important role in explaining the weak performance of the U.S. labor market during the latest recovery. Daly and others (2013) document how the global financial crisis changed the relationship between unemployment and output in advanced economies. Blanchard, Jaumotte, and Loungani (2013) provide a summary of labor market policies in advanced economies during the latest global recession and recovery. Gourinchas and Kose (2013a, 2013b) provide summaries of a series of studies on the dynamics of labor markets during the global financial crisis and its aftermath. Katz and others (2014) analyze how the long-term unemployment dynamics have changed in the aftermath of the Great Recession.
Prior to both the 2009 global financial crisis and the European Exchange Rate Mechanism (ERM) crisis of the early 1990s, many advanced economies experienced highly synchronized credit booms (Mendoza and Terrones 2012).
Thirteen advanced European economies experienced recessions during this period: Austria, 1992:Q3–1993:Q1; Belgium, 1992:Q2–1993:Q; Denmark, 1992:Q3–1993:Q2; Finland, 1990:Q1–1993:Q2; France, 1992:Q1–1993:Q3; Germany, 1992:Q1–1993:Q1; Greece, 1992:Q2–1993:Q1; Italy, 1992:Q1–1993:Q3; Portugal, 1992:Q2–1993:Q3; Spain, 1992:Q1–1993:Q2; Sweden, 1990:Q1–1993:Q1; Switzerland, 1990:Q2–1991:Q2 and 1991:Q4–1993:Q1; and the United Kingdom, 1990:Q2–1991:Q3.
During the 2009 global financial crisis, 18 advanced European economies experienced recessions. Many of these economies went through double-dip recessions during 2011–13. For recent developments in the euro area business cycle, see CEPR 2012 and 2014.
See Draghi 2012.
For a summary of the human costs of recessions, see Dao and Loungani 2010; for the social costs of financial crises, see van Dijk 2013 and Otker-Robe and Podpiera 2013; and for the implications of recessions for social cohesion, see Giuliano and Spilimbergo 2009. World Bank 2010 considers the implications of the crisis for poverty reduction in developing economies. World Bank 2013 analyzes the jobs crisis triggered by the 2007–09 financial crisis.
The International Labour Organization (2013, 2014) describes the evolution of global and national labor markets since the global recession. For a discussion of the jobs crisis following the 2009 global recession, see OECD 2009, 2012a; Dao and Loungani 2010; Loungani 2012; and World Bank 2013. Atkinson, Luttrell, and Rosenblum (2013) find that because of the 2007–09 financial crisis, the U.S. economy lost at least 40 to 90 percent of its annual output. However, they also consider other cost factors and conclude that “given our range of estimates, the tepid economic recovery, and the litany of other adverse effects stemming from the Second Great Contraction, we suggest that the total domestic cost is likely greater than the equivalent of an entire year’s output.”
It is not a subject we discuss here but one can debate about the logic of having only two business cycle phases. Leamer (2008) argues that “One reason we need a clear definition is that the media focus intensely on two questions: Is it a bear market? Are we in recession? If the answer is ‘yes, we are in recession,’ it seems useful to me if both speaker and listener understand what is being said. The focus on recession is not nearly as silly as the focus on bear markets. It is only somewhat misleading to describe the economy as having two states: healthy and ill.”
For discussions about the information technology revolution, see OECD 2002, 2012b; and Byrne, Oliner, and Sichel 2013.
Chapter 7 Synchronization of Recessions
Recent studies examine the sources of the highly synchronized nature of national recessions during the latest global recession. Perri and Quadrini (2011) emphasize the problems in credit markets as the main source of synchronization. Bacchetta and van Wincoop 2013 argue that national business cycles can become highly synchronized when the world economy is hit by a “global panic” shock. Kamin and DeMarco (2012) and Rose and Spiegel (2010) study this issue using empirical approaches. The former study concludes that “The U.S. subprime crisis, rather than being a fundamental driver of the global crisis, may have been merely a trigger for a global bank run and for disillusionment with a risky business model that already had spread around the world.” The latter one reports that “while countries with higher income seemed to suffer worse crises, we find few clear reliable indicators in the pre-crisis data of the incidence of the Great Recession.”
Imbs (2010), using monthly industrial production data, concludes that the degree of cross-country business cycle correlations during the latest crisis was the highest over the past three decades. Dua and Banerji (2010) use a wide range of measures to analyze the degree of synchronization of recessions and report that “the 2009 global recession was possibly the most concerted in the post world war period.” Recent research indicates that shocks originating in credit markets have been influential in driving global activity during global recessions (Helbling and others 2011).
We employed the statistical method to identify the dates of the turning points of cycles in the quarterly data. The algorithm is the same as the one applied to the annual data in Chapter 3, but it requires the duration of a complete cycle and for each phase to be at least five quarters and two quarters, respectively. For details of the methodology with the quarterly data and data set of advanced economies, see Claessens, Kose, and Terrones 2012.
A number of studies examine the behavior of macroeconomic and financial variables around recessions and recoveries. For additional information on this literature, see Claessens, Kose, and Terrones 2009, 2012; and Terrones, Scott, and Kannan 2009. In related research, Diebold and Yilmaz (2009) examine “return spillovers” and “volatility spillovers” of equities during crisis and noncrisis periods.
Appendix D provides a list of countries that experienced financial crises around global recessions.
Recent studies examine the degree of synchronization of cycles using a so-called concordance index, which measures the percentage of time that two financial variables are in the same phase of their respective cycles (Claessens, Kose, and Terrones 2012). Credit and equity cycles display the highest degree of synchronization across countries. These cycles tend to be in the same phase about 80 percent of the time. Although housing is a nontradable asset, the extent of synchronization of housing cycles across countries is still high at about 60 percent (Hirata and others 2012). This partly reflects the important roles played by global factors, including world interest rates, the global business cycle, and commodity prices in explaining house price movements around the world. The degree of synchronization in housing and equity markets has increased over time, probably due to the expansion of cross-border trade and financial flows.
Bluedorn, Decressin, and Terrones (2013) provide evidence that asset price drops are significantly associated with the beginning of recessions in the Group of Seven countries.
See Forbes and Rigobon 2002. The implications of the coincidence of financial cycles have provided fertile ground for recent research. Claessens, Kose, and Terrones (2011a, 2011b) show the presence of strong interactions—between credit and housing markets, for example. Credit downturns overlapping with house price busts are longer and deeper than other credit downturns. Similarly, when credit upturns coincide with housing booms, they tend to be longer and stronger. For example, a typical credit upturn becomes 25 percent longer and 40 percent stronger when it coincides with a housing boom.
For discussions on the theoretical implications of globalization for synchronization, see Kose, Prasad, and Terrones 2003a; and Hirata, Kose, and Otrok 2013.
Chapter 8 Double Whammy: Crisis and Recession
Beauchemin 2011; Bernanke 2012b; Council of Economic Advisers 2009, 2010, 2012; Reinhart and Rogoff 2012a, 2012b; Krugman 2012a; Bordo and Haubrich 2012; Taylor 2012; Hassett and Hubbard 2012; and Wynne 2011 provide arguments for different sides of this debate.
Reinhart and Rogoff 2009; Papell and Prodan 2011; Queralto 2013; Claessens, Kose, and Terrones 2009, 2012; and Terrones, Scott, and Kannan 2009 present detailed analyses of the implications of financial disruptions for macroeconomic outcomes during recessions and recoveries. This chapter builds on the last two studies.
Bordo and Haubrich 2012; and Howard, Martin, and Wilson 2011 argue that recessions and recoveries associated with financial disruptions are no different than other episodes. The conflicting conclusions across studies on the issue stem from differences in the definition of financial crises, the sample of countries, and the definition of recovery. There were also some speeches given by policymakers on the issue prior to the crisis. For example, Roger W. Ferguson (Vice Chairman of the Federal Reserve Board) argued that “recessions that follow swings in asset prices are not necessarily longer, deeper, and associated with a greater fall in output and investment than other recessions” in a speech he gave in January 2005 (Ferguson 2005).
Our sample includes recessions that took place during 1960:Q1–2007:Q4 (Claessens, Kose, and Terrones 2009). Recessions associated with the 15 financial crises include Australia (1990:Q2–1991:Q2), Denmark (1987:Q1–1988:Q2), Finland (1990:Q2–1993:Q2), France (1992:Q2–1993:Q3), Germany (1980:Q2–1980:Q4), Greece (1992:Q2–1993:Q1), Italy (1992:Q2–1993:Q3), Japan (1993:Q2–1993:Q4), Japan (1997:Q2–1999:Q1), New Zealand (1986:Q4–1987:Q4), Norway (1988:Q2–1988:Q4), Spain (1978:Q3–1979:Q1), Sweden (1990:Q2–1993:Q1), United Kingdom (1973:Q3–1974:Q1), and United Kingdom (1990:Q3–1991:Q3).
Recessions associated with the Big Five financial crises (identified by Reinhart and Rogoff 2009) include Finland (1990:Q2–1993:Q2), Japan (1993:Q2–1993:Q4), Norway (1988:Q2–1988:Q4), Spain (1978:Q3–1979:Q1), and Sweden (1990:Q2–1993:Q1).
Mendoza and Terrones (2012) study the likelihood of crises around credit booms. They report that the probability of having a financial crisis is more than 75 percent over the seven-year period around a credit boom. The likelihood of a financial crisis is 45 percent at the peak of a boom or after the boom. Credit booms have frequently followed financial deregulation. For example, almost all of the 15 financial crises considered here followed deregulation in the mortgage market. Claessens and others (2014) provide a wide range of studies analyzing the consequences of asset price and credit booms, busts and financial crises, and policy responses to these episodes.
Abiad and others (2009) study the medium-term output dynamics after 88 banking crises in a large number of countries. Cecchetti, Kohler, and Upper 2009; Reinhart and Reinhart 2010; Haltmaier 2012; and Furceri and Zdzienicka 2012 also document significant medium-term output losses associated with different types of financial crises. Ball (2014) estimates that the loss in potential output following the 2009 global recession ranges from almost nothing in Australia and Switzerland to more than 30 percent in Greece, Hungary, and Ireland with the weighted average loss of 23 OECD economies is 8.4 percent. IMF 2015c documents that potential output growth in advanced economies is likely to increase slightly from current rates as some crisis-related effects wear off but will likely remain below precrisis rates in the medium term.
This stylized fact is consistent with the finding that productivity is procyclical. Basu and Fernald (2000) argue that the procyclical nature of productivity is mainly explained by two forces—the variable utilization of inputs over the cycle and the reallocation of resources.
Their recent research also supports the sluggish nature of recoveries following financial crises. Reinhart and Rogoff (2014) report that, after systemic banking crises, it takes, on average, about eight years to reach the precrisis level of income; the median is about 6.5 years.
Mohammed El-Erian is a former chief executive officer and co–chief investment officer of PIMCO and Bill Gross is founder and former co–chief investment officer of PIMCO.
See El-Erian 2009, 2011; and Gross 2009. Gross (2009) claims that “we are heading into what we call the New Normal, which is a period of time in which economies grow very slowly as opposed to growing like weeds, the way children do; in which profits are relatively static; in which the government plays a significant role in terms of deficits and reregulation and control of the economy; in which the consumer stops shopping until he drops and begins, as they do in Japan (to be a little ghoulish), starts saving to the grave.” Roubini (2011) argues that “there are good reasons to believe that we are experiencing a more persistent slump.”
IMF 2013b and 2014b present these growth forecasts and an analysis of the evolutions of global real interest rates.
Summers (2013, 2014) presents the basic arguments describing secular stagnation. Summers (2013) notes that “There are many a priori reasons why the level of spending at any given set of interest rates is likely to have declined. Investment demand may have been reduced due to slower growth of the labor force and perhaps slower productivity growth. Consumption may be lower due to a sharp increase in the share of income held by the very wealthy and the rising share of income accruing to capital. Risk aversion has risen as a consequence of the crisis and as saving—by both states and consumers—has risen. The crisis increased the costs of financial intermediation and left major debt overhangs. Declines in the cost of durable goods, especially those associated with information technology, mean that the same level of saving purchases more capital every year.” Krugman (2013c, 2014c) and Cassidy (2014) also support the notion of secular stagnation for the United States. Samuelson (2013) considers the possible causes of secular stagnation and notes that “The problem might not be a dearth of investments so much as a surplus of risk aversion. For that, candidates abound: the traumatic impact of the Great Recession on confidence; a backlash against globalization, reduced cross-border investments by multinational firms; uncertain government policies; aging societies burdened by diminishing innovation and costly welfare states. Whatever the cause, we are in unfamiliar territory.” Baily and Bosworth (2013) examine the sources of the weak recovery in the United States and conclude that “the unresolved problems suggest a long period of slow growth and higher than normal unemployment.” Bernanke (2015a, 2015b, 2015c, 2015d) states that low interest rates are not a short-term aberration, but part of a long-term trend. He notes that global trade imbalances and unequal financial flows contribute to low global interest rates. OECD 2014 argues that “a global slowdown in productivity and the risk of higher structural unemployment threaten to usher in a new era of low economic growth” (Hutchens and Martin 2014). Gordon 2012 and 2014 present a broader discussion of a growth slowdown in the United States due to a variety of structural reasons. Alvin Hansen (1939), the president of the American Economic Association, advanced the idea of “secular stagnation” in 1939. His idea was that the Great Depression could lead to a prolonged period of stagnation and high unemployment because of the decline in the birth rate and excessive savings that constrain aggregate demand (Eggertsson and Mehrotra 2014). Foster, Grim, and Haltiwanger (2014) report that during the Great Recession, the intensity of reallocation across producers fell rather than rose and the reallocation that did occur was less productivity enhancing than in prior recessions. Hamilton and others (2015) conclude that the secular stagnation hypothesis confuses a delayed recovery with chronically weak aggregate demand.
Hoshi and Kashyap (2013) study the implications of the Japanese experience during its banking crisis in the 1990s for the United States and Europe. They focus on the delay in bank recapitalization and the lack of structural reforms in Japan, arguing that these two policy choices were responsible for stagnant postcrisis growth. They conclude that “In France, Italy, and Spain bank recapitalization has been delayed and the structural reforms have been slow. Without drastic changes, they are likely to follow Japan’s path to long economic stagnation. The situation in Germany looks somewhat better mainly because the structural reform was already advanced before the crisis. Although the recovery has been slow in the U.S. as well, the problems are at least different from those faced by Japan then and many European countries now.” Buiter, Rahbari, and Seydl (2014) report that “the risk of ‘secular stagnation’ through a failure to adopt appropriate policy measures is absent in emerging markets, low in the US and UK, somewhat higher in Japan and highest in the euro area.” Another view, though, is that the global economy has enormous potential to generate a healthy dose of growth in the coming decades (see Mokyr 2014). Innovations, well-designed policies and vibrant emerging market and frontier economies can help realize that potential.
Taylor (2014b) and Rogoff (2013) present detailed arguments. George Osborne (2014), Chancellor of the Exchequer in the United Kingdom, claims that the pickup in economic growth in the United States and the United Kingdom in 2014 repudiates the secular stagnation argument. Fernald (2014) argues that it would be unreasonable to expect the U.S. productivity growth would reach its level over the 1973–95 period.
Rodrik (2013) argues that “developing countries will face stronger headwinds in the decades ahead, both because the global economy is likely to be significantly less buoyant than in recent decades and because technological changes are rendering manufacturing more capital and skill intensive.” Dervis (2013) provides an alternative view and claims that “With weak demand in advanced countries now impeding growth in emerging economies, including major players in Asia and Latin America, many are arguing that the era of income convergence has come to an end. Nothing could be further from the truth.” Spence (2014) is also optimistic about future growth in emerging market economies as he writes, “The most likely scenario is that most major emerging markets, including China, will experience a transitional growth slowdown but will not be derailed by shifts in monetary policy in the West, with high growth rates returning in the course of the coming year. There are internal and external downside risks in each country that cannot and should not be dismissed, and volatility in international capital flows is complicating the adjustment. The problem today is that the downside risks are becoming the consensus forecast. That seems to me to be misguided – and a poor basis for investment and policy decisions.”
For example, the 1975 episode led to such predictions as The Economist (1975c) notes that “Economic growth over the next 10 years will be slower than the world is accustomed to, unless politicians dare sharply to increase the rewards for risk taking. The danger ahead is (a) that the world economy will experience more violent fluctuations in demand and activity over the decade to 1985 than it experienced during the three decades to 1975; (b) that these fluctuations will be about a much slower growth trend; and that (c) the only countries that get decent growth will be those that are willing to give much higher rewards for risk-bearing—that are ready to see a substantial shift in the share of GNP away from personal consumption and government spending towards company profits. Political considerations in Britain, and some other countries, do not seem likely to favor this.” Tylecote (1992) argues that “the period of downswing—slow growth or worse—lasts some 25 years. But after about 1982, the United States and Britain led a sustained recovery among the wealthy nations of the North. The outlook seemed rosy. Those of us who never shared the optimism can now say, ‘We told you so.’ I, for one, said the world depression never went away, for the world economy also includes the poor East, and the poorer South. For them, the 1980s were a nightmare. Their foreign debts were higher than ever and the real prices of their exports lower—the latter the main cause of the rise in living standards in the North. Beggars make bad customers. Yes, for now—just as the American New Deal would have been in 1930. That is why this Long Wave downswing still has about a decade to run.” Kose and Ozturk (2014, 2015) provide a summary of some of the major changes the global economy has experienced over the past 50 years and conclude that no one could have accurately predicted these changes.
Gertler 1988; Sinai 1992, 2010; and Bernanke 1993 review some of the early literature. Claessens and Kose 2014a, 2014b broadly survey the topic. Gourinchas and Kose 2014, 2015 present summaries of recent studies analyzing the implications of various types of crises.
These frictions often stem from information asymmetries and enforcement problems (Claessens and Kose 2014b).
Aoki, Proudman, and Vlieghe 2004; and Iacoviello 2005 provide models with these features. Using a New Keynesian model, Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Trabandt (2014) find that the vast bulk of the movements in aggregate real economic activity during the recent global recession was due to financial frictions interacting with the zero lower bound.
For example, Carroll, Otsuka, and Slacalek (2006) report that the propensity to consume from a $1 increase in housing wealth ranges between 2 cents (short term) and 9 cents (long term), twice that for equity wealth. Kishor (2007) reports that while 98 percent of the change in housing wealth is permanent, only 55 percent of the change in financial wealth is. Case, Quigley, and Shiller (2013) also report that a collapse in house prices tends to be followed by a sharp decline in household spending.
Chapter 9 Uncertainty: How Bad Is It?
For a more detailed discussion of this, see Friedman 1964, 1993.
Bloom 2009, 2013 and Baker, Bloom, and Davis 2013 provide details on the measurement of uncertainty, discuss interactions between uncertainty and activity, and present a detailed evaluation of the implications of uncertainty. Krugman 2012b and 2013b present a critical perspective on the relevance of policy uncertainty. Davis 2013 provides a response to Krugman’s criticisms. FOMC 2008, 2009; Blanchard 2009b; Summers 2009; and Romer 2009b also mention the negative impact of uncertainty on demand. Chinn 2011; Zandi 2013; and Stone 2013 analyze various aspects of policy uncertainty and their impact on activity. Lee 2014 considers the impact of uncertainty on global investment. Baker and others 2014 analyze the causes of the strong upward drift in policy-related economic uncertainty since 1960. This chapter builds on Kose and Terrones 2012 and Bloom, Kose, and Terrones 2013.
For a description of survey findings, see National Association for Business Economics 2014.
The National Association for Business Economics—NABE (2014b) reports that “A majority of the NABE Policy Survey panel feels that uncertainty about fiscal policy is holding back economic recovery, although the share that holds this opinion is smaller than that which held this view in the August 2013 survey.” Baker and others (2014) report that policy-related economic uncertainty has risen in the United States since 1960. They argue that the secular increase in policy uncertainty can be explained by two factors: growth in government spending, taxes, and regulation and a rise in political polarization and its implications for the policy-making process and policy choices.
Bloom and others (2012) document this observation.
Bachmann and Moscarini (2011) find that the direction of causality runs from recessions to uncertainty. Cesa-Bianchi, Peseran, and Rebucci (2014) also report that uncertainty is not a driver of business cycles since there is a significant impact of future output growth on current volatility (uncertainty) but exogenous changes in volatility have no effect on business cycles. Bachmann and Bayer (2013, 2014) find that the impact of uncertainty on growth is quite small in the context of general equilibrium models. In contrast, Baker and Bloom (2013) offer evidence, using disaster data as instruments, that the causality runs from uncertainty to recessions, and Bloom and others (2012) report that growth does not cause uncertainty. Predictions of theory and findings from empirical studies collectively indicate that uncertainty can play a dual role over the business cycle; that is, it can be an impulse as well as a propagation mechanism.
Bernanke (1983) and Dixit and Pindyck (1994) provide analytical models showing the impact of uncertainty on investment.
Gilchrist, Sim, and Zakrajsek (2010) and Arellano, Bai, and Kehoe (2012) provide models illustrating these interactions.
CarriÈre-Swallow and Céspedes (2013) present an empirical analysis of the impact of uncertainty in advanced economies on emerging market economies.
The growth rate of output is negatively correlated with macroeconomic uncertainty. Appendix I presents detailed results of this.
Empirical evidence based on vector autoregressive models points to a significant negative impact of uncertainty shocks on output and employment (Bloom 2009; Hirata and others 2012). These results also echo findings in a broader area of research on the negative impact of macroeconomic and policy volatility on economic growth (Ramey and Ramey 1995; Kose, Prasad, and Terrones 2005 and 2006; Fatas and Mihov 2013).
Figure 9.5 is based on the study by Baker, Bloom, and Davis 2012. Bloom and others (2012) and Baker and Bloom (2013) analyze the effects of uncertainty shocks on business cycle movements. For additional evidence on the impact of uncertainty, see Bloom 2009, 2013; and Hirata and others 2012.
Stock and Watson (2012) study the evolution of the Great Recession in the United States using a dynamic factor model. They report that many of the events during this episode were unprecedented and led to macroeconomic shocks that were larger than those previously experienced. They also find that while oil price shocks played a role in the initial slowdown, shocks stemming from financial market turbulence and heightened uncertainty were the major driving forces of the recession.
Chapter 10 The Great Divergence of Policies
Krugman (2013a) and Romer (2013) support the use of more aggressive expansionary policies to help economic recovery and argue that continued austerity could lead to an intensification of economic malaise, as happened in 1937. For a discussion of the use of a higher inflation target, see Rogoff 2008; Blanchard, Dell’Ariccia, and Mauro 2010; and Krugman 2014b, 2014d. Some argue that monetary policy, by stopping adverse feedback loops, can play a significant role during a financial crisis (Mishkin 2009). Bernanke (2012a); English, Lopez-Salido, and Tetlow (2013); and Reifschneider, Wascher, and Wilcox (2013) take stock of the diverse monetary policy actions, conventional and unconventional, taken by the Federal Reserve since late 2007. Yellen (2013a) discusses the difficulties the Federal Reserve faced in achieving its dual mandate of price stability and maximum employment after interest rates hit the zero lower bound.
Some argue that the severity of the recent recession reflects the aggressive use of fiscal and structural policies (that is, subsidies, taxes, and regulations) implemented after 2007 as these policies reduced incentives for firms to hire and for people to work (Mulligan 2012). Similarly, others state that the weak recovery has been the result of the adverse effects of policies and regulations on growth (Ohanian, Taylor, and Wright 2012; Cogan and Taylor 2012c; Taylor 2013, 2014a).
In particular, some claim that central banks might have exercised too much policy discretion with unknown medium- to long-term implications. For instance, Meltzer (2012) notes that many of the actions taken by the Federal Reserve since late 2007 have been inappropriate for an independent central bank, as they have distorted credit markets and focused on the near term.
Kose, Loungani, and Terrones (2013a) document how policies diverged during the latest global recovery and compare their paths with the average behavior of policies during previous episodes.
Other indicators, such as the ratio of government deficits to GDP and short-term real interest rates, often lead to noisy signals about the stance of policies over the business cycle (Kaminsky, Reinhart, and Végh 2005).
For a discussion of fiscal policies early in the crisis, see Spilimbergo and others 2008; Freedman and others 2009; Mankiw 2009a; Wolf 2009, 2010c, 2013a, 2013b; and the U.S. Department of the Treasury 2013. There have been intense debates on the effectiveness of the large fiscal stimulus implemented by the United States early in the crisis. Matthews (2011) provides a brief evaluation of nine studies on the subject (see also Cochrane 2009b; Frankel 2013; Council of Economic Advisers 2014a; Furman 2014; Krugman 2014a; Davies 2014; and Luce 2014). Coenen and others (2012) evaluate the effectiveness of discretionary fiscal policy in the euro area during the crisis. Végh and Vuletin (2013) analyze fiscal policy responses during the Latin American crisis and the euro area crisis. They conclude that procyclical fiscal policy has aggravated the duration and intensity of the crisis in both cases. Chari and Henry (2013) compare policy responses during the Asian crisis and the global financial crisis. They document that the fiscal adjustment in Asia was far more modest than is commonly known and that the switch from stimulus to austerity in Europe was quite abrupt. They conclude that the difference in fiscal stance helps explain the difference in the postcrisis paths of output and employment in the two regions. Davies (2012) draws some lessons from the Asian crisis for Europe. Wolf (2010a) considers the Japanese experience and draws parallels with the current episode. Wolf (2014) analyzes the experience of the economies that experienced credit cycles. Kollman, Roeger, and Veld (2012) examine government support programs to the financial sector during the crisis. Laeven and Valencia (2011) evaluate the implications of financial sector interventions for the real economy during the crisis. Claessens and others (2014) include several studies about various macroeconomic and structural policy measures that can help mitigate the adverse effects of financial crises.
The change in the direction of fiscal policy in the United States has also been a subject of intense debates. For example, Krugman (2014a) argues that “So, let me make the obvious point, just in case anyone missed it: the “pivot” of 2010—when all the Very Serious People decided that the danger from debt trumped any and all concern for job creation—was an utter disaster, economic and human. It was even a disaster in fiscal terms, because a permanently depressed economy will cost far more in revenue than was saved by slashing the deficit by a few percent of GDP in the short term.” On the opposite side, Sachs (2015) argues that although we need larger government spending relative to GDP, we should pay for this through higher taxes on the wealthy since there is nothing progressive about large budget deficits and a rising debt-to-GDP ratio. Similarly, Cochrane (2014) notes that “by Keynesian logic, fraud is good; thieves have notoriously high marginal propensity to consume. That’s a hard sell, so stimulus is routinely dressed in ‘infrastructure’ clothes. In the context of the United Kingdom, there was also a passionate debate about the direction of fiscal policy. Wolf (2013b) claims that “Austerity has failed. It turned a nascent recovery into stagnation. That imposes huge and unnecessary costs, not just in the short run, but also in the long term: the costs of investments unmade, of businesses not started, of skills atrophied, and of hopes destroyed.” George Osborne (2014), Chancellor of the Exchequer of the United Kingdom, defends the fiscal policy his government implemented: “Our economy has grown faster than any other in the G-7 over the past year and is now forecast by the International Monetary Fund to do the same in 2014. This is despite warnings from some that our determined pursuit of our economic plan made that impossible. At the same time, job creation has been better than anyone expected: three times faster than any previous U.K. recovery, with more than four new jobs in the private sector for every job lost in the public sector. All of this demonstrates that fiscal consolidation and economic recovery go together, and it undermines the pessimistic prognosis that only further fiscal stimulus can drive sustainable growth. Indeed, that is precisely the wrong prescription.”
In 2012, fiscal deficits declined to 6 percent of GDP in the advanced economies and 2 percent of GDP in the emerging market economies (IMF 2013b).
After Herndon, Ash, and Pollin (2013) point out some problems in a study by Reinhart and Rogoff (2010a), the debate on the impact of public debt on economic growth has become even more intense. Although other studies also document a negative correlation between public debt and economic growth, there is no conclusive evidence suggesting a causal relationship running from debt to growth (IMF 2012b; Panizza and Presbitero 2013).
In December 2013, the Federal Reserve decided to start reducing the pace of its asset purchases beginning in January 2014 (FOMC 2013).
In addition, IMF 2014c notes that “in most advanced economies, the pace of fiscal consolidation will slow in 2014 as average gross debt stabilizes and the focus shifts appropriately toward ensuring that the composition of adjustment supports the still uneven recovery.”
For a discussion of how the financial crisis has affected the design of macroeconomic policies, see Blanchard, Dell’Ariccia, and Mauro 2010, 2013; Blanchard and others 2012; and Taylor 2014a.
See, for instance, Blanchard and Perotti 2002; DeLong and Summers 2012; Blanchard and Leigh 2013b; Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Rebelo 2011; Ramey 2011; Auerbach and Gorodnichenko 2012; and Chinn 2014. One limitation of these studies is the difficulty in identifying truly exogenous policy changes (Alesina 2012; Alesina and Giavazzi 2013). This issue is complicated by the fact that fiscal and monetary policy changes are often simultaneous. Romer (2013) argues that one of the lessons from the Great Depression is that fiscal policy is a very effective tool to spur recovery. Alesina and Ardagna (2010) report that fiscal consolidation (particularly that based on spending cuts as opposed to tax increases) can be expansionary. More recent evidence, however, suggests that expansionary austerity is very rare (Perotti 2012) and, when properly measured, fiscal consolidation is indeed contractionary (Guajardo, Leigh, and Pescatori 2011). Mankiw (2009a) also provides a discussion of this issue.
Sargent and Wallace (1975) provide a discussion of this idea. See also Barro 1981 and Lucas 1975, 1977. Lucas (1995) argues that the distinction between anticipated and unanticipated money shocks is one of the main findings of research on monetary policy. While the anticipated monetary expansions affect nominal variables (that is, interest rates and inflation tax effects), the unanticipated monetary expansions can temporarily influence production and employment.
For the effectiveness of monetary policies under these circumstances, see Eggertsson and Woodford 2003; Krishnamurthy and Vissing-Jorgensen 2011; Carvalho, Eusipe, and Grisse 2012; Woodford 2012; Bauer and Rudebusch 2012; Baumeister and Benati 2010; Chen, Cúrdia, and Ferrero 2012; and Swanson and Williams 2013, among others.
Williamson (2013) makes this point and examines how the changes in the size and composition of central bank balance sheets can affect monetary policy. Gagnon and Sack (2014) discuss the implications of a large balance sheet and substantial amount of liquidity in the financial system.
There is broad agreement that unconventional monetary policies (based on liquidity provision and private asset purchases) at the early stages of the crisis were also effective in restoring the functioning of financial markets (IMF 2013c).
These findings have been partially confirmed by other studies in the United States and United Kingdom employing different methodologies (see, for instance, Krishnamurthy and Vissing-Jorgensen 2011, 2013; Gagnon and others 2011; Joyce and others 2010). Fischer 2015 notes that asset purchases have helped make financial conditions overall more accommodative and have provided significant stimulus for the broader economy.
Some of these risks or costs are also discussed in Bernanke 2012a. Yellen (2013b) argues that financial stability risks in the United States are being carefully monitored and that currently there is no pervasive evidence of excessive credit growth, a buildup of leverage, or asset bubbles. However, she admits that the financial stability concern is the most important potential cost of the monetary policy stance since the global financial crisis. A prolonged period of monetary accommodation in the advanced economies could weaken the resolve to repair and reform financial entities, encourage excessive risk taking by economic agents, and promote large capital flows to emerging market economies (Caruana 2013, Feldstein 2013, IMF 2013c, Stein 2013).
Chapter 11 A Complex Affair: Global and National Cycles
The IMF provided descriptions of the differential performance across various regions during the global recession and recovery. For example, IMF 2009b mentions the challenges of the Middle East and Central Asia region and notes that “The global crisis is now affecting the countries in the Middle East and Central Asia region, and economic and financial vulnerabilities are rising. In the Middle East and North Africa, good economic fundamentals, appropriate policy responses, and sizable currency reserves are helping mitigate the impact of the shock. In the Caucasus and Central Asia, lower commodity prices and adverse economic developments in Russia have hit hard.” IMF 2010b observes the strong performance of Asian economies: “Asia has entered the second year of the global economic expansion still firmly in the lead of the recovery. Growth in the first half of 2010 proceeded well above trend in almost all regional economies, as global manufacturing continued to rebound and fueled exports and investment in the region.” IMF 2010c discusses the rapid growth in the Latin America and Caribbean region: “A multispeed global recovery is under way, with some emerging markets in the lead and the major advanced economies growing more slowly. This macroeconomic setting has brought a return to easy global financial conditions and high commodity prices—a situation likely to be sustained for some time but unlikely to be permanent. Against that external backdrop, the recovery in the Latin America and Caribbean region overall is advancing faster than anticipated, but moving at different speeds across countries.” These themes are also discussed in IMF 2015a and IMF 2015b.
Goldstein and Khan 1982; Dornbusch 1985; Hoffmaister, Pradhan, and Samiei 1998; Frankel and Roubini 2001; IMF 2001d; and Calvo and others 2001 analyze the linkages between advanced and emerging market economies. Currie and Vines 1988 and Chui and others 2002 present surveys of studies focusing on trade and growth in the context of North-South interactions. Another branch of this research program examines the role of trading partners’ economic performance in driving the dynamics of domestic growth (see Akin and Kose 2008 for a summary).
Lewis (1980) makes this observation. Akin and Kose (2008) examine the extent of growth spillovers from the advanced economies to the emerging market economies and concludes that the impact of the former group on the growth dynamics of the latter has declined over time.
LIBOR is an index of the interest rates at which banks are willing to offer to lend unsecured funds to other banks in the London wholesale money market. We provide the details of our model and present an extensive discussion of our findings in Kose, Loungani, and Terrones 2013b.
Appendix J presents the details of regression results.
A number of papers study these types of asymmetric effects of interest rates on output during recessions and expansions (Garcia and Schaller 2002; Sensier, Osborn, and Ocal 2002; Karras 1996).
Forbes and Warnock (2012) find evidence that global factors are key drivers of waves of international capital flows. These factors become especially important during global recessions (as we saw during the latest episode) because foreign investors can rapidly reduce their bank and equity flows. Milesi-Ferretti and Tille (2011) report that countries with large precrisis debt positions indeed witnessed much larger outflows of capital at the height of the 2009 global recession.
Kose, Otrok, and Prasad (2012) provide details about the roles played by global and national factors in driving cycles in advanced, emerging market, and other developing economies.
Gourinchas and Kose (2010, 2011) present summaries of recent studies analyzing the transmission of the global financial crisis across borders through trade and financial linkages.
For example, Arora and Vamvakidis (2004) find that advanced economies benefit from trading with rapidly growing emerging market economies, while developing economies benefit from trading with the relatively high-income advanced economies. Helbling and others (2007) find that spillovers from the United States to other economies have increased with greater trade and financial integration.
These types of terms-of-trade shocks tend to play a more important role in countries connected to each other through vertical linkages involving multinational production chains. Research indicates that vertical linkages appear to amplify transmission of business cycles across borders (Kose and Yi 2001, 2006; Burstein, Kurz, and Tesar 2008; di Giovanni and Levchenko 2010; Chinn, 2013).
Chapter 12 Lessons: Past, Present, and Future
Blanchard and Milesi-Ferretti (2009, 2012) discuss the implications of global imbalances and policies to adjust them.
An extensive research program has analyzed the benefits and costs of policy coordination. Most studies suggest that given the costs of reaching a consensus among countries with different objectives, the benefits of policy coordination are quite small (Oudiz and Sachs 1985; Obstfeld and Rogoff 2002; Williamson 2005; Stiglitz 2009; Angeloni and Pisani-Ferry 2012; Taylor 2013a). Analyzing the implications of fiscal policy coordination at the zero lower bound, Gomes and others (2015) show that international coordination is helpful but it does not necessarily play a major role.
The importance of policy coordination was also emphasized in previous global recessions. For example, Nossiter (1974) describes the expectations of the international organizations during the 1975 episode: “The International Monetary Fund notes that it has appealed for global coordination in the past ‘but never with greater urgency than at the present time.’ The IMF calls the unbalanced accounts created by the oil states a ‘disequilibrium wholly unprecedented in size and character.’ A failure to redistribute these funds, it warns, ‘could seriously damage the world economy.’ In the same vein, the Organization for Economic Coordination and Development, a grouping of the wealthiest nations, declares: ‘Cooperation and consultation between governments have never been more necessary than they are today, given the unaccustomed and troubled waters on which the world economy is now embarked.’” In 1983, The Economist ran a piece by Helmut Schmidt, ex-chancellor of Germany, about the necessary policy measures to head off a global recession. He noted that “The world’s economic interdependence has never been greater than it is this decade. It has never been more necessary to make sure that economic policies complement each other and are internationally compatible. Never has co-operation been as necessary as today. Just as democracies cannot keep going without a general consensus about the rules, the world economy cannot survive without agreement on the rules of the game and the distribution of roles” (The Economist 1983). In 1992, the U.S. Treasury noted that “Since the mid-1980s, the Group of Seven (G7) has worked intensively to achieve consistent and compatible policies and performance necessary for sustained growth with price stability, reduced external imbalances and greater stability of exchange markets. The economic policy coordination process grew directly out of each country’s growing recognition that, in an interdependent world, economic performance at home depends in large part on economic developments in the rest of the world, and particularly in the major industrial economies. As recent experience has once again demonstrated, the formulation of economic policies—especially fiscal and monetary policies—by individual G7 countries has a major impact on the economies of the others. Moreover, no individual G7 member acting alone can overcome economic difficulties which affect all of the G7 economies” (Department of the Treasury 1992). Uchitelle (1991) explains how the international policy coordination effort failed during the G7 meeting in April 1991.
The G20 web page states that “the G20 is the premier forum for international cooperation on the most important issues of the global economic and financial agenda. The objectives of the G20 refer to: (i) policy coordination between its members in order to achieve global economic stability and sustainable growth; (ii) promoting financial regulations that reduce risks and prevent future financial crises; and (iii) modernizing international financial architecture.”
Despite its initial success, the effectiveness of the G20 has become a topic of debate, especially after 2010 (Angeloni and Pisani-Ferry 2012; Faruqee and Srinivasan 2012). O’Neill and Terzi (2014) make predictions about the world economy in 2020 and conclude that “If our projections to 2020 are broadly right, then many established frameworks for the running of the world economy and its governance are not going to be fit for purpose, and will need to change. The global monetary system itself, and global organizations such as the IMF, G7 and G20 will have to adapt considerably if they want to remain legitimate representatives of the world order. The alternative is their relegation to irrelevance.”
There has been an intense debate on the feasibility and benefits of international monetary policy coordination in light of the developments in financial markets in emerging market economies following the announcements of tapering of bond purchases by the U.S. Federal Reserve in mid-2013. Raghuram Rajan, governor of the Reserve Bank of India, made a strong case for coordination: “Hence, my call is for more coordination in monetary policy because I think it would be an immense improvement over the current international non-system. International monetary policy coordination, of course, is unpopular among central bankers, and I therefore have to say why I reiterate the call and what I mean by it. I do not mean that central bankers sit around a table and make policy collectively, nor do I mean that they call each other regularly and coordinate actions. In its strong form, I propose that large country central banks, both in advanced countries and emerging markets, internalize more of the spillovers from their policies in their mandate, and are forced by new conventions on the ‘rules of the game’ to avoid unconventional policies with large adverse spillovers and questionable domestic benefits” (Rajan 2014). Harding (2014) notes that “Janet Yellen has turned a cold shoulder to the pleas of emerging markets by signaling that only a domestic slowdown will influence US monetary policy, in comments that suggest there will be no relief for those countries being battered by the Fed’s reduction of its asset purchases.” William F. Dudley, president of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, argues that “Moreover, it is far from clear that explicitly coordinated policy would produce better outcomes for the global economy generally, or the EMEs (emerging market economies) specifically. Central banks have challenges enough in tailoring policies to their domestic circumstances. I believe that it would be taking on too much to attempt to collectively fashion policy in reference to global conditions. Moreover, our last system of explicit coordination—the system of fixed exchange rates under Bretton Woods—broke down for a reason. Monetary policy meant to suit everybody is likely in the end to suit nobody” (Dudley 2014). Prasad (2014) emphasizes the importance of addressing domestic vulnerabilities in emerging market economies and notes that “Rather than fulminating about other countries’ monetary policies, national leaders ought to put their own houses in order. Monetary authorities should focus on delivering low inflation and financial stability. If central bankers wage proxy battles on behalf of their feckless political leaders, they risk damaging their own hard-won credibility, independence and effectiveness.” Christine Lagarde, managing director of the IMF, often emphasizes the importance of policy coordination: “Getting beyond the crisis still requires a sustained and substantial policy effort, coordination, and the right policy mix” (Lagarde 2014).
Blanchard (2013) discusses the importance of advancing research on policies.
McKinsey Global Institute (2013) analyzes the evolution of financial flows in recent years. Kose and others (2010) present a review of the literature on the implications of financial flows for macroeconomic stability and long-term growth.
For a discussion about the end of the business cycles in the 1960s, see Bronfenbrenner 1969 and Gordon 1970. The Economist (1989) noted that “thousands of economists have studied the business cycle—the regular swings in economic activity between boom and bust. But just as they thought they understood its causes and consequences, it seems to be disappearing.” Weber (1997) discusses the end of the cycle in light of developments during the late 1990s. The Economist (1998) noted that “History is, indeed, littered with premature obituaries of the business cycle. In the late 1920s, on the eve of the Depression, there was talk of a new industrial era of rapid, everlasting growth. In the late 1960s, Arthur Okun, an economic adviser to Presidents Kennedy and Johnson, proclaimed that the business cycle was ‘obsolete’—and the Commerce Department was so confident that it decided to change the name of one of its publications from Business Cycle Developments to Business Conditions Digest. A recession began a year later.” Businessweek, in a cover story in early 2000, claimed that we lived in an era of a new economy: “It seems almost too good to be true. With the information technology sector leading the way, the U.S. has enjoyed almost 4% growth since 1994. Unemployment has fallen from 6 percent to about 4 percent, and inflation just keeps getting lower and lower… consumer inflation in 1999 was only 1.9 percent, the smallest increase in 34 years. This spectacular boom was not built on smoke and mirrors… The result is the so-called New Economy: faster growth and lower inflation” (Businessweek 2000).
Appendices
List of Appendices
A. Abbreviations
B. Database
1. Definitions and Sources of Variables
a. Activity Variables
b. Financial Variables
c. Commodity Prices
d. Weights Used to Compute Aggregate and per Capita Variables
e. Measures of Uncertainty
f. Macroeconomic Policy Variables
g. Variables Used in Regressions in Chapter 11
2. List of Countries: Functional Groups (163 Countries)
3. List of Countries: Regional Groups (128 Countries)
4. List of Countries Used in Regressions in Chapter 11 (97 Countries)
C. Evolution of Purchasing Power Parity and Market Weights
D. Crises around Global Recessions and Global Downturns
1. Banking Crises
2. Currency Crises
3. Debt Crises
E. Timeline: Selected Events around Global Recessions and Recoveries
F. Global Recessions: Regional Country Groups
G. Sensitivity of Global Activity Variables
H. Global Recoveries: Regional Country Groups
I. Uncertainty, Business Cycles, and Growth
1. Uncertainty over the Business Cycle
2. Uncertainty and Growth
J. Linkages between the Global Cycle and National Cycles
1. Linkages between Global and National Cycles: All Countries
2. Linkages between Global and National Cycles: Country Groups
3. Linkages between Global and National Cycles: Roles of Trade and Financial Integration
Appendix A. Abbreviations
CEO | Chief executive officer |
CIO | Chief information officer |
CEPR | Centre for Economic Policy Research |
CPI | Consumer price index |
CIS | Commonwealth of Independent States |
Datastream | Thomson Reuters financial and economic data |
DX Databases | Financial and economic databases produced by EconData Pty Ltd., CEIC Data Ltd., and Emerging Markets Economic Data Ltd. (EMED) |
ECB | European Central Bank |
ERM | European Exchange Rate Mechanism |
G20 | Group of Twenty major advanced and emerging market economies |
GDI | Gross domestic income |
GDP | Gross domestic product |
GDS | IMF Global data source |
GFD | Global financial data |
GNP | Gross national product |
GPG | Global Property Guide |
IFS | IMF International Financial Statistics |
ILO | International Labour Organization |
IMF | International Monetary Fund |
LIBOR | London interbank offered rate |
MS | Markov Switching |
MSCI | Morgan Stanley Country Index |
MW | Market-exchange-rate-weighted average |
NBER | National Bureau of Economic Research |
OECD | Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development |
OMT | Outright Monetary Transactions |
PFMHD | IMF Public Finance in Modern History Database |
PIMCO | Pacific Investment Management Company, LLC. |
PPP | Purchasing power parity |
PW | PPP-exchange-rate-weighted average |
PWT | Penn World Tables |
QE | Quantitative easing |
S&P | Standard & Poor’s |
VAR | Vector autoregression |
VXO | Chicago Board Options Volatility Index |
WDI | World Development Indicators |
WEO | IMF World Economic Outlook |
ZLB | Zero lower bound |
Appendix B. Database
1. Definitions and Sources of Variables
a. Activity Variables
a. Activity Variables
Variable | Definition | Source |
---|---|---|
Output | Gross domestic product (GDP), constant prices. Before 1968, the series are spliced using data from the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD). | IMF World Economic Outlook (WEO) |
Trade Flows | Exports + imports. World trade flows growth is the sum of the trade weights multiplied by trade flows growth. Trade weights are the sum of exports and imports of each country over the sum of exports and imports of all countries. | WEO |
Capital Flows over GDP | Total capital flows = (|outflows| + |inflows|)/GDP in U.S. dollars. Outflows = direct assets + portfolio assets + other assets. Inflows = direct liabilities + portfolio liabilities + other liabilities. World capital flows over GDP growth is the difference from the previous year of the sum of total capital flows of all countries. |
WEO |
Oil Consumption | World aggregate oil consumption. | British Petroleum, WEO |
Unemployment | Unemployment rate = (labor force – employment)/labor force. Labor weight = labor force/total labor force of all countries. The change in the world unemployment rate is the difference from the previous year of the sum of the labor-weighted unemployment rate of all countries. |
|
Industrial Production | Industrial production (if not available, manufacturing production) index. Data are in quarterly frequency, and year-over-year growth rates are annualized as the average of four quarters. Data for advanced countries are from the OECD, and whenever series are not available in the OECD, they are spliced using the growth rates of series from the IMF Global Data Source (GDS). Data for emerging market economies are from the IMF International Financial Statistics (IFS) and GDS. |
OECD, GDS, IFS |
Consumption | Private consumption expenditure, constant prices. World consumption growth is the sum of weighted consumption growth. |
WEO |
Investment | Gross fixed capital formation, constant prices. World investment growth is the sum of weighted investment growth. | WEO |
Residential Investment | Private residential fixed capital formation volume. | OECD |
a. Activity Variables
Variable | Definition | Source |
---|---|---|
Output | Gross domestic product (GDP), constant prices. Before 1968, the series are spliced using data from the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD). | IMF World Economic Outlook (WEO) |
Trade Flows | Exports + imports. World trade flows growth is the sum of the trade weights multiplied by trade flows growth. Trade weights are the sum of exports and imports of each country over the sum of exports and imports of all countries. | WEO |
Capital Flows over GDP | Total capital flows = (|outflows| + |inflows|)/GDP in U.S. dollars. Outflows = direct assets + portfolio assets + other assets. Inflows = direct liabilities + portfolio liabilities + other liabilities. World capital flows over GDP growth is the difference from the previous year of the sum of total capital flows of all countries. |
WEO |
Oil Consumption | World aggregate oil consumption. | British Petroleum, WEO |
Unemployment | Unemployment rate = (labor force – employment)/labor force. Labor weight = labor force/total labor force of all countries. The change in the world unemployment rate is the difference from the previous year of the sum of the labor-weighted unemployment rate of all countries. |
|
Industrial Production | Industrial production (if not available, manufacturing production) index. Data are in quarterly frequency, and year-over-year growth rates are annualized as the average of four quarters. Data for advanced countries are from the OECD, and whenever series are not available in the OECD, they are spliced using the growth rates of series from the IMF Global Data Source (GDS). Data for emerging market economies are from the IMF International Financial Statistics (IFS) and GDS. |
OECD, GDS, IFS |
Consumption | Private consumption expenditure, constant prices. World consumption growth is the sum of weighted consumption growth. |
WEO |
Investment | Gross fixed capital formation, constant prices. World investment growth is the sum of weighted investment growth. | WEO |
Residential Investment | Private residential fixed capital formation volume. | OECD |
b. Financial Variables
b. Financial Variables
Variable | Definition | Source |
---|---|---|
Credit | Nominal credit deflated using the consumer price index (CPI). Data are in quarterly frequency, and year-over-year growth rates are annualized as the average of four quarters. Nominal credit from IFS is generally titled as “Claims on Private Sector.” Growth of world credit is the weighted sum of the year-over-year growth rate of credit of each country annualized as the average of four quarters. Weights are in annual frequency, and for each quarter the weight is equal to the weight in the corresponding year. | IFS, Datastream |
Equity Prices | Share price (index) deflated using the CPI. World equity price growth is the weighted sum of the year-over-year growth rate of stock prices of each country annualized as the average of four quarters. Weights are in annual frequency, and for each quarter the weight is equal to the weight in the corresponding year. | IFS, Datastream, Global Financial Database |
House Prices | National house prices deflated using the CPI. World house price growth is the weighted sum of the year-over-year growth rate of house prices of each country annualized as the average of four quarters. Weights are in annual frequency, and for each quarter the weight is equal to the weight in the corresponding year. | Global Property Guide, OECD |
Inflation Rate | Percentage change in CPI. Growth in world inflation is the weighted sum of the year-over-year difference of each country’s inflation rate. Weights are in annual frequency, and for each quarter the weight is equal to the weight in the corresponding year. |
IFS |
Short-Term Interest Rates | Treasury bill rates or short-term interest rates. Real short-term interest rate is the difference between nominal short-term interest rate and inflation. Growth in short-term interest rate is the weighted year-over-year difference annualized as the average of four quarters. |
IFS, Datastream, Haver Analytics, GDS, DXTime |
LIBOR Overnight/3 Month | Overnight (3-month) U.S. dollar deposits in London. Growth in London interbank offered rate (LIBOR) is the year-over-year difference and is annualized as the average of four quarters. |
IFS |
b. Financial Variables
Variable | Definition | Source |
---|---|---|
Credit | Nominal credit deflated using the consumer price index (CPI). Data are in quarterly frequency, and year-over-year growth rates are annualized as the average of four quarters. Nominal credit from IFS is generally titled as “Claims on Private Sector.” Growth of world credit is the weighted sum of the year-over-year growth rate of credit of each country annualized as the average of four quarters. Weights are in annual frequency, and for each quarter the weight is equal to the weight in the corresponding year. | IFS, Datastream |
Equity Prices | Share price (index) deflated using the CPI. World equity price growth is the weighted sum of the year-over-year growth rate of stock prices of each country annualized as the average of four quarters. Weights are in annual frequency, and for each quarter the weight is equal to the weight in the corresponding year. | IFS, Datastream, Global Financial Database |
House Prices | National house prices deflated using the CPI. World house price growth is the weighted sum of the year-over-year growth rate of house prices of each country annualized as the average of four quarters. Weights are in annual frequency, and for each quarter the weight is equal to the weight in the corresponding year. | Global Property Guide, OECD |
Inflation Rate | Percentage change in CPI. Growth in world inflation is the weighted sum of the year-over-year difference of each country’s inflation rate. Weights are in annual frequency, and for each quarter the weight is equal to the weight in the corresponding year. |
IFS |
Short-Term Interest Rates | Treasury bill rates or short-term interest rates. Real short-term interest rate is the difference between nominal short-term interest rate and inflation. Growth in short-term interest rate is the weighted year-over-year difference annualized as the average of four quarters. |
IFS, Datastream, Haver Analytics, GDS, DXTime |
LIBOR Overnight/3 Month | Overnight (3-month) U.S. dollar deposits in London. Growth in London interbank offered rate (LIBOR) is the year-over-year difference and is annualized as the average of four quarters. |
IFS |
c. Commodity Prices
c. Commodity Prices
Variable | Definition | Source |
---|---|---|
Oil Prices | Three spot price index. Real oil prices are nominal oil prices deflated by world CPI. | IFS |
Food Prices | Real food prices are nominal food prices deflated by world CPI. | IFS |
Gold Prices | Gold London Average Second Fix. Real gold prices are nominal gold prices deflated by world CPI. | IFS |
c. Commodity Prices
Variable | Definition | Source |
---|---|---|
Oil Prices | Three spot price index. Real oil prices are nominal oil prices deflated by world CPI. | IFS |
Food Prices | Real food prices are nominal food prices deflated by world CPI. | IFS |
Gold Prices | Gold London Average Second Fix. Real gold prices are nominal gold prices deflated by world CPI. | IFS |
d. Weights Used to Compute Aggregate and per Capita Variables
d. Weights Used to Compute Aggregate and per Capita Variables
Variable | Definition | Source |
---|---|---|
Purchasing-Power-Parity (PPP ) Weights | PPP weight of a country is the ratio of GDP in PPP terms over the sum of GDP in PPP terms of all countries. For series prior to 1970, PPP weights are generated using PPP-weighted per capita GDP and population data from the Penn World Tables (PWT), version 7. | WEO, PWT |
Market Weights | The market weight of a country is the nominal GDP in U.S. dollar terms of that country over the sum of nominal GDP in U.S. dollar terms of all countries. This is used for weights of output and industrial production. Consumption (investment) in U.S. dollar terms is calculated by multiplying GDP in U.S. dollar terms by real consumption (investment) over real GDP in local currency. Market weight for consumption (investment) is consumption (investment) in U.S. dollar terms over sum of consumption (investment) in U.S. dollar terms of all countries. | WEO |
Per Capita Growth Variables | World population is the sum of population of all countries. World population growth is the annual percentage change in the world population. The per capita growth rate of a variable is the difference between the growth rate of the variable and the population growth of the group. If data for the variable of interest are not available for a particular country, then the group population does not include the population of that country. When there is a jump in the population growth due to inclusion of a country in a year, then this jump is smoothed using the average growth rate of population one year before and one year after. | WEO |
d. Weights Used to Compute Aggregate and per Capita Variables
Variable | Definition | Source |
---|---|---|
Purchasing-Power-Parity (PPP ) Weights | PPP weight of a country is the ratio of GDP in PPP terms over the sum of GDP in PPP terms of all countries. For series prior to 1970, PPP weights are generated using PPP-weighted per capita GDP and population data from the Penn World Tables (PWT), version 7. | WEO, PWT |
Market Weights | The market weight of a country is the nominal GDP in U.S. dollar terms of that country over the sum of nominal GDP in U.S. dollar terms of all countries. This is used for weights of output and industrial production. Consumption (investment) in U.S. dollar terms is calculated by multiplying GDP in U.S. dollar terms by real consumption (investment) over real GDP in local currency. Market weight for consumption (investment) is consumption (investment) in U.S. dollar terms over sum of consumption (investment) in U.S. dollar terms of all countries. | WEO |
Per Capita Growth Variables | World population is the sum of population of all countries. World population growth is the annual percentage change in the world population. The per capita growth rate of a variable is the difference between the growth rate of the variable and the population growth of the group. If data for the variable of interest are not available for a particular country, then the group population does not include the population of that country. When there is a jump in the population growth due to inclusion of a country in a year, then this jump is smoothed using the average growth rate of population one year before and one year after. | WEO |
e. Measures of Uncertainty
e. Measures of Uncertainty
Variable | Definition | Source |
---|---|---|
Macroeconomic Uncertainty | Macroeconomic uncertainty refers to the monthly standard deviation of daily stock returns in each country. Daily returns are calculated using each country's stock price index; time coverage varies across economies. Global uncertainty is the dynamic common factor of country-specific uncertainty of the three major advanced economies with the longest data available. Uncertainty in the United States is the Chicago Board Options Exchange (CBOE) Volatility Index, which is calculated from Standard and Poor's (S&P) 100 calls and puts. | Baker, Bloom, and Davis (2012); Kose and Terrones (2012); and CBOE |
Economic Policy Uncertainty | Economic policy uncertainty is an index of policy uncertainty for the United States and the euro area from Baker, Bloom, and Davis (2012). It refers to the weighted average of three indicators, including the frequency of the appearance of terms like “economic policy” and “uncertainty” in the media, the number of tax provisions that will expire in the coming years, and the dispersion of forecasts of future government outlays and inflation. | Baker, Bloom, and Davis (2012) |
e. Measures of Uncertainty
Variable | Definition | Source |
---|---|---|
Macroeconomic Uncertainty | Macroeconomic uncertainty refers to the monthly standard deviation of daily stock returns in each country. Daily returns are calculated using each country's stock price index; time coverage varies across economies. Global uncertainty is the dynamic common factor of country-specific uncertainty of the three major advanced economies with the longest data available. Uncertainty in the United States is the Chicago Board Options Exchange (CBOE) Volatility Index, which is calculated from Standard and Poor's (S&P) 100 calls and puts. | Baker, Bloom, and Davis (2012); Kose and Terrones (2012); and CBOE |
Economic Policy Uncertainty | Economic policy uncertainty is an index of policy uncertainty for the United States and the euro area from Baker, Bloom, and Davis (2012). It refers to the weighted average of three indicators, including the frequency of the appearance of terms like “economic policy” and “uncertainty” in the media, the number of tax provisions that will expire in the coming years, and the dispersion of forecasts of future government outlays and inflation. | Baker, Bloom, and Davis (2012) |
f. Macroeconomic Policy Variables
f. Macroeconomic Policy Variables
Variable | Definition | Source |
---|---|---|
Government Expenditures | Primary government expenditure = expenditure −interest expense from WEO for 2006 onward and spliced back using data from Public Finances in Modern History Database (PFMHD). Series is a mix of general and central government data for some countries. | WEO, PFMHD |
Short-Term Interest Rates | Policy rates from GDS or policy/discount rates from IFS depending on the length of the data. If three- or four-month Treasury bill rate series are longer, they are used as proxies. Observations are dropped in instances where inflation is greater than 50 percent from the previous year. | GDS, Haver Analytics, IFS |
Central Bank Assets | Total Central Bank Assets. Principal series are from Haver Analytics and spliced backward using growth rates from IFS. Series were deflated with WEO consumer price index (CPI). Euro area countries data were converted to euros using exchange rates from Eurostat. Foreign assets are from IFS and calculated as a percentage of the total. Series were deflated using WEO CPI and are expressed as a percent of real GDP for the year prior to the crisis. |
Haver Analytics, Bank of England, IFS |
Public Debt-to-GDP Ratio | Gross Government Debt from WEO (for 2006 onward) and spliced backward using PFMHD data. Data were deflated using WEO CPI. Series is a mix of general and central government data for some countries. | WEO, PFMHD |
Overall Balance | Defined as the difference between revenue and total expenditure, using the 2001 edition of the IMF’s Government Finance Statistics Manual (GFSM 2001). | Fiscal Monitor |
Net Debt | Gross debt minus financial assets, including those held by the broader public sector; for example, social security funds held by the relevant component of the public sector, in some cases. | Fiscal Monitor |
Gross Domestic Debt | All liabilities that require future payment of interest and/or principal by the debtor to the creditor. The term “public debt” is used in the Fiscal Monitor, for simplicity, as synonymous with gross debt of the general government, unless specified otherwise. (Strictly speaking, public debt refers to the debt of the public sector as a whole, which includes financial and nonfinancial public enterprises and the central bank.) | Fiscal Monitor |
f. Macroeconomic Policy Variables
Variable | Definition | Source |
---|---|---|
Government Expenditures | Primary government expenditure = expenditure −interest expense from WEO for 2006 onward and spliced back using data from Public Finances in Modern History Database (PFMHD). Series is a mix of general and central government data for some countries. | WEO, PFMHD |
Short-Term Interest Rates | Policy rates from GDS or policy/discount rates from IFS depending on the length of the data. If three- or four-month Treasury bill rate series are longer, they are used as proxies. Observations are dropped in instances where inflation is greater than 50 percent from the previous year. | GDS, Haver Analytics, IFS |
Central Bank Assets | Total Central Bank Assets. Principal series are from Haver Analytics and spliced backward using growth rates from IFS. Series were deflated with WEO consumer price index (CPI). Euro area countries data were converted to euros using exchange rates from Eurostat. Foreign assets are from IFS and calculated as a percentage of the total. Series were deflated using WEO CPI and are expressed as a percent of real GDP for the year prior to the crisis. |
Haver Analytics, Bank of England, IFS |
Public Debt-to-GDP Ratio | Gross Government Debt from WEO (for 2006 onward) and spliced backward using PFMHD data. Data were deflated using WEO CPI. Series is a mix of general and central government data for some countries. | WEO, PFMHD |
Overall Balance | Defined as the difference between revenue and total expenditure, using the 2001 edition of the IMF’s Government Finance Statistics Manual (GFSM 2001). | Fiscal Monitor |
Net Debt | Gross debt minus financial assets, including those held by the broader public sector; for example, social security funds held by the relevant component of the public sector, in some cases. | Fiscal Monitor |
Gross Domestic Debt | All liabilities that require future payment of interest and/or principal by the debtor to the creditor. The term “public debt” is used in the Fiscal Monitor, for simplicity, as synonymous with gross debt of the general government, unless specified otherwise. (Strictly speaking, public debt refers to the debt of the public sector as a whole, which includes financial and nonfinancial public enterprises and the central bank.) | Fiscal Monitor |
g. Variables Used in Regressions in Chapter 11
g. Variables Used in Regressions in Chapter 11
Variable | Definition | Source |
---|---|---|
Rest of the World per Capita Output Growth | For each country it is the PPP-weighted output growth of the remaining countries in the sample minus their population growth. | |
World Real Interest Rate | Difference between the three-month U.S. dollar LIBOR interest rate and U.S. inflation. | |
Trade Openness | Ratio of the sum of exports and imports to GDP. | World Development Indicators |
Financial Openness | Ratio of the sum of total assets and liabilities to GDP. | Lane and Milesi-Ferretti (2007) |
External Leverage | Ratio of a country’s total assets to its gross equity liabilities (domestic and foreign). |
g. Variables Used in Regressions in Chapter 11
Variable | Definition | Source |
---|---|---|
Rest of the World per Capita Output Growth | For each country it is the PPP-weighted output growth of the remaining countries in the sample minus their population growth. | |
World Real Interest Rate | Difference between the three-month U.S. dollar LIBOR interest rate and U.S. inflation. | |
Trade Openness | Ratio of the sum of exports and imports to GDP. | World Development Indicators |
Financial Openness | Ratio of the sum of total assets and liabilities to GDP. | Lane and Milesi-Ferretti (2007) |
External Leverage | Ratio of a country’s total assets to its gross equity liabilities (domestic and foreign). |
2. List of Countries: Functional Groups (163 Countries)
Advanced Economies (24) | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|
Australia* | Denmark * | Iceland | Netherlands* | Sweden* |
Austria* | Finland* | Ireland* | New Zealand* | Switzerland* |
Belgium* | France* | Italy* | Norway* | United Kingdom* |
Canada* | Germany* | Japan* | Portugal* | United States* |
Cyprus | Greece* | Luxembourg | Spain* |
Advanced Economies (24) | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|
Australia* | Denmark * | Iceland | Netherlands* | Sweden* |
Austria* | Finland* | Ireland* | New Zealand* | Switzerland* |
Belgium* | France* | Italy* | Norway* | United Kingdom* |
Canada* | Germany* | Japan* | Portugal* | United States* |
Cyprus | Greece* | Luxembourg | Spain* |
Emerging Markets (30) | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|
Argentina* | Costa Rica* | Israel* | Pakistan | South Africa* |
Brazil* | Czech Republic | Jordan | Peru* | Taiwan Province of China* |
Chile* | Egypt | Korea* | Philippines* | Thailand* |
China: Mainland* | Hungary | Malaysia* | Poland | Turkey* |
Hong Kong SAR* | India* | Mexico* | Russia | Ukraine |
Colombia* | Indonesia* | Morocco | Singapore* | Venezuela* |
Emerging Markets (30) | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|
Argentina* | Costa Rica* | Israel* | Pakistan | South Africa* |
Brazil* | Czech Republic | Jordan | Peru* | Taiwan Province of China* |
Chile* | Egypt | Korea* | Philippines* | Thailand* |
China: Mainland* | Hungary | Malaysia* | Poland | Turkey* |
Hong Kong SAR* | India* | Mexico* | Russia | Ukraine |
Colombia* | Indonesia* | Morocco | Singapore* | Venezuela* |
Other Developing Economies (109) | ||
---|---|---|
Afghanistan | Cameroon | Guatemala |
Algeria | Cape Verde | Guinea |
Antigua and Barbuda | Central African Republic | Guinea-Bissau |
Armenia | Democratic Republic of the Congo | Guyana |
Azerbaijan | Republic of Congo | Haiti |
The Bahamas | Croatia | Honduras |
Bahrain | CÔte d’Ivoire | Iran, Islamic Rep. of |
Bangladesh | Djibouti | Jamaica |
Barbados | Dominica | Kazakhstan |
Belarus | Dominican Republic | Kenya |
Benin | Ecuador* | Kiribati |
Bhutan | El Salvador | Kyrgyz Republic |
Bolivia | Eritrea | Lao P.D.R. |
Bosnia and Herzegovina | Estonia | Latvia |
Botswana | Ethiopia | Lesotho |
Brunei Darussalam | Fiji | Liberia |
Bulgaria | Gabon | Libya |
Burkina Faso | Georgia | Lithuania |
Burundi | Ghana | Macedonia, former Yugoslav Republic of |
Cambodia | Grenada | |
Madagascar | Qatar | São Tomé and PrÍncipe |
Malawi | Romania | Tajikistan |
Maldives | Rwanda | Tanzania |
Mali | St. Kitts and Nevis | Timor-Leste |
Malta | St. Lucia | Tonga |
Mauritius | St. Vincent and the Grenadines | Trinidad and Tobago |
Moldova | Samoa | Tunisia |
Montenegro | Saudi Arabia | Turkmenistan |
Mozambique | Senegal | United Arab Emirates |
Myanmar | Serbia | Uruguay* |
Namibia | Seychelles | Uzbekistan |
Nicaragua | Slovak Republic | Vanuatu |
Niger | Slovenia | Vietnam |
Nigeria | Sri Lanka | Yemen |
Oman | Sudan | Zambia |
Papua New Guinea | Suriname | Zimbabwe |
Paraguay | Syria |
Other Developing Economies (109) | ||
---|---|---|
Afghanistan | Cameroon | Guatemala |
Algeria | Cape Verde | Guinea |
Antigua and Barbuda | Central African Republic | Guinea-Bissau |
Armenia | Democratic Republic of the Congo | Guyana |
Azerbaijan | Republic of Congo | Haiti |
The Bahamas | Croatia | Honduras |
Bahrain | CÔte d’Ivoire | Iran, Islamic Rep. of |
Bangladesh | Djibouti | Jamaica |
Barbados | Dominica | Kazakhstan |
Belarus | Dominican Republic | Kenya |
Benin | Ecuador* | Kiribati |
Bhutan | El Salvador | Kyrgyz Republic |
Bolivia | Eritrea | Lao P.D.R. |
Bosnia and Herzegovina | Estonia | Latvia |
Botswana | Ethiopia | Lesotho |
Brunei Darussalam | Fiji | Liberia |
Bulgaria | Gabon | Libya |
Burkina Faso | Georgia | Lithuania |
Burundi | Ghana | Macedonia, former Yugoslav Republic of |
Cambodia | Grenada | |
Madagascar | Qatar | São Tomé and PrÍncipe |
Malawi | Romania | Tajikistan |
Maldives | Rwanda | Tanzania |
Mali | St. Kitts and Nevis | Timor-Leste |
Malta | St. Lucia | Tonga |
Mauritius | St. Vincent and the Grenadines | Trinidad and Tobago |
Moldova | Samoa | Tunisia |
Montenegro | Saudi Arabia | Turkmenistan |
Mozambique | Senegal | United Arab Emirates |
Myanmar | Serbia | Uruguay* |
Namibia | Seychelles | Uzbekistan |
Nicaragua | Slovak Republic | Vanuatu |
Niger | Slovenia | Vietnam |
Nigeria | Sri Lanka | Yemen |
Oman | Sudan | Zambia |
Papua New Guinea | Suriname | Zimbabwe |
Paraguay | Syria |
3. List of Countries: Regional Groups (128)
Emerging Asia (10) | |
---|---|
China: Mainland | Malaysia |
Hong Kong SAR | Philippines |
India | Singapore |
Indonesia | Taiwan Province of China |
Korea | Thailand |
Emerging Asia (10) | |
---|---|
China: Mainland | Malaysia |
Hong Kong SAR | Philippines |
India | Singapore |
Indonesia | Taiwan Province of China |
Korea | Thailand |
Developing Asia (15) | ||
---|---|---|
Bangladesh | Lao P.D.R. | Samoa |
Bhutan | Maldives | Sri Lanka |
Cambodia | Myanmar | Tonga |
Fiji | Pakistan | Vanuatu |
Kiribati | Papua New Guinea | Vietnam |
Developing Asia (15) | ||
---|---|---|
Bangladesh | Lao P.D.R. | Samoa |
Bhutan | Maldives | Sri Lanka |
Cambodia | Myanmar | Tonga |
Fiji | Pakistan | Vanuatu |
Kiribati | Papua New Guinea | Vietnam |
Latin America and the Caribbean (30) | ||
---|---|---|
Antigua and Barbuda | Dominican Republic | Nicaragua |
Argentina | Ecuador | Paraguay |
The Bahamas | El Salvador | Peru |
Barbados | Grenada | St. Kitts and Nevis |
Bolivia | Guatemala | St. Lucia |
Brazil | Guyana | St. Vincent and the Grenadines |
Chile | Haiti | Suriname |
Colombia | Honduras | Trinidad and Tobago |
Costa Rica | Jamaica | Uruguay |
Dominica | Mexico | Venezuela |
Latin America and the Caribbean (30) | ||
---|---|---|
Antigua and Barbuda | Dominican Republic | Nicaragua |
Argentina | Ecuador | Paraguay |
The Bahamas | El Salvador | Peru |
Barbados | Grenada | St. Kitts and Nevis |
Bolivia | Guatemala | St. Lucia |
Brazil | Guyana | St. Vincent and the Grenadines |
Chile | Haiti | Suriname |
Colombia | Honduras | Trinidad and Tobago |
Costa Rica | Jamaica | Uruguay |
Dominica | Mexico | Venezuela |
Middle East and North Africa (14) | ||
---|---|---|
Algeria | Libya | Syria |
Bahrain | Morocco | Tunisia |
Egypt | Oman | United Arab Emirates |
Iran, Islamic Rep. of | Qatar | Yemen |
Jordan | Saudi Arabia |
Middle East and North Africa (14) | ||
---|---|---|
Algeria | Libya | Syria |
Bahrain | Morocco | Tunisia |
Egypt | Oman | United Arab Emirates |
Iran, Islamic Rep. of | Qatar | Yemen |
Jordan | Saudi Arabia |
Emerging Europe and Commonwealth of Independent States (24) | |||
---|---|---|---|
Armenia | Estonia | Lithuania | Russia |
Azerbaijan | Georgia | Macedonia, former Yugoslav Republic of | Slovak Republic |
Belarus | Hungary | Malta | Tajikistan |
Bulgaria | Kazakhstan | Moldova | Turkey |
Croatia | Kyrgyz Republic | Poland | Turkmenistan |
Czech Republic | Latvia | Romania | Uzbekistan |
Emerging Europe and Commonwealth of Independent States (24) | |||
---|---|---|---|
Armenia | Estonia | Lithuania | Russia |
Azerbaijan | Georgia | Macedonia, former Yugoslav Republic of | Slovak Republic |
Belarus | Hungary | Malta | Tajikistan |
Bulgaria | Kazakhstan | Moldova | Turkey |
Croatia | Kyrgyz Republic | Poland | Turkmenistan |
Czech Republic | Latvia | Romania | Uzbekistan |
Sub-Saharan Africa (35) | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|
Benin | Democratic Republic of the Congo | Guinea | Mauritius | Seychelles |
Botswana | Republic of Congo | Guinea-Bissau | Mozambique | South Africa |
Burkina Faso | CÔte d’Ivoire | Kenya | Namibia | Sudan |
Burundi | Djibouti | Lesotho | Niger | Tanzania |
Cameroon | Ethiopia | Madagascar | Nigeria | Tunisia |
Cabo Verde | Gabon | Malawi | Rwanda | Zambia |
Central African Republic | Ghana | Mali | Senegal | Zimbabwe |
Sub-Saharan Africa (35) | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|
Benin | Democratic Republic of the Congo | Guinea | Mauritius | Seychelles |
Botswana | Republic of Congo | Guinea-Bissau | Mozambique | South Africa |
Burkina Faso | CÔte d’Ivoire | Kenya | Namibia | Sudan |
Burundi | Djibouti | Lesotho | Niger | Tanzania |
Cameroon | Ethiopia | Madagascar | Nigeria | Tunisia |
Cabo Verde | Gabon | Malawi | Rwanda | Zambia |
Central African Republic | Ghana | Mali | Senegal | Zimbabwe |
4. List of Countries Used in Regressions in Chapter 11 (97 Countries)
Advanced Economies (21) | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|
Australia | Finland | Ireland | New Zealand | Sweden |
Austria | France | Italy | Norway | Switzerland |
Belgium | Germany | Japan | Portugal | United Kingdom |
Canada | Greece | Netherlands | Spain | United States |
Denmark |
Advanced Economies (21) | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|
Australia | Finland | Ireland | New Zealand | Sweden |
Austria | France | Italy | Norway | Switzerland |
Belgium | Germany | Japan | Portugal | United Kingdom |
Canada | Greece | Netherlands | Spain | United States |
Denmark |
Emerging Markets (30) | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|
Argentina | Czech Republic | Israel | Pakistan | South Africa |
Brazil | Egypt | Jordan | Peru | Taiwan Province of China |
Chile | Hong Kong SAR | Korea | Philippines | Thailand |
China: Mainland | Hungary | Malaysia | Poland | Turkey |
Colombia | India | Mexico | Russia | Ukraine |
Costa Rica | Indonesia | Morocco | Singapore | Venezuela |
Emerging Markets (30) | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|
Argentina | Czech Republic | Israel | Pakistan | South Africa |
Brazil | Egypt | Jordan | Peru | Taiwan Province of China |
Chile | Hong Kong SAR | Korea | Philippines | Thailand |
China: Mainland | Hungary | Malaysia | Poland | Turkey |
Colombia | India | Mexico | Russia | Ukraine |
Costa Rica | Indonesia | Morocco | Singapore | Venezuela |
Other Developing Economies (46) | ||
---|---|---|
Bangladesh | Jamaica | Niger |
Belarus | Kazakhstan | Papua New Guinea |
Benin | Kenya | Paraguay |
Bolivia | Kyrgyz Republic | Romania |
Bulgaria | Latvia | Saudi Arabia |
Burkina Faso | Lesotho | Senegal |
Cameroon | Liberia | Slovak Republic |
Central African Republic | Lithuania | Slovenia |
Republic of Congo | Macedonia, former Yugoslav Republic of | Sri Lanka |
Dominican Republic | Madagascar | Tanzania |
Ecuador | Malawi | Trinidad and Tobago |
El Salvador | Mali | Tunisia |
Estonia | Mauritius | Uruguay |
Ghana | Mozambique | Uzbekistan |
Guatemala | Namibia | Vietnam |
Honduras |
Other Developing Economies (46) | ||
---|---|---|
Bangladesh | Jamaica | Niger |
Belarus | Kazakhstan | Papua New Guinea |
Benin | Kenya | Paraguay |
Bolivia | Kyrgyz Republic | Romania |
Bulgaria | Latvia | Saudi Arabia |
Burkina Faso | Lesotho | Senegal |
Cameroon | Liberia | Slovak Republic |
Central African Republic | Lithuania | Slovenia |
Republic of Congo | Macedonia, former Yugoslav Republic of | Sri Lanka |
Dominican Republic | Madagascar | Tanzania |
Ecuador | Malawi | Trinidad and Tobago |
El Salvador | Mali | Tunisia |
Estonia | Mauritius | Uruguay |
Ghana | Mozambique | Uzbekistan |
Guatemala | Namibia | Vietnam |
Honduras |
Appendix C. Evolution of Purchasing Power Parity and Market Weights
Evolution of Purchasing Power Parity and Market Weights
(in percent)Note: Market weights (purchasing-power-parity weights) are the ratio of total gross domestic product (GDP) in U.S. dollars (GDP in purchasing power parity) of countries in each group to the total GDP in U.S. dollars (GDP in purchasing power parity) of all countries in the sample.
Evolution of Purchasing Power Parity and Market Weights
(in percent)1960s | 1970s | 1980s | 1990s | 2000s | Full Sample | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Market weights | ||||||
Advanced economies | 87.53 | 67.63 | 70.75 | 76.74 | 70.92 | 74.25 |
Emerging market economies | 10.55 | 23.32 | 21.67 | 19.35 | 24.28 | 20.27 |
Other developing economies | 1.91 | 9.05 | 7.58 | 3.91 | 4.80 | 5.48 |
Purchasing-power-parity weights | ||||||
Advanced economies | 72.39 | 64.20 | 61.01 | 60.03 | 52.88 | 61.37 |
Emerging market economies | 22.51 | 26.74 | 30.11 | 32.24 | 38.71 | 30.71 |
Other developing economies | 5.10 | 9.06 | 8.88 | 7.72 | 8.41 | 7.92 |
Note: Market weights (purchasing-power-parity weights) are the ratio of total gross domestic product (GDP) in U.S. dollars (GDP in purchasing power parity) of countries in each group to the total GDP in U.S. dollars (GDP in purchasing power parity) of all countries in the sample.
Evolution of Purchasing Power Parity and Market Weights
(in percent)1960s | 1970s | 1980s | 1990s | 2000s | Full Sample | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Market weights | ||||||
Advanced economies | 87.53 | 67.63 | 70.75 | 76.74 | 70.92 | 74.25 |
Emerging market economies | 10.55 | 23.32 | 21.67 | 19.35 | 24.28 | 20.27 |
Other developing economies | 1.91 | 9.05 | 7.58 | 3.91 | 4.80 | 5.48 |
Purchasing-power-parity weights | ||||||
Advanced economies | 72.39 | 64.20 | 61.01 | 60.03 | 52.88 | 61.37 |
Emerging market economies | 22.51 | 26.74 | 30.11 | 32.24 | 38.71 | 30.71 |
Other developing economies | 5.10 | 9.06 | 8.88 | 7.72 | 8.41 | 7.92 |
Note: Market weights (purchasing-power-parity weights) are the ratio of total gross domestic product (GDP) in U.S. dollars (GDP in purchasing power parity) of countries in each group to the total GDP in U.S. dollars (GDP in purchasing power parity) of all countries in the sample.
Appendix D. Crises around Global Recessions and Global Downturns
1. Banking Crises
Note: Global recessions: 1975, 1982, 1991, 2009; global downturns: 1998, 2001.
1. Banking Crises
1975 | 1982 | 1991 | 2009 | 1998 | 2001 |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Central African Rep. (1976) Chile (1976) Israel (1977) Spain (1977) Mexico (1977) |
Argentina (1980) Morocco (1980) Chile (1981) Mexico (1981) Uruguay (1981) Colombia (1982) Ecuador (1982) Ghana (1982) Turkey (1982) Chad (1983) Dem. Rep. of Congo (1983) Nigeria (1983) Peru (1983) Philippines (1983) Thailand (1983) |
Argentina (1989) Jordan (1989) Sri Lanka (1989) Algeria (1990) Brazil (1990) Romania (1990) Lebanon (1990) Nicaragua (1990) Sierra Leone (1990) Dem. Rep. of Congo (1991) Finland (1991) Georgia (1991) Hungary (1991) Liberia (1991) Norway (1991) Sweden (1991) Tunisia (1991) Bosnia and Herzegovina (1992) Chad (1992) Estonia (1992) Kenya (1992) Poland (1992) Rep. of Congo (1992) São Tomé and PrÍncipe (1992) Slovenia (1992) Guinea (1993) India (1993) Guyana (1993) Togo (1993) Macedonia FYR (1993) |
United Kingdom (2007) United States (2007) Austria (2008) Belgium (2008) Denmark (2008) France (2008) Greece (2008) Hungary (2008) Iceland (2008) Ireland (2008) Italy (2008) Latvia (2008) Luxembourg (2008) Kazakhstan (2008) Mongolia (2008) Netherlands (2008) Portugal (2008) Russia (2008) Slovenia (2008) Spain (2008) Sweden (2008) Switzerland (2008) Ukraine (2008) Nigeria (2009) |
Bulgaria (1996) Czech Republic (1996) Jamaica (1996) Yemen (1996) Indonesia (1997) Japan (1997) Korea (1997) Malaysia (1997) Philippines (1997) Thailand (1997) Vietnam (1997) China (1998) Colombia (1998) Croatia (1998) Ecuador (1998) Slovak Republic (1998) Ukraine (1998) |
Turkey (2000) Argentina (2001) Uruguay (2002) |
Note: Global recessions: 1975, 1982, 1991, 2009; global downturns: 1998, 2001.
1. Banking Crises
1975 | 1982 | 1991 | 2009 | 1998 | 2001 |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Central African Rep. (1976) Chile (1976) Israel (1977) Spain (1977) Mexico (1977) |
Argentina (1980) Morocco (1980) Chile (1981) Mexico (1981) Uruguay (1981) Colombia (1982) Ecuador (1982) Ghana (1982) Turkey (1982) Chad (1983) Dem. Rep. of Congo (1983) Nigeria (1983) Peru (1983) Philippines (1983) Thailand (1983) |
Argentina (1989) Jordan (1989) Sri Lanka (1989) Algeria (1990) Brazil (1990) Romania (1990) Lebanon (1990) Nicaragua (1990) Sierra Leone (1990) Dem. Rep. of Congo (1991) Finland (1991) Georgia (1991) Hungary (1991) Liberia (1991) Norway (1991) Sweden (1991) Tunisia (1991) Bosnia and Herzegovina (1992) Chad (1992) Estonia (1992) Kenya (1992) Poland (1992) Rep. of Congo (1992) São Tomé and PrÍncipe (1992) Slovenia (1992) Guinea (1993) India (1993) Guyana (1993) Togo (1993) Macedonia FYR (1993) |
United Kingdom (2007) United States (2007) Austria (2008) Belgium (2008) Denmark (2008) France (2008) Greece (2008) Hungary (2008) Iceland (2008) Ireland (2008) Italy (2008) Latvia (2008) Luxembourg (2008) Kazakhstan (2008) Mongolia (2008) Netherlands (2008) Portugal (2008) Russia (2008) Slovenia (2008) Spain (2008) Sweden (2008) Switzerland (2008) Ukraine (2008) Nigeria (2009) |
Bulgaria (1996) Czech Republic (1996) Jamaica (1996) Yemen (1996) Indonesia (1997) Japan (1997) Korea (1997) Malaysia (1997) Philippines (1997) Thailand (1997) Vietnam (1997) China (1998) Colombia (1998) Croatia (1998) Ecuador (1998) Slovak Republic (1998) Ukraine (1998) |
Turkey (2000) Argentina (2001) Uruguay (2002) |
Note: Global recessions: 1975, 1982, 1991, 2009; global downturns: 1998, 2001.
2. Currency Crises
2. Currency Crises
1975 | 1982 | 1991 | 2009 | 1998 | 2001 |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Bolivia (1973) Argentina (1975) Iceland (1975) Israel (1975) Maldives (1975) Myanmar (1975) Brazil (1976) Bangladesh (1976) Dem. Rep. of Congo (1976) Peru (1976) Mexico (1977) |
Israel (1980) Guinea-Bissau (1980) Argentina (1981) Bolivia (1981) Costa Rica (1981) Iceland (1981) Italy (1981) Morocco (1981) Peru (1981) Brazil (1982) Chile (1982) Ecuador (1982) Guinea (1982) Mexico (1982) Dem. Rep. of Congo (1983) Ghana (1983) Greece (1983) Nigeria (1983) Philippines (1983) Portugal (1983) Spain (1983) Sierra Leone (1983) Uruguay (1983) Botswana (1984) Lebanon (1984) Madagascar (1984) Namibia (1984) Nepal (1984) New Zealand (1984) Paraguay (1984) South Africa (1984) Turkey (1984) Venezuela (1984) |
Dem. Rep. of Congo (1989) Iceland (1989) Jordan (1989) Paraguay (1989) Venezuela (1989) Dominican Rep. (1990) Honduras (1990) Lebanon (1990) Mongolia (1990) Myanmar (1990) Nicaragua (1990) Suriname (1990) Tanzania (1990) Uruguay (1990) Angola (1991) Costa Rica (1991) Jamaica (1991) Rwanda (1991) Brazil (1992) Cambodia (1992) Estonia (1992) Georgia (1992) Haiti (1992) Latvia (1992) Lithuania (1992) Nepal (1992) São Tomé and PrÍncipe (1992) Cape Verde (1993) Ethiopia (1993) Finland (1993) Ghana (1993) Mauritania (1993) Iran, Islamic Rep. of (1993) Sweden (1993) |
Iceland (2008) Venezuela (2010) |
Bulgaria (1996) Romania (1996) Turkey (1996) Kyrgyz Republic (1997) Lao P.D.R. (1997) Mongolia (1997) Nigeria (1997) São Tomé and PrÍncipe (1997) Fiji (1998) Indonesia (1998) Malaysia (1998) Philippines (1998) Sierra Leone (1998) |
Belarus (1999) Brazil (1999) Dem. Rep. of Congo (1999) Georgia (1999) Hong Kong SAR (1999) Kazakhstan (1999) Tajikistan (1999) Ghana (2000) Serbia (2000) Myanmar (2001) Suriname (2001) Argentina (2002) Libya (2002) Paraguay (2002) Uruguay (2002) Venezuela (2002) Dominican Rep. (2003) Haiti (2003) The Gambia (2004) |
2. Currency Crises
1975 | 1982 | 1991 | 2009 | 1998 | 2001 |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Bolivia (1973) Argentina (1975) Iceland (1975) Israel (1975) Maldives (1975) Myanmar (1975) Brazil (1976) Bangladesh (1976) Dem. Rep. of Congo (1976) Peru (1976) Mexico (1977) |
Israel (1980) Guinea-Bissau (1980) Argentina (1981) Bolivia (1981) Costa Rica (1981) Iceland (1981) Italy (1981) Morocco (1981) Peru (1981) Brazil (1982) Chile (1982) Ecuador (1982) Guinea (1982) Mexico (1982) Dem. Rep. of Congo (1983) Ghana (1983) Greece (1983) Nigeria (1983) Philippines (1983) Portugal (1983) Spain (1983) Sierra Leone (1983) Uruguay (1983) Botswana (1984) Lebanon (1984) Madagascar (1984) Namibia (1984) Nepal (1984) New Zealand (1984) Paraguay (1984) South Africa (1984) Turkey (1984) Venezuela (1984) |
Dem. Rep. of Congo (1989) Iceland (1989) Jordan (1989) Paraguay (1989) Venezuela (1989) Dominican Rep. (1990) Honduras (1990) Lebanon (1990) Mongolia (1990) Myanmar (1990) Nicaragua (1990) Suriname (1990) Tanzania (1990) Uruguay (1990) Angola (1991) Costa Rica (1991) Jamaica (1991) Rwanda (1991) Brazil (1992) Cambodia (1992) Estonia (1992) Georgia (1992) Haiti (1992) Latvia (1992) Lithuania (1992) Nepal (1992) São Tomé and PrÍncipe (1992) Cape Verde (1993) Ethiopia (1993) Finland (1993) Ghana (1993) Mauritania (1993) Iran, Islamic Rep. of (1993) Sweden (1993) |
Iceland (2008) Venezuela (2010) |
Bulgaria (1996) Romania (1996) Turkey (1996) Kyrgyz Republic (1997) Lao P.D.R. (1997) Mongolia (1997) Nigeria (1997) São Tomé and PrÍncipe (1997) Fiji (1998) Indonesia (1998) Malaysia (1998) Philippines (1998) Sierra Leone (1998) |
Belarus (1999) Brazil (1999) Dem. Rep. of Congo (1999) Georgia (1999) Hong Kong SAR (1999) Kazakhstan (1999) Tajikistan (1999) Ghana (2000) Serbia (2000) Myanmar (2001) Suriname (2001) Argentina (2002) Libya (2002) Paraguay (2002) Uruguay (2002) Venezuela (2002) Dominican Rep. (2003) Haiti (2003) The Gambia (2004) |
3. Debt Crises
Note: Crises that are three years before and after the global recessions and downturns are reported. The crises dates are from Laeven and Valencia (2008, 2012).
3. Debt Crises
1975 | 1982 | 1991 | 2009 | 1998 | 2001 |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Dem. Rep. of Congo (1976) Sierra Leone (1977) |
Bolivia (1980) Liberia (1980) Nicaragua (1980) Costa Rica (1981) Madagascar (1981) Honduras (1981) Poland (1981) Uganda (1981) Argentina (1982) Dominican Rep. (1982) Ecuador (1982) Guyana (1982) Malawi (1982) Mexico (1982) Paraguay (1982) Romania (1982) Venezuela (1982) Brazil (1983) Chile (1983) Morocco (1983) Niger (1983) Nigeria (1983) Panama (1983) Philippines (1983) Uruguay (1983) Yugoslavia (1983) Zambia (1983) CÔte d’Ivoire (1984) Mozambique (1984) Tanzania (1984) |
Cameroon (1989) Jordan (1989) Trinidad and Tobago (1989) Albania (1990) Bulgaria (1990) Iran, Islamic Rep. of (1992) |
Hong Kong SAR (2008) Ireland (2008) Greece (2009) Spain (2010) Portugal (2011) Cyprus (2012) |
Russia (1998) | Hong Kong SAR (1999) Indonesia (1999) Argentina (2001) CÔte d’Ivoire (2001) Dominica (2002) Gabon (2002) Moldova (2002) Uruguay (2002) Dominican Rep. (2003) |
Note: Crises that are three years before and after the global recessions and downturns are reported. The crises dates are from Laeven and Valencia (2008, 2012).
3. Debt Crises
1975 | 1982 | 1991 | 2009 | 1998 | 2001 |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Dem. Rep. of Congo (1976) Sierra Leone (1977) |
Bolivia (1980) Liberia (1980) Nicaragua (1980) Costa Rica (1981) Madagascar (1981) Honduras (1981) Poland (1981) Uganda (1981) Argentina (1982) Dominican Rep. (1982) Ecuador (1982) Guyana (1982) Malawi (1982) Mexico (1982) Paraguay (1982) Romania (1982) Venezuela (1982) Brazil (1983) Chile (1983) Morocco (1983) Niger (1983) Nigeria (1983) Panama (1983) Philippines (1983) Uruguay (1983) Yugoslavia (1983) Zambia (1983) CÔte d’Ivoire (1984) Mozambique (1984) Tanzania (1984) |
Cameroon (1989) Jordan (1989) Trinidad and Tobago (1989) Albania (1990) Bulgaria (1990) Iran, Islamic Rep. of (1992) |
Hong Kong SAR (2008) Ireland (2008) Greece (2009) Spain (2010) Portugal (2011) Cyprus (2012) |
Russia (1998) | Hong Kong SAR (1999) Indonesia (1999) Argentina (2001) CÔte d’Ivoire (2001) Dominica (2002) Gabon (2002) Moldova (2002) Uruguay (2002) Dominican Rep. (2003) |
Note: Crises that are three years before and after the global recessions and downturns are reported. The crises dates are from Laeven and Valencia (2008, 2012).
Appendix E. Timeline: Selected Events around Global Recessions and Recoveries
1975 Global Recession
A. End of the Gold Standard
1971
August 15: Exit of the United States from the Bretton Woods gold standard system; suspension of the convertibility of dollars into gold; end of the system of fixed bilateral exchange rates established at Bretton Woods in 1944 (The Economist 1971)
B. 1973–74 Oil Embargo
1973
October 6–26: Yom Kippur/Ramadan war between a coalition of Arab states and Israel (BBC News 1973)
October 16: Start of an oil embargo by the Arab members of the Organization of the Petroleum Exporting Countries against countries siding with Israel during the war; the price of oil quadruples, adversely affecting oil importers; massive oil exporter windfall profits and flow of most of the windfall into the U.S. banking system (The Guardian 1973)
1974
January 1: Tripling of oil prices in one month; imposition of U.K. Prime Minister Edward Heath’s “three-day-week,” a measure to reduce electricity consumption in the United Kingdom (The Economist 1974c)
March 17: End of the oil embargo, following the resolution of the Arab-Israeli war (The Economist 1974d)
C. Synchronized Recessions in Advanced Economies
1974
Recessions in Austria, Belgium, Denmark, France, Germany, Greece, Italy, Portugal, Spain, Switzerland, United States, and United Kingdom
D. Stagflation
1973–75
Period of “stagflation” in a number of advanced economies during 1973–75 (The Economist 1973)
1982 Global Recession
A. 1978–80 Second Oil Crisis
1978
August–December: Strikes and demonstrations in the Islamic Republic of Iran; spread of the strikes to the oil sector and reduction of oil production; increase in oil production by Saudi Arabia and other countries to partly offset the lost Iranian production (The Economist 1978a, 1978b)
1979
January 16: Change in the political regime in the Islamic Republic of Iran (The Economist 1979a)
Further decline in oil production by the Islamic Republic of Iran; more than tripling of oil prices between August 1978 and November 1979 (The Economist 1979b)
1980
September 22: Beginning of the Iran-Iraq war; adverse effects of the war on oil production and increase in oil prices (The Economist 1980a)
Inflation at new highs in several advanced economies—13.5 percent in the United States and 17 percent in the United Kingdom in 1980 (The Economist 1980b)
B. Tight Monetary Policies
1979
October: Introduction of explicit targeting of money supply by the Federal Reserve and application of measures to limit credit expansion to fight inflation expectations; discount rate rises to 12 percent (The Economist 1979c)
1981
Federal funds rate is raised to about 18–20 percent to curb inflation in the United States (The Economist 1981b)
1980–82
Introduction of measures to deregulate the thrift industry (which includes institutions that accept deposits); deposit insurance coverage per account raised from $40,000 to $100,000; phaseout of Regulation Q deposit rate ceilings; deregulation of U.S. savings and loan associations to allow commercial lending; banks permitted to offer adjustable rate mortgages (Robinson 2013)
C. Double-Dip Recession in the United States
1980
January: Beginning of the U.S. recession following contractionary monetary policies and high oil prices (The Economist 2010)
1981
July: Beginning of the second U.S. recession; previous recession ended in July 1980 (NBER 2010)
D. Synchronized Recessions in Advanced Economies
1980–82
Recessions in Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, United States, and United Kingdom
E. Less-Developed-Countries (LDC) Debt Crisis
1982
Accumulation of $327 billion in Latin American debt by U.S. commercial banks (FDIC 1997)
Financial crises in Argentina, Bolivia, Chile, Costa Rica, Dominican Republic, Ecuador, Guyana, Honduras, Mexico, Nicaragua, Panama, Paraguay, Uruguay, and Venezuela (Laeven and Valencia 2008, 2013)
August 12: Mexican default on sovereign debt (following falling world oil prices, rising world interest rates, and a reversal of capital flows); rescheduled debt by 16 Latin American and 11 other countries (Rabobank 2013; Sims 2013)
1983–89
Restructuring of LDC sovereign debt; increase in banks’ loan-loss reserves and recognition of losses on their LDC loans; introduction of the Brady Plan in 1989, leading to permanent reduction in loan principal and debt-service obligations of the debtor countries, which agreed to reform their economies and strengthen their debt-service capacity (Sims 2013)
1991 Global Recession
A. Asset Price Busts
1987
October 19 (Black Monday): Sharp declines in stock markets around the world beginning in Hong Kong SAR and spreading to Australia, Canada, New Zealand, Spain, United Kingdom, and United States (Carlson 2006; Goodley 2012)
1990–92
End of the commercial real estate construction boom in the United States (The Economist 1990)
Sharp fall in Japanese stock markets starting in 1990 and collapse by 1992; severe drop in land prices (Kanaya and Woo 2000)
B. Banking Crises
1986–95
Savings and loan crisis: The number of federally insured thrift institutions (savings and loan associations that accept savings deposits and offer mortgages and other loans) in the United States declines from 3,234 to 1,645, with total asset failure of more than $500 billion (Curry and Shibut 2000)
Late 1980s–early 1990s
Nordic crises: Banking crises in Finland, Norway, and Sweden starting in 1991; currency crises in Finland and Sweden starting in 1993 and in Iceland starting in 1989; the first systemic crisis in advanced economies since the 1930s (Laeven and Valencia 2008)
C. European Exchange Rate Mechanism (ERM) Crisis
1990
Expansionary fiscal policies by the German government following the reunification of East and West Germany; tightening monetary policy by the Bundesbank in an attempt to control runaway inflation (Bayer and others 2009)
1992
September 13: Devaluation of the Italian lira by 7 percent against other currencies in participating ERM countries (Mitchener 1992)
September 16 (Black Wednesday): Speculative attack on the British pound; increase of interest rates to 12 percent by the Bank of England and extensive use of foreign currency reserves to prop up the pound; fall of the pound below its minimum level in the ERM; exit of the United Kingdom from the ERM (BBC News 1992)
September 16: Exit of Italy from the ERM; devaluation of the Spanish peseta by 5 percent within the ERM; defense of the Irish pound by the Central Bank of Ireland through overnight interest rate increase to 300 percent (Buiter, Corsetti, and Pesenti 1998)
September 23: Speculative attacks on the French franc; despite successful containment of the attack by the Banque de France, loss of 80 billion francs in reserves and increase in the French repo rate to 13 percent; heavy Bundesbank interventions in support of the franc (Buiter, Corsetti, and Pesenti 1998)
1993
ERM aftershocks: Resumption of speculation against the franc in late June and July 1993; attacks against the Belgian franc and Austrian shilling; widening of ERM bands from 4.5 percent to plus or minus15 percent to end the new speculative attacks (Buiter, Corsetti, and Pesenti 1998)
D. Synchronized Recessions in Advanced Economies
1990–92
Recessions in Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Italy, New Zealand, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, United Kingdom, and United States
E. Persian Gulf War
1990
August 2: Invasion of Kuwait by Iraq; international quarantine of Iraq in mid-August for its conquest of Kuwait (BBC News 1990; New York Times 1990)
November 29: Authorization by United Nations Security Council of use of force against Iraq barring withdrawal from Kuwait by January 15, 1991 (United Nations 1990)
1991
January 17–February 28: Defeat of Iraqi forces after war between the coalition and Iraqi forces; liberation of Kuwait (USA Today 1996)
Rise in oil prices by more than 35 percent between July 1990 and February 1991
F. Transition of Eastern European Economies
1989–92
November 9, 1989: Fall of the Berlin Wall (BBC News 1989)
Beginning of transition process: Construction of democratic institutions and market-oriented economies in eastern European countries after dissolution of the Soviet Union (Office of the Historian 2013)
2009 Global Recession
A. Financial Sector Problems
2007
August 9: Freeze of three investment funds of France’s largest bank, BNP Paribas, following problems calculating the value of their holdings of subprime loans (New York Times 2007)
September 14: Bank run on one of largest U.K. mortgage lenders, Northern Rock, and liquidity support from the Bank of England (Wallop 2007; Shin 2009)
2008
February 17: Nationalization of Northern Rock by the U.K. Treasury (Desai and Jones 2008)
March 14–24: Sale of Bear Stearns to JPMorgan with the backing of the Federal Reserve (Goldstein 2008)
Increase in oil prices to $133 a barrel in July from $53 a barrel in January 2007
September 7: Bailout by the U.S. Treasury of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, the two largest mortgage financing companies in the United States (Sommerville 2008)
September 15: Chapter 12 bankruptcy protection filing by U.S. securities firm Lehman Brothers, under severe liquidity pressure; sale of Merrill Lynch, another large investment bank with liquidity problems, to Bank of America (Mollenkamp and others 2008)
September 16: Bailout of American International Group (AIG), the world’s largest insurance company, by the Federal Reserve (Karnitschnig and others 2008)
September 17: Acquisition of HBOS, the U.K.’s largest mortgage lender, by Lloyds TSB (Cimilluca, Macdonald, and Munoz 2008)
September 21: End of investment banking as Federal Reserve approves designation of Goldman Sachs and JPMorgan Chase as bank holding companies (New York Times 2008)
September 25: Seizure of Washington Mutual (WaMu) by federal regulators and its sale to JPMorgan Chase (Sidel, Enrich, and Fitzpatrick 2008)
October 3: Passage of the Emergency Economic Stabilization Act of 2008, establishing the $700 billion Troubled Asset Relief Program (TARP), by the U.S. Congress (Sahadi 2008)
October 7–8: Failure of three major banks in Iceland with a combined balance sheet equal to several times Iceland’s GDP
October 13: Bailout of several banks, including the Royal Bank of Scotland, Lloyds TSB, and HBOS, by the U.K. government (Wearden 2008)
November 25: Announcement of the Quantitative Easing operations by the Federal Reserve
December 11: Announcement by the Business Cycle Dating Committee of the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) that the United States had been in a recession since December 2007 (NBER 2011)
December 16: Announcement of the target range for the federal funds rate of zero to ¼ percent and start of qualitative forward guidance about future policy rates (Board of Governers of the Federal Reserve System 2008)
B. Synchronized Recessions in Advanced Economies
2007–09
Recessions in Austria, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Japan, New Zealand, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, United Kingdom, and United States
February 2009: Passage of the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act in the United States, which introduced a fiscal stimulus package of more than $780 billion in spending increases and tax relief (New York Times 2009)
April 2009: Announcement of the G20 global stimulus package of $1 trillion to curb the global financial crisis (CNN 2009)
2008:Q1: Start of the recession in euro area (CEPR 2009)
2009:Q2: End of the recession in euro area (CEPR 2010)
June 2009: End of the recession in the United States (NBER 2010)
C. Euro Area Crisis
2010
April 27: Standard & Poor’s downgrade of Greek credit rating to junk status (Reuters 2010)
May 2: Announcement of a series of austerity measures by the Greek government to secure a multiyear loan from the European Union and the IMF (BBC News 2010a)
November 28: Bailout of Ireland with a loan from the European Union; the IMF; and Denmark, Sweden, and the United Kingdom (BBC News 2010b)
2011
May 5: Financial rescue package for Portugal from the European Union and the IMF (Kowsmann 2011)
July 21: Second bailout package for Greece from the European Union, the IMF, and banks and private investors (BBC News 2011; IMF 2011b)
August 5: Downgrade of U.S. sovereign debt by Standard & Poor’s (Paletta and Phillips 2011)
August 7: Announcement by the European Central Bank (ECB) of purchase of Italian and Spanish government bonds (Carrell 2011)
2011:Q3: Start of the recession in euro area (CEPR 2012)
October 4–18: Downgrades of credit ratings of Italy and Spain by the three main rating agencies (Totaro and Ross-Thomas 2011)
2012
June 25: Bailout request by Cyprus, making it the fifth euro area country to seek international help (Reuters 2012)
July 26: Speech by Mario Draghi, president of the ECB, on the ECB’s readiness to do whatever is needed to preserve the euro (Bloomberg News 2012)
Recessions in Austria, Belgium, Cyprus, Estonia, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Malta, Netherlands, Portugal, Slovenia, Spain, and United Kingdom
D. A Brief List of Events during 2013–15
2013
February 1: Dow Jones Industrial Average rises above 14,000 for the first time since October 2007.
April 5: The Bank of Japan announces policies aimed at increasing inflation to 2 percent within two years.
May 21: After the Federal Reserve Chairman says the Fed could stop its bond-buying program (known as QE) over the next two Federal Open Market Committee meetings if economic conditions continued to improve, global financial markets react sharply. Several emerging market economies saw their currencies depreciate, equity markets drop, and capital flows reverse.
December 18: The Federal Reserve announces it will end its QE program in 2014.
2014
June 5: European Central Bank launches bold measures including negative interest rate to boost euro area growth and inflation.
June 19: Brent oil price reaches $115 a barrel for the first time since September 2013.
October 29: The Federal Reserve ends its QE program.
October 31: The Bank of Japan increases its annual asset purchases target by between 15 and 33 percent.
November 17: Japan's economy slips back into recession.
November 27: Morgan Stanley Country Index (MSCI) demotes Greece to emerging market status.
November 27: The Organization of the Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC) decides to maintain its production target of 30 million barrels a day, established in December 2011, unchanged despite the sharp drop in oil prices.
December 23: U.S. economy posts strongest growth in more than a decade.
2015
January 12: Brent crude oil prices fall below $50 a barrel, a six-year low (almost a 60 percent drop since oil prices started to fall in June 2014 (Baffes and others 2015).
January 15: The Swiss National Bank abandons its policy instituted in 2011 of capping the Swiss franc vis-À-vis the euro (at Sfr 1.20 to the euro).
January 22: The European Central Bank announces an aggressive quantitative easing plan. The bank plans to buy up bonds worth up to 60 billion euros a month for at least 19 months.
January 25: Elections in Greece bring a radical left party (Syriza) to power. The new government announces plans to renegotiate the bailout program with its creditors, increase the minimum wage, hire additional government employees, cancel privatization plans, and provide free food and electricity to the poor.
February 20: The new government of Greece and its creditors agree on an extension of the second bailout program to the end of June.
March 2: The Nasdaq tops the 5,000 level for the first time in 15 years.
March 9: The European Central Bank starts its bond-buying (QE) program.
March 21: The U.S. dollar rises 22 percent over the past year (its fastest climb in decades) against a basket of widely used currencies.
April 27: Fitch downgrades Japan’s credit rating over fiscal concerns.
May 8: U.S. unemployment rate falls to 5.4 percent in April, a seven-year low.
May 12: Greece makes IMF debt payment after using its own emergency account in the Fund.
July 12: The Chinese stock markets plunge by more than 1/3 from their peaks in mid-June.
July 14: IMF report finds that Greece’s public debt is unsustainable.
August 14: Europe agrees on new bailout terms for Greece.
August 24: China has its own “Black Monday”: the Shanghai Composite Index closes down 8.5 percent and is followed by significant losses in global stock markets.
August 28: Brazil enters recession after activity contracts 1.9 percent in the second quarter.
September 4: The U.S. unemployment rate falls to 5.1 percent in August, a seven year low.
September 9: Standard & Poor’s downgrades Brazil’s sovereign credit rating to “junk” status.
September 17: The Federal Reserve keeps its policy interest rate close to zero citing concerns about global economic and financial developments.
Appendix F. Global Recessions: Regional Country Groups
Global Recessions: Regional Country Groups
Global Recessions: Regional Country Groups
Average 1972–74 | 1975 | Average 1979–81 | 1982 | Average 1988–90 | 1991 | Average 2006–08 | 2009 | Average All Global Recessions | Average Non-Recession Years 1960–2012 | Average 1960–2012 | Average Three Years Before | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Emerging Asia | ||||||||||||
Total output (PW) | 5.75 | 7.14 | 5.50 | 5.68 | 7.35 | 6.76 | 9.20 | 6.18 | 6.44 | 6.73 | 6.71 | 6.95 |
Total output (MW) | 5.54 | 7.08 | 5.69 | 5.72 | 7.41 | 7.04 | 8.66 | 5.66 | 6.38 | 6.80 | 6.77 | 6.83 |
Per capita output (PW) | 3.42 | 5.05 | 3.68 | 3.77 | 5.60 | 5.12 | 8.21 | 5.23 | 4.79 | 5.04 | 5.02 | 5.23 |
Per capita output (MW) | 3.22 | 4.99 | 3.87 | 3.80 | 5.66 | 5.40 | 7.67 | 4.71 | 4.73 | 5.12 | 5.09 | 5.10 |
Developing Asia | ||||||||||||
Total output (PW) | 2.97 | 3.63 | 5.14 | 5.55 | 4.79 | 5.01 | 6.56 | 3.79 | 4.50 | 5.00 | 4.96 | 4.86 |
Total output (MW) | 2.63 | 3.48 | 4.61 | 5.71 | 4.29 | 4.63 | 6.44 | 3.75 | 4.39 | 4.83 | 4.80 | 4.49 |
Per capita output (PW) | 0.32 | 1.61 | 1.65 | 3.36 | 2.52 | 2.94 | 5.05 | 1.51 | 2.35 | 1.47 | 1.54 | 2.39 |
Per capita output (MW) | −0.02 | 1.46 | 1.11 | 3.51 | 2.02 | 2.56 | 4.93 | 1.46 | 2.25 | 1.30 | 1.37 | 2.01 |
Latin America and the Caribbean | ||||||||||||
Total output (PW) | 7.90 | 3.45 | 4.78 | −0.66 | 1.03 | 3.83 | 5.20 | −1.56 | 1.27 | 4.19 | 3.96 | 4.73 |
Total output (MW) | 7.03 | 2.63 | 4.32 | −1.11 | 0.55 | 3.68 | 5.08 | −1.65 | 0.89 | 4.00 | 3.76 | 4.24 |
Per capita output (PW) | 5.28 | 0.44 | 2.78 | −2.86 | −0.92 | 1.98 | 3.91 | −2.90 | −0.84 | 2.10 | 1.87 | 2.76 |
Per capita output (MW) | 4.41 | −0.39 | 2.32 | −3.31 | −1.40 | 1.83 | 3.78 | −2.99 | −1.21 | 1.92 | 1.68 | 2.28 |
Middle East and North Africa | ||||||||||||
Total output (PW) | 11.38 | 5.16 | 0.85 | 2.63 | 4.72 | 7.59 | 5.27 | 3.00 | 4.60 | 5.06 | 5.02 | 5.55 |
Total output (MW) | 10.11 | 5.44 | 0.67 | 0.70 | 4.39 | 6.73 | 5.44 | 2.38 | 3.81 | 4.31 | 4.27 | 5.15 |
Per capita output (PW) | 8.53 | 2.39 | −2.22 | −0.67 | 2.27 | 4.80 | 3.14 | 0.81 | 1.83 | 2.32 | 2.28 | 2.93 |
Per capita output (MW) | 7.26 | 2.66 | −2.40 | −2.60 | 1.95 | 3.94 | 3.31 | 0.18 | 1.05 | 1.58 | 1.54 | 2.53 |
Sub-Saharan Africa | ||||||||||||
Total output (PW) | 4.96 | 2.05 | 5.37 | 0.53 | 3.45 | 0.35 | 5.72 | 2.79 | 1.43 | 4.06 | 3.86 | 4.88 |
Total output (MW) | 4.75 | 1.58 | 5.25 | 0.05 | 2.81 | 0.09 | 5.35 | 2.56 | 1.07 | 3.71 | 3.51 | 4.54 |
Per capita output (PW) | 2.44 | −0.76 | 2.83 | −2.52 | −0.01 | −2.61 | 3.28 | 0.29 | −1.40 | 1.25 | 1.05 | 2.13 |
Per capita output (MW) | 2.22 | −1.22 | 2.70 | −3.00 | −0.66 | −2.86 | 2.91 | 0.06 | −1.76 | 0.90 | 0.70 | 1.79 |
Emerging Europe and CIS | ||||||||||||
Total output (PW) | 5.90 | 5.37 | 2.21 | 2.76 | 2.32 | −6.14 | 6.52 | −4.76 | −0.69 | 3.89 | 3.54 | 4.24 |
Total output (MW) | 5.69 | 5.13 | 2.54 | 3.19 | 2.64 | −5.85 | 6.24 | −5.02 | −0.64 | 3.66 | 3.33 | 4.28 |
Per capita output (PW) | 4.80 | 4.20 | 1.56 | 1.92 | 1.78 | −6.84 | 6.16 | −5.29 | −1.50 | 3.07 | 2.72 | 3.58 |
Per capita output (MW) | 4.59 | 3.96 | 1.90 | 2.35 | 2.10 | −6.55 | 5.88 | −5.55 | −1.45 | 2.83 | 2.50 | 3.62 |
Global Recessions: Regional Country Groups
Average 1972–74 | 1975 | Average 1979–81 | 1982 | Average 1988–90 | 1991 | Average 2006–08 | 2009 | Average All Global Recessions | Average Non-Recession Years 1960–2012 | Average 1960–2012 | Average Three Years Before | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Emerging Asia | ||||||||||||
Total output (PW) | 5.75 | 7.14 | 5.50 | 5.68 | 7.35 | 6.76 | 9.20 | 6.18 | 6.44 | 6.73 | 6.71 | 6.95 |
Total output (MW) | 5.54 | 7.08 | 5.69 | 5.72 | 7.41 | 7.04 | 8.66 | 5.66 | 6.38 | 6.80 | 6.77 | 6.83 |
Per capita output (PW) | 3.42 | 5.05 | 3.68 | 3.77 | 5.60 | 5.12 | 8.21 | 5.23 | 4.79 | 5.04 | 5.02 | 5.23 |
Per capita output (MW) | 3.22 | 4.99 | 3.87 | 3.80 | 5.66 | 5.40 | 7.67 | 4.71 | 4.73 | 5.12 | 5.09 | 5.10 |
Developing Asia | ||||||||||||
Total output (PW) | 2.97 | 3.63 | 5.14 | 5.55 | 4.79 | 5.01 | 6.56 | 3.79 | 4.50 | 5.00 | 4.96 | 4.86 |
Total output (MW) | 2.63 | 3.48 | 4.61 | 5.71 | 4.29 | 4.63 | 6.44 | 3.75 | 4.39 | 4.83 | 4.80 | 4.49 |
Per capita output (PW) | 0.32 | 1.61 | 1.65 | 3.36 | 2.52 | 2.94 | 5.05 | 1.51 | 2.35 | 1.47 | 1.54 | 2.39 |
Per capita output (MW) | −0.02 | 1.46 | 1.11 | 3.51 | 2.02 | 2.56 | 4.93 | 1.46 | 2.25 | 1.30 | 1.37 | 2.01 |
Latin America and the Caribbean | ||||||||||||
Total output (PW) | 7.90 | 3.45 | 4.78 | −0.66 | 1.03 | 3.83 | 5.20 | −1.56 | 1.27 | 4.19 | 3.96 | 4.73 |
Total output (MW) | 7.03 | 2.63 | 4.32 | −1.11 | 0.55 | 3.68 | 5.08 | −1.65 | 0.89 | 4.00 | 3.76 | 4.24 |
Per capita output (PW) | 5.28 | 0.44 | 2.78 | −2.86 | −0.92 | 1.98 | 3.91 | −2.90 | −0.84 | 2.10 | 1.87 | 2.76 |
Per capita output (MW) | 4.41 | −0.39 | 2.32 | −3.31 | −1.40 | 1.83 | 3.78 | −2.99 | −1.21 | 1.92 | 1.68 | 2.28 |
Middle East and North Africa | ||||||||||||
Total output (PW) | 11.38 | 5.16 | 0.85 | 2.63 | 4.72 | 7.59 | 5.27 | 3.00 | 4.60 | 5.06 | 5.02 | 5.55 |
Total output (MW) | 10.11 | 5.44 | 0.67 | 0.70 | 4.39 | 6.73 | 5.44 | 2.38 | 3.81 | 4.31 | 4.27 | 5.15 |
Per capita output (PW) | 8.53 | 2.39 | −2.22 | −0.67 | 2.27 | 4.80 | 3.14 | 0.81 | 1.83 | 2.32 | 2.28 | 2.93 |
Per capita output (MW) | 7.26 | 2.66 | −2.40 | −2.60 | 1.95 | 3.94 | 3.31 | 0.18 | 1.05 | 1.58 | 1.54 | 2.53 |
Sub-Saharan Africa | ||||||||||||
Total output (PW) | 4.96 | 2.05 | 5.37 | 0.53 | 3.45 | 0.35 | 5.72 | 2.79 | 1.43 | 4.06 | 3.86 | 4.88 |
Total output (MW) | 4.75 | 1.58 | 5.25 | 0.05 | 2.81 | 0.09 | 5.35 | 2.56 | 1.07 | 3.71 | 3.51 | 4.54 |
Per capita output (PW) | 2.44 | −0.76 | 2.83 | −2.52 | −0.01 | −2.61 | 3.28 | 0.29 | −1.40 | 1.25 | 1.05 | 2.13 |
Per capita output (MW) | 2.22 | −1.22 | 2.70 | −3.00 | −0.66 | −2.86 | 2.91 | 0.06 | −1.76 | 0.90 | 0.70 | 1.79 |
Emerging Europe and CIS | ||||||||||||
Total output (PW) | 5.90 | 5.37 | 2.21 | 2.76 | 2.32 | −6.14 | 6.52 | −4.76 | −0.69 | 3.89 | 3.54 | 4.24 |
Total output (MW) | 5.69 | 5.13 | 2.54 | 3.19 | 2.64 | −5.85 | 6.24 | −5.02 | −0.64 | 3.66 | 3.33 | 4.28 |
Per capita output (PW) | 4.80 | 4.20 | 1.56 | 1.92 | 1.78 | −6.84 | 6.16 | −5.29 | −1.50 | 3.07 | 2.72 | 3.58 |
Per capita output (MW) | 4.59 | 3.96 | 1.90 | 2.35 | 2.10 | −6.55 | 5.88 | −5.55 | −1.45 | 2.83 | 2.50 | 3.62 |
Appendix G. Sensitivity of Global Activity Variables
Sensitivity of Global Activity Variables
Note: Each cell represents the sensitivity of the respective activity variable to changes in global output. The sensitivities of world consumption per capita, investment, industrial production, and trade to changes in global output are computed by estimating a basic regression of the growth rates of each of these variables on the growth rate of world GDP per capita (measured in purchasing-power-parity and market-weighted terms). All coefficients are statistically significant at the 1 percent level.
Sensitivity of Global Activity Variables
Consumption | Investment | Industrial Production | Trade | |
---|---|---|---|---|
Purchasing-power-parity-weighted per capita output | 0.777 [0.076] |
2.228 [0.139] |
2.440 [0.202] |
2.454 [0.261] |
Market-weighted per capita output | 0.771 [0.079] |
1.985 [0.144] |
2.479 [0.203] |
2.440 [0.251] |
Note: Each cell represents the sensitivity of the respective activity variable to changes in global output. The sensitivities of world consumption per capita, investment, industrial production, and trade to changes in global output are computed by estimating a basic regression of the growth rates of each of these variables on the growth rate of world GDP per capita (measured in purchasing-power-parity and market-weighted terms). All coefficients are statistically significant at the 1 percent level.
Sensitivity of Global Activity Variables
Consumption | Investment | Industrial Production | Trade | |
---|---|---|---|---|
Purchasing-power-parity-weighted per capita output | 0.777 [0.076] |
2.228 [0.139] |
2.440 [0.202] |
2.454 [0.261] |
Market-weighted per capita output | 0.771 [0.079] |
1.985 [0.144] |
2.479 [0.203] |
2.440 [0.251] |
Note: Each cell represents the sensitivity of the respective activity variable to changes in global output. The sensitivities of world consumption per capita, investment, industrial production, and trade to changes in global output are computed by estimating a basic regression of the growth rates of each of these variables on the growth rate of world GDP per capita (measured in purchasing-power-parity and market-weighted terms). All coefficients are statistically significant at the 1 percent level.
Appendix H. Global Recoveries: Regional Country Groups
Global Recoveries: Regional Country Groups
(percent change unless otherwise noted)Global Recoveries: Regional Country Groups
(percent change unless otherwise noted)1976 | Average 1976–78 | 1983 | Average 1983–85 | 1992 | Average 1992–94 | 2010 | Average 2010–12 | Average of First Years | Average 1960–2012 Non-Recession Years | Average 1960–2012 | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Emerging Asia | |||||||||||
Total output (PW) | 4.45 | 6.68 | 7.77 | 7.62 | 8.53 | 8.98 | 9.80 | 7.69 | 7.64 | 7.74 | 6.71 |
Total output (MW) | 3.82 | 6.50 | 7.89 | 7.92 | 8.02 | 8.54 | 9.72 | 7.66 | 7.36 | 7.66 | 6.77 |
Per capita output (PW) | 2.77 | 4.87 | 6.00 | 5.84 | 6.97 | 7.42 | 8.82 | 6.73 | 6.14 | 6.22 | 5.02 |
Per capita output (MW) | 2.13 | 4.69 | 6.12 | 6.14 | 6.46 | 6.99 | 8.75 | 6.70 | 5.87 | 6.13 | 5.09 |
Developing Asia | |||||||||||
Total output (PW) | 4.90 | 5.28 | 5.69 | 5.67 | 7.16 | 5.46 | 5.32 | 5.22 | 5.76 | 5.41 | 4.96 |
Total output (MW) | 6.14 | 5.87 | 5.71 | 5.74 | 6.93 | 5.24 | 5.31 | 5.24 | 6.03 | 5.52 | 4.80 |
Per capita output (PW) | 2.58 | 2.89 | 3.29 | 3.28 | 4.84 | 3.14 | 3.76 | 3.68 | 3.62 | 3.25 | 1.54 |
Per capita output (MW) | 3.83 | 3.48 | 3.31 | 3.35 | 4.62 | 2.92 | 3.75 | 3.71 | 3.88 | 3.36 | 1.37 |
Latin America and the Caribbean | |||||||||||
Total output (PW) | 5.64 | 4.95 | −2.50 | 1.45 | 3.30 | 4.05 | 6.15 | 4.51 | 3.15 | 3.74 | 3.96 |
Total output (MW) | 4.33 | 4.36 | −2.19 | 1.05 | 3.42 | 4.21 | 6.08 | 4.28 | 2.91 | 3.47 | 3.76 |
Per capita output (PW) | 3.13 | 2.51 | −4.67 | −0.65 | 1.52 | 2.32 | 4.92 | 3.30 | 1.22 | 1.87 | 1.87 |
Per capita output (MW) | 1.81 | 1.92 | −4.36 | −1.04 | 1.64 | 2.48 | 4.85 | 3.07 | 0.99 | 1.61 | 1.68 |
Middle East and North Africa | |||||||||||
Total output (PW) | 12.24 | 7.08 | 2.31 | 2.38 | 3.53 | 1.91 | 5.32 | 4.45 | 5.85 | 3.95 | 5.02 |
Total output (MW) | 12.39 | 7.16 | 0.96 | 1.51 | 3.33 | 1.91 | 5.21 | 4.58 | 5.47 | 3.79 | 4.27 |
Per capita output (PW) | 9.88 | 4.15 | −1.05 | −1.01 | −1.27 | −0.96 | 3.33 | 4.58 | 2.72 | 1.69 | 2.28 |
Per capita output (MW) | 10.03 | 4.23 | −2.41 | −1.88 | −1.47 | −0.97 | 3.22 | 4.72 | 2.34 | 1.53 | 1.54 |
Sub-Saharan Africa | |||||||||||
Total output (PW) | 6.03 | 2.08 | −1.09 | 1.25 | −0.88 | 0.99 | 5.13 | 4.62 | 2.30 | 2.23 | 3.86 |
Total output (MW) | 4.94 | 1.71 | −1.52 | 1.02 | −1.15 | 0.86 | 4.98 | 4.42 | 1.81 | 2.00 | 3.51 |
Per capita output (PW) | 3.27 | −0.77 | −4.07 | −1.75 | −3.73 | −1.70 | 2.68 | 2.48 | −0.46 | −0.43 | 1.05 |
Per capita output (MW) | 2.18 | −1.14 | −4.51 | −1.98 | −4.00 | −1.83 | 2.53 | 2.28 | −0.95 | −0.67 | 0.70 |
Emerging Europe and Commonwealth of Independent States | |||||||||||
Total output (PW) | 6.55 | 5.64 | 4.12 | 3.15 | −8.77 | −6.20 | 4.71 | 4.08 | 1.65 | 1.67 | 3.54 |
Total output (MW) | 6.47 | 5.52 | 4.19 | 3.15 | −8.34 | −4.66 | 4.72 | 4.13 | 1.76 | 2.03 | 3.33 |
Per capita output (PW) | 5.48 | 4.57 | 2.73 | 2.08 | −9.15 | −6.35 | 3.99 | 3.55 | 0.76 | 0.96 | 2.72 |
Per capita output (MW) | 5.40 | 4.45 | 2.80 | 2.08 | −8.72 | −4.80 | 4.00 | 3.60 | 0.87 | 1.33 | 2.50 |
Global Recoveries: Regional Country Groups
(percent change unless otherwise noted)1976 | Average 1976–78 | 1983 | Average 1983–85 | 1992 | Average 1992–94 | 2010 | Average 2010–12 | Average of First Years | Average 1960–2012 Non-Recession Years | Average 1960–2012 | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Emerging Asia | |||||||||||
Total output (PW) | 4.45 | 6.68 | 7.77 | 7.62 | 8.53 | 8.98 | 9.80 | 7.69 | 7.64 | 7.74 | 6.71 |
Total output (MW) | 3.82 | 6.50 | 7.89 | 7.92 | 8.02 | 8.54 | 9.72 | 7.66 | 7.36 | 7.66 | 6.77 |
Per capita output (PW) | 2.77 | 4.87 | 6.00 | 5.84 | 6.97 | 7.42 | 8.82 | 6.73 | 6.14 | 6.22 | 5.02 |
Per capita output (MW) | 2.13 | 4.69 | 6.12 | 6.14 | 6.46 | 6.99 | 8.75 | 6.70 | 5.87 | 6.13 | 5.09 |
Developing Asia | |||||||||||
Total output (PW) | 4.90 | 5.28 | 5.69 | 5.67 | 7.16 | 5.46 | 5.32 | 5.22 | 5.76 | 5.41 | 4.96 |
Total output (MW) | 6.14 | 5.87 | 5.71 | 5.74 | 6.93 | 5.24 | 5.31 | 5.24 | 6.03 | 5.52 | 4.80 |
Per capita output (PW) | 2.58 | 2.89 | 3.29 | 3.28 | 4.84 | 3.14 | 3.76 | 3.68 | 3.62 | 3.25 | 1.54 |
Per capita output (MW) | 3.83 | 3.48 | 3.31 | 3.35 | 4.62 | 2.92 | 3.75 | 3.71 | 3.88 | 3.36 | 1.37 |
Latin America and the Caribbean | |||||||||||
Total output (PW) | 5.64 | 4.95 | −2.50 | 1.45 | 3.30 | 4.05 | 6.15 | 4.51 | 3.15 | 3.74 | 3.96 |
Total output (MW) | 4.33 | 4.36 | −2.19 | 1.05 | 3.42 | 4.21 | 6.08 | 4.28 | 2.91 | 3.47 | 3.76 |
Per capita output (PW) | 3.13 | 2.51 | −4.67 | −0.65 | 1.52 | 2.32 | 4.92 | 3.30 | 1.22 | 1.87 | 1.87 |
Per capita output (MW) | 1.81 | 1.92 | −4.36 | −1.04 | 1.64 | 2.48 | 4.85 | 3.07 | 0.99 | 1.61 | 1.68 |
Middle East and North Africa | |||||||||||
Total output (PW) | 12.24 | 7.08 | 2.31 | 2.38 | 3.53 | 1.91 | 5.32 | 4.45 | 5.85 | 3.95 | 5.02 |
Total output (MW) | 12.39 | 7.16 | 0.96 | 1.51 | 3.33 | 1.91 | 5.21 | 4.58 | 5.47 | 3.79 | 4.27 |
Per capita output (PW) | 9.88 | 4.15 | −1.05 | −1.01 | −1.27 | −0.96 | 3.33 | 4.58 | 2.72 | 1.69 | 2.28 |
Per capita output (MW) | 10.03 | 4.23 | −2.41 | −1.88 | −1.47 | −0.97 | 3.22 | 4.72 | 2.34 | 1.53 | 1.54 |
Sub-Saharan Africa | |||||||||||
Total output (PW) | 6.03 | 2.08 | −1.09 | 1.25 | −0.88 | 0.99 | 5.13 | 4.62 | 2.30 | 2.23 | 3.86 |
Total output (MW) | 4.94 | 1.71 | −1.52 | 1.02 | −1.15 | 0.86 | 4.98 | 4.42 | 1.81 | 2.00 | 3.51 |
Per capita output (PW) | 3.27 | −0.77 | −4.07 | −1.75 | −3.73 | −1.70 | 2.68 | 2.48 | −0.46 | −0.43 | 1.05 |
Per capita output (MW) | 2.18 | −1.14 | −4.51 | −1.98 | −4.00 | −1.83 | 2.53 | 2.28 | −0.95 | −0.67 | 0.70 |
Emerging Europe and Commonwealth of Independent States | |||||||||||
Total output (PW) | 6.55 | 5.64 | 4.12 | 3.15 | −8.77 | −6.20 | 4.71 | 4.08 | 1.65 | 1.67 | 3.54 |
Total output (MW) | 6.47 | 5.52 | 4.19 | 3.15 | −8.34 | −4.66 | 4.72 | 4.13 | 1.76 | 2.03 | 3.33 |
Per capita output (PW) | 5.48 | 4.57 | 2.73 | 2.08 | −9.15 | −6.35 | 3.99 | 3.55 | 0.76 | 0.96 | 2.72 |
Per capita output (MW) | 5.40 | 4.45 | 2.80 | 2.08 | −8.72 | −4.80 | 4.00 | 3.60 | 0.87 | 1.33 | 2.50 |
Appendix I. Uncertainty, Business Cycles, and Growth
1. Uncertainty over the Business Cycle
1. Uncertainty over the Business Cycle
Country-Specific Uncertainty | Uncertainty in the United States | Economic Policy Uncertainty | Global Uncertainty | |
---|---|---|---|---|
Recession | 1.29*** | 24.12*** | 134.59*** | 1.61*** |
[0.08] | [0.50] | [2.78] | [0.18] | |
Expansion | 0.93*** | 19.03*** | 100.56*** | −0.24*** |
[0.03] | [0.06] | [0.51] | [0.02] | |
Number of observations | 3,138 | 4,158 | 2,268 | 4,347 |
Number of economies | 21 | 21 | 21 | 21 |
R2 adjusted | 0.77 | 0.89 | 0.92 | 0.07 |
Test (P values) | ||||
h0: Recession coefficient = Expansion coefficient | 0.00 | 0.00 | 0.00 | 0.00 |
1. Uncertainty over the Business Cycle
Country-Specific Uncertainty | Uncertainty in the United States | Economic Policy Uncertainty | Global Uncertainty | |
---|---|---|---|---|
Recession | 1.29*** | 24.12*** | 134.59*** | 1.61*** |
[0.08] | [0.50] | [2.78] | [0.18] | |
Expansion | 0.93*** | 19.03*** | 100.56*** | −0.24*** |
[0.03] | [0.06] | [0.51] | [0.02] | |
Number of observations | 3,138 | 4,158 | 2,268 | 4,347 |
Number of economies | 21 | 21 | 21 | 21 |
R2 adjusted | 0.77 | 0.89 | 0.92 | 0.07 |
Test (P values) | ||||
h0: Recession coefficient = Expansion coefficient | 0.00 | 0.00 | 0.00 | 0.00 |
2. Uncertainty and Growth
2. Uncertainty and Growth
Output | Consumption | Investment | ||||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | |
Country-specific uncertainty | −0.65* [0.37] |
−0.23 [0.38] |
−1.18 [0.99] |
|||||||||
Uncertainty in the United States | −0.18*** [0.01] |
−0.12*** [0.01] |
−0.41*** [0.06] |
|||||||||
Economic policy uncertainty | −0.01*** [0.00] |
−0.01** [0.00] |
−0.02** [0.01] |
|||||||||
Global uncertainty | −0.46*** [0.03] |
−0.31*** [0.04] |
−0.87*** [0.164] |
|||||||||
Number of observations | 3,117 | 4,157 | 2,267 | 4,283 | 3,115 | 4,155 | 2,265 | 4,281 | 3,111 | 4,041 | 2,265 | 4,123 |
Number of economies | 21 | 21 | 21 | 21 | 21 | 21 | 21 | 21 | 21 | 21 | 21 | 21 |
R2 adjusted | 0.42 | 0.38 | 0.44 | 0.38 | 0.09 | 0.13 | 0.06 | 0.13 | 0.31 | 0.25 | 0.35 | 0.25 |
2. Uncertainty and Growth
Output | Consumption | Investment | ||||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | |
Country-specific uncertainty | −0.65* [0.37] |
−0.23 [0.38] |
−1.18 [0.99] |
|||||||||
Uncertainty in the United States | −0.18*** [0.01] |
−0.12*** [0.01] |
−0.41*** [0.06] |
|||||||||
Economic policy uncertainty | −0.01*** [0.00] |
−0.01** [0.00] |
−0.02** [0.01] |
|||||||||
Global uncertainty | −0.46*** [0.03] |
−0.31*** [0.04] |
−0.87*** [0.164] |
|||||||||
Number of observations | 3,117 | 4,157 | 2,267 | 4,283 | 3,115 | 4,155 | 2,265 | 4,281 | 3,111 | 4,041 | 2,265 | 4,123 |
Number of economies | 21 | 21 | 21 | 21 | 21 | 21 | 21 | 21 | 21 | 21 | 21 | 21 |
R2 adjusted | 0.42 | 0.38 | 0.44 | 0.38 | 0.09 | 0.13 | 0.06 | 0.13 | 0.31 | 0.25 | 0.35 | 0.25 |
Appendix J. Linkages between the Global Cycle and National Cycles
1. Linkages between Global and National Cycles: All Countries
1. Linkages between Global and National Cycles: All Countries
Global Recessions | Global Expansions | Full Sample | |||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | (6) | (7) | (8) | (9) | (10) | (11) | |
Output growth (lagged) | 0.395*** [0.071] |
0.370*** [0.075] |
0.411*** [0.077] |
0.285*** [0.039] |
0.291*** [0.040] |
0.282*** [0.039] |
0.289*** [0.037] |
0.293*** [0.038] |
0.286*** [0.037] |
0.286*** [0.037] |
0.287*** [0.037] |
Rest of the world output growth | 1.373*** [0.232] |
1.463*** [0.248] |
0.728*** [0.060] |
0.717*** [0.061] |
0.725*** [0.060] |
0.717*** [0.060] |
0.735*** [0.061] |
0.714*** [0.060] |
|||
Rest of the world output growth × Global recession dummy | 0.507** [0.236] |
0.422* [0.233] |
0.557** [0.244] |
||||||||
Real LIBOR rate | −0.005 [0.063] |
0.081 [0.067] |
−0.135*** [0.033] |
−0.117*** [0.034] |
−0.135*** [0.033] |
−0.091*** [0.032] |
−0.117*** [0.034] |
−0.117*** [0.034] |
|||
Real LIBOR rate × Global recession dummy | 0.113* [0.057] |
0.131** [0.058] |
0.159*** [0.060] |
||||||||
Global recession dummy | 0.089 [0.315] |
−2.864*** [0.279] |
−0.022 [0.312] |
−0.527* [0.274] |
−0.231 [0.312] |
||||||
Constant | −0.002 [0.173] |
−0.970*** [0.204] |
−0.112 [0.209] |
−0.013 [0.187] |
2.065*** [0.114] |
0.262 [0.205] |
−0.016 [0.178] |
2.060*** [0.105] |
0.2 [0.200] |
0.21 [0.200] |
0.258 [0.196] |
Number of observations | 382 | 382 | 382 | 4,197 | 4,197 | 4,197 | 4,579 | 4,579 | 4,579 | 4,579 | 4,579 |
Number of economies | 97 | 97 | 97 | 97 | 97 | 97 | 97 | 97 | 97 | 97 | 97 |
R2 adjusted | 0.15 | 0.096 | 0.152 | 0.133 | 0.101 | 0.136 | 0.16 | 0.13 | 0.16 | 0.16 | 0.16 |
1. Linkages between Global and National Cycles: All Countries
Global Recessions | Global Expansions | Full Sample | |||||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | (6) | (7) | (8) | (9) | (10) | (11) | |
Output growth (lagged) | 0.395*** [0.071] |
0.370*** [0.075] |
0.411*** [0.077] |
0.285*** [0.039] |
0.291*** [0.040] |
0.282*** [0.039] |
0.289*** [0.037] |
0.293*** [0.038] |
0.286*** [0.037] |
0.286*** [0.037] |
0.287*** [0.037] |
Rest of the world output growth | 1.373*** [0.232] |
1.463*** [0.248] |
0.728*** [0.060] |
0.717*** [0.061] |
0.725*** [0.060] |
0.717*** [0.060] |
0.735*** [0.061] |
0.714*** [0.060] |
|||
Rest of the world output growth × Global recession dummy | 0.507** [0.236] |
0.422* [0.233] |
0.557** [0.244] |
||||||||
Real LIBOR rate | −0.005 [0.063] |
0.081 [0.067] |
−0.135*** [0.033] |
−0.117*** [0.034] |
−0.135*** [0.033] |
−0.091*** [0.032] |
−0.117*** [0.034] |
−0.117*** [0.034] |
|||
Real LIBOR rate × Global recession dummy | 0.113* [0.057] |
0.131** [0.058] |
0.159*** [0.060] |
||||||||
Global recession dummy | 0.089 [0.315] |
−2.864*** [0.279] |
−0.022 [0.312] |
−0.527* [0.274] |
−0.231 [0.312] |
||||||
Constant | −0.002 [0.173] |
−0.970*** [0.204] |
−0.112 [0.209] |
−0.013 [0.187] |
2.065*** [0.114] |
0.262 [0.205] |
−0.016 [0.178] |
2.060*** [0.105] |
0.2 [0.200] |
0.21 [0.200] |
0.258 [0.196] |
Number of observations | 382 | 382 | 382 | 4,197 | 4,197 | 4,197 | 4,579 | 4,579 | 4,579 | 4,579 | 4,579 |
Number of economies | 97 | 97 | 97 | 97 | 97 | 97 | 97 | 97 | 97 | 97 | 97 |
R2 adjusted | 0.15 | 0.096 | 0.152 | 0.133 | 0.101 | 0.136 | 0.16 | 0.13 | 0.16 | 0.16 | 0.16 |
2. Linkages between Global and National Cycles: Country Groups
2. Linkages between Global and National Cycles: Country Groups
Advanced Economies | Emerging Market Economies | Other Developing Economies | |||||||||||||
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | (6) | (7) | (8) | (9) | (10) | (11) | (12) | (13) | (14) | (15) | |
Output growth (lagged) | 0.291*** [0.077] |
0.269*** [0.078] |
0.258*** [0.077] |
0.270*** [0.077] |
0.260*** [0.077] |
0.276*** [0.043] |
0.275*** [0.041] |
0.271*** [0.043] |
0.270*** [0.043] |
0.271*** [0.043] |
0.292*** [0.057] |
0.291*** [0.058] |
0.281*** [0.057] |
0.282*** [0.056] |
0.282*** [0.057] |
Rest of the world output growth | 0.660*** [0.068] |
0.683*** [0.067] |
0.724*** [0.073] |
0.681*** [0.067] |
0.693*** [0.089] |
0.684*** [0.088] |
0.709*** [0.093] |
0.682*** [0.088] |
0.778*** [0.109] |
0.759*** [0.110] |
0.760*** [0.110] |
0.755*** [0.110] |
|||
Rest of the world output growth × Global recession dummy | 0.925*** [0.304] |
1.232*** [0.313] |
1.328*** [0.326] |
0.730* [0.393] |
0.602 [0.385] |
0.691 [0.411] |
0.187 [0.430] |
−0.028 [0.421] |
0.156 [0.435] |
||||||
Real LIBOR rate | 0.213*** [0.025] |
0.252*** [0.028] |
0.234*** [0.027] |
0.235*** [0.027] |
−0.185*** [0.052] |
−0.153*** [0.046] |
−0.172*** [0.052] |
−0.173*** [0.052] |
−0.267*** [0.046] |
−0.212*** [0.046] |
−0.246*** [0.047] |
−0.247*** [0.047] |
|||
Real LIBOR rate ×Global recession dummy | 0.012 [0.100] |
0.032 [0.103] |
0.103 [0.107] |
0.066 [0.100] |
0.087 [0.101] |
0.12 [0.106] |
0.188** [0.091] |
0.203** [0.091] |
0.211** [0.094] |
||||||
Global recession dummy | −0.525 [0.566] |
−3.300*** [0.429] |
−0.223 [0.575] |
−0.996* [0.512] |
−0.354 [0.612] |
0.365 [0.594] |
−2.628*** [0.474] |
0.193 [0.593] |
−0.357 [0.501] |
0.03 [0.568] |
0.21 [0.479] |
−2.825*** [0.476] |
−0.052 [0.475] |
−0.41 [0.424] |
−0.327 [0.475] |
Constant | 0.197 [0.246] |
1.464*** [0.164] |
−0.315 [0.240] |
−0.41 [0.238] |
−0.28 [0.236] |
0.614** [0.236] |
2.729*** [0.182] |
0.975*** [0.263] |
0.955*** [0.268] |
1.018*** [0.262] |
−0.530* [0.290] |
1.944*** [0.133] |
−0.029 [0.342] |
0.037 [0.337] |
0.051 [0.333] |
Number of observations | 1,050 | 1,050 | 1,050 | 1,050 | 1,050 | 1,432 | 1,432 | 1,432 | 1,432 | 1,432 | 2,097 | 2,097 | 2,097 | 2,097 | 2,097 |
Number of economies | 21 | 21 | 21 | 21 | 21 | 30 | 30 | 30 | 30 | 30 | 46 | 46 | 46 | 46 | 46 |
R2 adjusted | 0.306 | 0.257 | 0.344 | 0.336 | 0.344 | 0.148 | 0.121 | 0.154 | 0.153 | 0.154 | 0.141 | 0.124 | 0.149 | 0.15 | 0.15 |
2. Linkages between Global and National Cycles: Country Groups
Advanced Economies | Emerging Market Economies | Other Developing Economies | |||||||||||||
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | (6) | (7) | (8) | (9) | (10) | (11) | (12) | (13) | (14) | (15) | |
Output growth (lagged) | 0.291*** [0.077] |
0.269*** [0.078] |
0.258*** [0.077] |
0.270*** [0.077] |
0.260*** [0.077] |
0.276*** [0.043] |
0.275*** [0.041] |
0.271*** [0.043] |
0.270*** [0.043] |
0.271*** [0.043] |
0.292*** [0.057] |
0.291*** [0.058] |
0.281*** [0.057] |
0.282*** [0.056] |
0.282*** [0.057] |
Rest of the world output growth | 0.660*** [0.068] |
0.683*** [0.067] |
0.724*** [0.073] |
0.681*** [0.067] |
0.693*** [0.089] |
0.684*** [0.088] |
0.709*** [0.093] |
0.682*** [0.088] |
0.778*** [0.109] |
0.759*** [0.110] |
0.760*** [0.110] |
0.755*** [0.110] |
|||
Rest of the world output growth × Global recession dummy | 0.925*** [0.304] |
1.232*** [0.313] |
1.328*** [0.326] |
0.730* [0.393] |
0.602 [0.385] |
0.691 [0.411] |
0.187 [0.430] |
−0.028 [0.421] |
0.156 [0.435] |
||||||
Real LIBOR rate | 0.213*** [0.025] |
0.252*** [0.028] |
0.234*** [0.027] |
0.235*** [0.027] |
−0.185*** [0.052] |
−0.153*** [0.046] |
−0.172*** [0.052] |
−0.173*** [0.052] |
−0.267*** [0.046] |
−0.212*** [0.046] |
−0.246*** [0.047] |
−0.247*** [0.047] |
|||
Real LIBOR rate ×Global recession dummy | 0.012 [0.100] |
0.032 [0.103] |
0.103 [0.107] |
0.066 [0.100] |
0.087 [0.101] |
0.12 [0.106] |
0.188** [0.091] |
0.203** [0.091] |
0.211** [0.094] |
||||||
Global recession dummy | −0.525 [0.566] |
−3.300*** [0.429] |
−0.223 [0.575] |
−0.996* [0.512] |
−0.354 [0.612] |
0.365 [0.594] |
−2.628*** [0.474] |
0.193 [0.593] |
−0.357 [0.501] |
0.03 [0.568] |
0.21 [0.479] |
−2.825*** [0.476] |
−0.052 [0.475] |
−0.41 [0.424] |
−0.327 [0.475] |
Constant | 0.197 [0.246] |
1.464*** [0.164] |
−0.315 [0.240] |
−0.41 [0.238] |
−0.28 [0.236] |
0.614** [0.236] |
2.729*** [0.182] |
0.975*** [0.263] |
0.955*** [0.268] |
1.018*** [0.262] |
−0.530* [0.290] |
1.944*** [0.133] |
−0.029 [0.342] |
0.037 [0.337] |
0.051 [0.333] |
Number of observations | 1,050 | 1,050 | 1,050 | 1,050 | 1,050 | 1,432 | 1,432 | 1,432 | 1,432 | 1,432 | 2,097 | 2,097 | 2,097 | 2,097 | 2,097 |
Number of economies | 21 | 21 | 21 | 21 | 21 | 30 | 30 | 30 | 30 | 30 | 46 | 46 | 46 | 46 | 46 |
R2 adjusted | 0.306 | 0.257 | 0.344 | 0.336 | 0.344 | 0.148 | 0.121 | 0.154 | 0.153 | 0.154 | 0.141 | 0.124 | 0.149 | 0.15 | 0.15 |
3. Linkages between Global and National Business Cycles: Roles of Trade and Financial Integration
3. Linkages between Global and National Business Cycles: Roles of Trade and Financial Integration
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | (6) | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Output growth (lagged) | 0.265*** [0.0367] |
0.265*** [0.0366] |
0.266*** [0.0367] |
0.264*** [0.0368] |
0.265*** [0.0369] |
0.265*** [0.0368] |
Rest of the world output growth | 0.774*** [0.0565] |
0.567*** [0.0792] |
0.520*** [0.0748] |
0.772*** [0.0568] |
0.659*** [0.0569] |
0.512*** [0.0752] |
Real LIBOR rate | −0.123*** [0.0351] |
−0.123*** [0.0351] |
−0.142*** [0.0359] |
−0.159*** [0.0417] |
−0.192*** [0.0436] |
−0.191*** [0.0433] |
Trade openness (lagged) | 1.204** [0.584] |
0.666 [0.605] |
0.985 [0.621] |
1.166** [0.564] |
1.397** [0.593] |
0.948 [0.599] |
Financial openness (lagged) | −0.249*** [0.0479] |
−0.264*** [0.0525] |
−0.253*** [0.0501] |
−0.232*** [0.0512] |
−0.218*** [0.0498] |
−0.231*** [0.0537] |
Rest of the world output growth × Trade openness | 0.272*** [0.0837] |
0.210*** [0.0670] |
0.208*** [0.0667] |
|||
Rest of the world output growth × Global recession dummy | 0.875*** [0.302] |
1.103*** [0.319] |
0.925*** [0.305] |
|||
Real LIBOR rate × Global recession dummy | 0.157** [0.0725] |
0.196*** [0.0739] |
0.182** [0.0739] |
|||
Real LIBOR rate × Financial openness | 0.0292* [0.0169] |
0.0380** [0.0177] |
0.0377** [0.0174] |
|||
Global recession dummy | −0.145 [0.386] |
−0.127 [0.389] |
−0.192 [0.386] |
|||
Constant | −0.344 [0.419] |
0.0881 [0.428] |
0.120 [0.441] |
−0.330 [0.404] |
−0.179 [0.418] |
0.154 [0.421] |
Number of observations | 3,465 | 3,465 | 3,465 | 3,465 | 3,465 | 3,465 |
Number of economies | 97 | 97 | 97 | 97 | 97 | 97 |
R2 adjusted | 0.603 | 0.597 | 0.570 | 0.610 | 0.555 | 0.564 |
3. Linkages between Global and National Business Cycles: Roles of Trade and Financial Integration
(1) | (2) | (3) | (4) | (5) | (6) | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Output growth (lagged) | 0.265*** [0.0367] |
0.265*** [0.0366] |
0.266*** [0.0367] |
0.264*** [0.0368] |
0.265*** [0.0369] |
0.265*** [0.0368] |
Rest of the world output growth | 0.774*** [0.0565] |
0.567*** [0.0792] |
0.520*** [0.0748] |
0.772*** [0.0568] |
0.659*** [0.0569] |
0.512*** [0.0752] |
Real LIBOR rate | −0.123*** [0.0351] |
−0.123*** [0.0351] |
−0.142*** [0.0359] |
−0.159*** [0.0417] |
−0.192*** [0.0436] |
−0.191*** [0.0433] |
Trade openness (lagged) | 1.204** [0.584] |
0.666 [0.605] |
0.985 [0.621] |
1.166** [0.564] |
1.397** [0.593] |
0.948 [0.599] |
Financial openness (lagged) | −0.249*** [0.0479] |
−0.264*** [0.0525] |
−0.253*** [0.0501] |
−0.232*** [0.0512] |
−0.218*** [0.0498] |
−0.231*** [0.0537] |
Rest of the world output growth × Trade openness | 0.272*** [0.0837] |
0.210*** [0.0670] |
0.208*** [0.0667] |
|||
Rest of the world output growth × Global recession dummy | 0.875*** [0.302] |
1.103*** [0.319] |
0.925*** [0.305] |
|||
Real LIBOR rate × Global recession dummy | 0.157** [0.0725] |
0.196*** [0.0739] |
0.182** [0.0739] |
|||
Real LIBOR rate × Financial openness | 0.0292* [0.0169] |
0.0380** [0.0177] |
0.0377** [0.0174] |
|||
Global recession dummy | −0.145 [0.386] |
−0.127 [0.389] |
−0.192 [0.386] |
|||
Constant | −0.344 [0.419] |
0.0881 [0.428] |
0.120 [0.441] |
−0.330 [0.404] |
−0.179 [0.418] |
0.154 [0.421] |
Number of observations | 3,465 | 3,465 | 3,465 | 3,465 | 3,465 | 3,465 |
Number of economies | 97 | 97 | 97 | 97 | 97 | 97 |
R2 adjusted | 0.603 | 0.597 | 0.570 | 0.610 | 0.555 | 0.564 |
Bibliography
Abberger, K., and W. Nierhaus. 2008. “How to Define a Recession?” CESifo Forum 4: 74–76.
Abiad, A., R. Balakrishnan, P. Koeva Brooks, D. Leigh, and I. Tytell. 2009. “What’s the Damage? Medium-term Output Dynamics after Banking Crises.” IMF Working Paper 09/245. International Monetary Fund, Washington.
Abiad, A., D. Furceri, and P. Topalova. 2015. “The Macroeconomic Effects of Public Investment: Evidence from Advanced Economies.” IMF Working Paper 15/95. International Monetary Fund.
Acosta, P. A., E. K. K. Lartey, and F. S. Mandelman. 2009. “Remittances and the Dutch Disease.” Journal of International Economics 79 (1): 102–16.
Adrian, T., and H. S. Shin. 2008. “Liquidity, Monetary Policy, and Financial Cycles.” Federal Reserve Bank of New York Current Issues in Economics and Finance 14 (1): 1–7.
Ahmed, S., A. Levin, and B. A. Wilson. 2004. “Recent U.S. Macroeconomic Stability: Good Policies, Good Practices, or Good Luck?” Review of Economics and Statistics 86 (3): 824–32.
Aiolfi, M., L. A. V. Catão, and A. Timmermann. 2011. “Common Factors in Latin America’s Business Cycles.” Journal of Development Economics 95 (2): 212–28.
Akin, C., and M. A. Kose. 2008. “Changing Nature of North-South Linkages: Stylized Facts and Explanations.” Journal of Asian Economics 19: 1–28.
Alesina, A. 2012. “Fiscal Policy after the Great Recession.” Atlantic Economic Journal 40 (4): 429–35.
Alesina A., and S. Ardagna. 2010. “Large Changes in Fiscal Policy: Taxes versus Spending.” Tax Policy and the Economy 24: 35–68.
Alesina, A., and F. Giavazzi. 2013. Fiscal Policy after the Financial Crisis. Chicago: University of Chicago Press and National Bureau of Economic Research.
Alessandria, G., J. P. Kaboski, and V. Midrigan. 2010. “The Great Trade Collapse of 2008–09: An Inventory Adjustment.” IMF Economic Review 58 (2): 254–94.
Allen, R. E., 2010. Financial Crises and Recession in the Global Economy. Cheltenham, United Kingdom: Edward Elgar, 3rd ed.
Almunia, M., A. Benetrix, B. Eichengreen, K. O’Rourke, and G. Rua. 2010. “From Great Depression to Great Credit Crisis: Similarities, Differences, and Lessons.” Economic Policy 25 (62): 219–65.
Altig, D., S. M. Byrne, and K. A. Samolyk. 1992. “Is Household Debt Inhibiting the Recovery?” Economic Commentary. Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.
Ambler, S., E. Cardia, and C. Zimmermann. 2004. “International Business Cycles: What Are the Facts?” Journal of Monetary Economics 51 (2): 257–76.
Amiti, M., and D. E. Weinstein. 2011. “Exports and Financial Shocks.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 126 (4): 1841–77.
Angeloni, I., and J. Pisani-Ferry. 2012. “The G20: Characters in Search of an Author,” Bruegel Working Paper 2012/04.
Aoki, K., J. Proudman, and G. Vlieghe. 2004. “House Prices, Consumption, and Monetary Policy: A Financial Accelerator Approach.” Journal of Financial Intermediation 13 (4): 414–35.
Arellano, C., Y. Bai, and P. Kehoe. 2012. “Financial Markets and Fluctuations in Uncertainty.” Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department Staff Report.
Arora, V., and A. Vamvakidis. 2004. “How Much Do Trading Partners Matter for Economic Growth?” IMF Working Paper 04/26, International Monetary Fund, Washington.
Artis, M. J., Z. G. Kontolemis, and D. R. Osborn. 1997. “Business Cycles for G-7 and European Countries.” Journal of Business 70: 249–79.
Artis, M. J., M. Marcellino, and T. Proietti. 2003. “Dating the Euro Area Business Cycle.” CEPR Discussion Paper 3696, Centre for Economic Policy Research, London.
Aslam, A., S. Beidas-Strom, M. E. Terrones, and J. Yepez. 2014. “Are Global Imbalances at a Turning Point?.” World Economic Outlook. October. International Monetary Fund, Washington.
Atkinson, T., D. Luttrell, and H. Rosenblum. 2013. “How Bad Was It? The Costs and Consequences of the 2007–09 Financial Crisis.” Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Staff Paper No. 20.
Auerbach, A., and Y. Gorodnichenko. 2012. “Measuring the Output Responses to Fiscal Policy.” American Economic Journal—Economic Policy 4: 1–27.
Bacchetta, P., and E. van Wincoop. 2013. “The Great Recession: A Self-Fulfilling Global Panic.” NBER Working Paper 19062, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Massachusetts.
Bachmann, R., and C. Bayer. 2011. “Uncertainty Business Cycles—Really?” NBER Working Paper 16862. National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Massachusetts.
———. 2013. “‘Wait-and-See’ Business Cycles?” Journal of Monetary Economics 60 (6): 704–19.
———. 2014. “Investment Dispersion and the Business Cycle.” American Economic Review, 104 (4): 1392–416.
Bachmann, R., and G. Moscarini. 2011. “Business Cycles and Endogenous Uncertainty.” 2011 Meeting Papers 36, Society for Economic Dynamics.
Baffes, J., M. A. Kose, F. Ohnsorge, and M. Stocker. 2015. “The Great Plunge in Oil Prices: Causes, Consequences, and Policy Responses,” Policy Research Note: 1, World Bank.
Baily, M. N., and B. Bosworth. 2013. “The United States Economy: Why Such a Weak Recovery?” paper presented at the Nomura Foundation’s Macro Economy Research Conference, Prospects for Growth in the World’s Four Major Economies, September 11, Brookings Institution.
Baker, S., and N. Bloom. 2013. “Does Uncertainty Reduce Growth? Using Disasters as Natural Experiments.” NBER Working Paper 19475, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Massachusetts.
Baker, S., N. Bloom, B. Canes-Wrone, S. J. Davis, and J. A. Rodden. 2014. “Why Has U.S. Policy Uncertainty Risen Since 1960?” NBER Working Paper, No. 19826.
Baker, S., N. Bloom, and S. J. Davis. 2012. “The Rocky Balboa Recovery” VoxEU, June 20.
———. 2013. “Measuring Economic Policy Uncertainty.” Stanford University Working Paper, Stanford University, Palo Alto, California.
Baldwin, R., and S. Evenett, eds. 2009. The Collapse of Global Trade, Murky Protectionism, and the Crisis: Recommendations for the G20, VoxEU.
Balke, N. S., and M. A. Wynne. 1995. “Recessions and Recoveries in Real Business Cycle Models,” Economic Inquiry 33: 640–63.
Ball, L. 2014. “Long-term Damage from the Great Recession in OECD Countries,” NBER Working Paper, No. 20185.
Ball, L., D. Leigh, and P. Loungani. 2013. “Okun’s Law: Fit at 50?” IMF Working Paper 13/10, International Monetary Fund, Washington.
Barro, R. J. 1981. Money, Expectations, and Business Cycles. New York.
Barsky, R. B., and L. Kilian. 2004. “Oil and the Macroeconomy since the 1970s.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 18 (4): 115–34.
Barth, J. R., S. Trimbath, and G. Yago. 2004. The Savings and Loan Crisis: Lessons from a Regulatory Failure. Milken Institute Series on Financial Innovation and Economic Growth.
Basu, S., and J. Fernald. 2000. “Why Is Productivity Procyclical? Why Do We Care?” NBER Working Paper 7940, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Massachusetts.
Bauer, M. D., and G. D. Rudebusch. 2012. “The Signaling Channel for Federal Reserve Bond Purchases.” Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Working Paper 2011–21.
Baumeister, C., and L. Benati. 2010. “Unconventional Monetary Policy and the Great Recession.” ECB Working Paper 1258, European Central Bank, Frankfurt.
Baxter, M., and M. A. Kouparitsas. 2005. “Determinants of Business Cycle Comovement: A Robust Analysis.” Journal of Monetary Economics 52 (1): 113–57.
Bayer, A., V. Gaspar, C. Gerberding, and M. Issing. 2009. “Opting Out of the Great Inflation: German Monetary Policy after the Break Down of Bretton Woods.” ECB Working Paper 1020, European Central Bank, Frankfurt.
BBC News. 1973. “Arab States Attack Israeli Forces,” October 6.
———. 1989. “Berliners Celebrate the Fall of the Wall,” November 9.
———. 1990. “Iraq Invades Kuwait,” August 2.
———. 1992. “UK Crashes out of ERM,” September 16.
———. 2010a. “Eurozone Approves Massive Greece Bail-out,” May 2.
———. 2010b. “Irish Republic 85bn Euro Bail-out Agreed,” November 28.
———. 2011. “Eurozone Agrees New 109bn Euros Greek Bailout,” July 21.
Beauchemin, K. R. 2011. “Not Your Father’s Recovery?” FRB Cleveland Economic Commentary (September).
Bems, R., R. C. Johnson, and K. Yi. 2010. “Demand Spillovers and the Collapse of Trade in the Global Recession.” IMF Economic Review 58 (2): 295–326.
———. 2012. “The Great Trade Collapse.” NBER Working Paper 18632, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Massachusetts.
Bergman, U. M., M. D. Bordo, and L. Jonung. 1998. “Historical Evidence on Business Cycles: The International Experience,” in Beyond Shocks: What Causes Business Cycles? edited by J. C. Fuhrer and S. Schuh. Federal Reserve Bank of Boston Conference Series 42: 65–113.
Berkmen, P., G. Gelos, R. Rennhack, and J. P. Walsh. 2009. “The Global Financial Crisis: Explaining Cross-Country Differences in the Output Impact.” IMF Working Paper 09/280, International Monetary Fund, Washington.
Berle, A. A., Jr. 1953. “Wesley Clair Mitchell: The Economic Scientist.” Journal of the American Statistical Association 48 (262): 169–75.
Bernanke, B. S. 1983. “Irreversibility, Uncertainty, and Cyclical Investment.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 98 (1): 85–106.
———. 1993. “Credit in the Macroeconomy,” Federal Reserve Bank of New York Quarterly Review (Spring): 50–70.
———. 2004. “The Great Moderation,” remarks at the meetings of the Eastern Economic Association, Washington, February 20.
———. 2012a. “Monetary Policy since the Onset of the Crisis,” Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Economic Symposium, Jackson Hole, Wyoming.
———. 2012b. “The Economic Recovery and Economic Policy,” remarks at the Economic Club of New York.
———. 2013. The Federal Reserve and the Financial Crisis. Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press.
———. 2014. “The Federal Reserve: Looking Back, Looking Forward,” speech at the Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association, Philadelphia, Pennsylvania, January 3.
———. 2015a. “Why are Interest Rates So Low?” Ben Bernanke’s Blog, Brookings Institute.
———. 2015b. “Why are Interest Rates So Low, part 2: Secular Stagnation” Ben Bernanke’s Blog, Brookings Institute.
———. 2015c. “Why are Interest Rates So Low, part 3: The Global Savings Glut” Ben Bernanke’s Blog, Brookings Institute.
———. 2015d. “Why are Interest Rates So Low, part 4: Term Premiums” Ben Bernanke’s Blog, Brookings Institute.
———. 2015e. “WSJ Editorial Page Watch: The Slow-Growth Fed?” Ben Bernanke’s Blog, Brookings Institute.
Bernanke, B. S., and M. Gertler. 1989. “Agency Costs, Net Worth, and Business Fluctuations,” American Economic Review 79: 14–31.
Bernanke, B. S., and C. S. Lown. 1991. “The Credit Crunch.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2: 205–47.
Bernanke, B. S., M. Gertler, and S. Gilchrist. 1999. “The Financial Accelerator in a Quantitative Business Cycle Framework,” in Handbook of Macroeconomics Vol. 1, edited by J. B. Taylor and M. Woodford, 1341–393.
Blanchard, O. J. 1993. “Consumption and the Recession of 1990–1991,” American Economic Review 83 (2): 270–74.
———. 2001. “Close Encounters with Recessions of the Third Kind.” Project Syndicate, March 12.
———. 2008. “Press Conference on the World Economic Outlook,” October 9. http://www.imf.org/external/index.htm.
———. 2009a. “The State of Macro.” Annual Review of Economics 1 (1): 209–28.
———. 2009b. “The Crisis: Basic Mechanism and Appropriate Policies,” CESifo Forum 10 (1): 3–14.
———. 2009c. “(Nearly) Nothing to Fear but Fear Itself.” Guest Article, Economist, January 29.
———. 2010. “Sustaining a Global Recovery.” Journal of Policy Modeling 32 (5): 604–9.
———. 2013. “Rethinking Macroeconomic Policy.” VoxEU, May 9.
Blanchard, O. J., and S. Fischer. 1989. Lectures on Macroeconomics. Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press.
Blanchard, O. J., and D. Leigh. 2013a. “Fiscal Consolidation: At What Speed?” VoxEU, May 3.
———. 2013b. “Growth Forecast Errors and Fiscal Multipliers.” IMF Working Paper 13/1, International Monetary Fund, Washington.
Blanchard, O. J., and G. M. Milesi-Ferretti. 2012. “(Why) Should Current Account Balances Be Reduced?” IMF Economic Review 60 (1): 139–50.
———. 2009. “Global Imbalances: In Midstream?” IMF Staff Position Note 09/29, International Monetary Fund, Washington.
Blanchard, O. J., and R. Perotti. 2002. “An Empirical Characterization of the Dynamic Effects of Changes in Government Spending and Taxes on Output.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 117 (4): 1329–68.
Blanchard, O. J., and J. Simon. 2001. “The Long and Large Decline in U.S. Output Volatility.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1: 135–64.
Blanchard, O. J., and J. Viñals. 2009. “Joint Foreword to World Economic Outlook and Global Financial Stability Report.” World Economic Outlook, April: xii–xiv. Washington: International Monetary Fund.
Blanchard, O. J., G. Dell’Ariccia, and P. Mauro. 2010. “Rethinking Macroeconomic Policy.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 42 (1): 199–215.
———. 2013. “Rethinking Macroeconomic Policy II: Getting Granular.” IMF Staff Discussion Note13/03, International Monetary Fund, Washington.
Blanchard, O. J., H. Faruqee, and M. Das. 2010. “The Initial Impact of the Crisis on Emerging Market Countries.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (Spring): 264–323.
Blanchard, O. J., F. Jaumotte, and P. Loungani. 2013. “Labor Market Policies and IMF Advice in Advanced Economies during the Great Recession.” IMF Staff Discussion Note 13/02, International Monetary Fund, Washington.
Blanchard, O. J., D. Romer, J. Stiglitz, and M. Spence. 2012. In the Wake of the Crisis: Leading Economists Reassess Economic Policy. Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press.
Blinder, A. S. 2013. After the Music Stopped: The Financial Crisis, the Response, and the Work Ahead. New York: Penguin Press.
Blinder, A. S., and J. B. Rudd. 2012. “The Supply-Shock Explanation of the Great Stagflation Revisited,” in The Great Inflation: The Rebirth of Modern Central Banking. Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Bloom, N. 2009. “The Impact of Uncertainty Shocks.” Econometrica 77 (3): 623–85.
———. 2013. “Fluctuations in Uncertainty.” NBER Working Paper 19714, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Massachusetts.
Bloom, N., M. A. Kose, and M. E. Terrones. 2013. “Held Back by Uncertainty.” Finance & Development 50 (1): 38–41.
Bloom, N., M. Floetotto, N. Jaimovich, I. Saporta-Eksten, and S. Terry. 2012. “Really Uncertain Business Cycles.” NBER Working Paper, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Massachusetts.
Bloomberg News. 2012. “Draghi Says ECB Will Do What’s Needed to Preserve Euro,” July 26.
Bluedorn, J. C., J. Decressin, and M. E. Terrones. 2013. “Do Asset Price Drops Foreshadow Recessions?” IMF Working Paper 13/203, International Monetary Fund, Washington.
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. 2008. Press Release, December 16.
———. 2013. Press Release, December 18.
———. 2014. “Monetary Policy Report,” February 11.
Bordo, M. D. 2012a. “Financial Recessions Don’t Lead to Weak Recoveries.” Wall Street Journal, September 27.
Bordo, M. D. 2012b. “The Great Depression and the Great Recession: What Have we Learnt?” Fourth P.R. Brahmananda Memorial Lecture in Mumbai. Reserve Bank of India.
Bordo, M. D., and J. G. Haubrich. 2012. “Deep Recessions, Fast Recoveries, and Financial Crises: Evidence from the American Record.” Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland Working Paper 12/14.
Bordo, M., and T. Helbling. 2004. “Have National Business Cycles Become More Synchronized?” in Macroeconomic Policies in the World Economy, edited by H. Siebert. Berlin: Springer.
Boskin, M. J. 2009. “Global Disaster Recovery.” Project Syndicate, March 23.
Bosworth, B., and S. Collins, 2010. “Rebalancing the U.S. Economy in a Post-Crisis World.” Paper presented at the Trans-Pacific Rebalancing Conference organized by the Asian Development Bank Institute and the Brookings Institution, March 3–4, Tokyo.
Bosworth, B., and A. Flaaen. 2009. “America’s Financial Crisis: The End of an Era.” Paper presented at Global Financial and Economic Crisis: Impacts, Lessons, and Growth Rebalancing Conference, April 22–23, Tokyo.
Bown, C. P., ed. 2011, The Great Recession and Import Protection: The Role of Temporary Trade Barriers. London: Centre for Economic Policy Research and World Bank.
Broda, C., and C. Tille. 2003. “Coping with Terms-of-Trade Shocks in Developing Countries.” Current Issues in Economics and Finance, Federal Reserve Bank of New York (November).
Bronfenbrenner, M. 1969. Is the Business Cycle Obsolete? New York: Wiley.
Brunnermeier, M. K. 2009. “Deciphering the 2007–08 Liquidity and Credit Crunch.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 23 (1): 77–100.
———, and Y. Sannikov. 2012. “A Macroeconomic Model with a Financial Sector.” 2012 Meeting Papers 507, Society for Economic Dynamics.
Bry, G., and C. Boschan. 1971. Cyclical Analysis of Time Series: Selected Procedures and Computer Programs. Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Buiter, W. H., G. M. Corsetti, and P. A. Pesenti. 1998. “Interpreting the ERM Crisis: Country-Specific and Systemic Issues.” Princeton Studies in International Finance 84.
Buiter, W. H., E. Rahbari, and J. Seydl. 2014. “Secular Stagnation: Only If We Really Ask for It.” Global Economic View, Citi Research, January 13.
Buiter, W. 2015. “Is China Leading the World into Recession?” Global Economic View, Citi Research, September 8.
Burns, A. F., ed. 1952. Wesley Clair Mitchell: The Economic Scientist. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Burns, A. F., and W. C. Mitchell. 1947. Measuring Business Cycles. Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Burstein, A., C. Kurz, and L. Tesar. 2008. “Trade, Production Sharing, and the International Transmission of Business Cycles.” Journal of Monetary Economics 55 (4): 775–95.
Businessweek. 2000. “The New Economy,” January 30.
Bussière, M., E. Perez-Barreiro, R. Straub, and D. Taglioni. 2010. “Protectionist Responses to the Crisis: Global Trends and Implications.” ECB Working Paper 110, European Central Bank, Frankfurt.
Bussière, M., G. Callegari, F. Ghironi, G. Sestieri, and N. Yamano. 2013. “Estimating Trade Elasticities: Demand Composition and the Trade Collapse of 2008–09.” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 5 (3): 118–51.
Byrne, D. M., S. D. Oliner, and D. E. Sichel. 2013. “Is the Information Technology Revolution Over?” Federal Reserve Board Finance and Economics Discussion Series.
Caballero, R. J. 2010. “Macroeconomics after the Crisis: Time to Deal with the Pretense-of-Knowledge Syndrome.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 24 (4): 85–102.
Callen, T. 2007. “PPP versus the Market: Which Weight Matters?” Finance and Development 44: 50–51.
———. 2008. “Gross Domestic Product: An Economy’s All.” Finance and Development 45 (March): 48–49.
Calomiris, C. W. 2009. “The Subprime Turmoil: What’s Old, What’s New, and What’s Next.” Journal of Structured Finance 15 (1): 6–52.
Calomiris, C. W., and S. H. Haber. 2014. Fragile by Design: The Political Origins of Banking Crises and Scarce Credit. Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press.
Calvo, G., and R. Loo-Kung. 2010. “US Recovery: A New ‘Phoenix Miracle’?” VoxEu.
Calvo, G. A., C. Reinhart, E. Fernández-Arias, and E. Talvi. 2001. “Growth and External Financing in Latin America,” Working Paper 4277, Inter-American Development Bank, Washington.
Canova, F. 1998. “Detrending and Business Cycle Facts.” Journal of Monetary Economics 41 (3): 475–512.
———. 2005. “The Transmission of US Shocks to Latin America.” Journal of Applied Econometrics 20 (2): 229–51.
———, M. Ciccarelli, and E. Ortega. 2007. “Similarities and Convergence in G-7 Cycles.” Journal of Monetary Economics 54 (3): 850–78.
Cardarelli, R., S. Elekdag, and M. A. Kose. 2010. “Capital Inflows: Macroeconomic Implications and Policy Responses.” Economic Systems 34: 333–56.
Carlson, M. 2006. “A Brief History of the 1987 Stock Market Crash.” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve Working Paper.
Carrell, P. 2011. “ECB Says Will ‘Actively Implement’ Bond-buying,” August 7, Reuters.
Carrière-Swallow, Y., and L. F. Céspedes. 2013. “The Impact of Uncertainty Shocks in Emerging Economies.” Journal of International Economics 90 (2): 316–25.
Carroll, C. D., M. Otsuka, and J. Slacalek. 2006. “How Large Is the Housing Wealth Effect? A New Approach.” Economics Working Paper Archive Vol. 535, Johns Hopkins University Department of Economics, Baltimore, Maryland.
Caruana, J. 2013. “Hitting the Limits of ‘Outside the Box’ Thinking? Monetary Policy” in The Crisis and Beyond, Official Monetary and Financial Institutions Forum lecture. London.
Carvalho C., S. Eusipe, and C. Grisse. 2012. “Policy Initiatives in the Global Recession: What Did Forecasters Expect?” Current Issues in Economics and Finance. New York: Federal Reserve Bank.
Case, K., J. Quigley, and R. Shiller. 2013. “Wealth Effects Revisited: 1975–2012,” NBER Working Paper 18667, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Massachusetts.
Cassidy, K. 2014. “Is Larry Summers Right about ‘Secular Stagnation’?” New Yorker, January 8.
Castle, S. 2012. “O.E.C.D., Slashing Growth Outlook, Warns of Global Recession,” New York Times, November 27.
Cecchetti, S. G. 2006. “Measuring the Macroeconomic Risks Posed by Asset Price Booms.” NBER Working Paper 12542, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Massachusetts.
———. 2009. “Crisis and Responses: The Federal Reserve in the Early Stages of the Financial Crisis.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 23 (1): 51–75.
Cecchetti, S. G., M. Kohler, and C. Upper. 2009. “Financial Crises and Economic Activity.” Proceedings—Economic Policy Symposium—Jackson Hole, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, 89–135.
Centre for Economic Policy Research (CEPR). 2003. “Business-Cycle Dating Committee Report,” London.
———. 2009. “Euro Area Business Cycle Dating Committee: Determination of the 2008 Q1 Peak in Economic Activity,” London.
———. 2010. Euro Area Business Cycle Dating Committee: Determination of the 2009 Q2 Trough in Economic Activity,” London.
———. 2012. Euro Area Business Cycle Dating Committee: Euro Area Business Cycle Peaked in Third Quarter of 2011, Has Been in Recession Since,” London.
———. 2014. Euro Area Business Cycle Dating Committee: Euro Area Mired in Recession Pause,” London.
Cesa-Bianchi, A., M. H. Pesaran, and A. Rebucci. 2014. “Uncertainty and Economic Activity: A Global Perspective” Unpublished Working Paper.
Chandra, S. 2009. “U.S. Factories Contracted at Fastest Pace since 1980 (Update2),” Bloomberg, January 2.
Chari, A., and P. B. Henry. 2013. “Two Tales of Adjustment: East Asian Lessons for European Growth.” Paper Presented at the 14th Jacques Polak Annual Research Conference, November 7–8, Washington.
Chen, H., V. Cúrdia, and A. Ferrero. 2012. “The Macroeconomic Effects of Large-Scale Asset Purchase Programs.” The Economic Journal 122 (564): 289–315.
Chinn, M. D. 2011. “Regulatory Uncertainty, Macro Policy Uncertainty, and Demand.” Econbrowser.com, December 22.
———. 2013. “Global Supply Chains and Macroeconomic Relationships in Asia.” Unpublished, University of Wisconsin.
———. 2014. “Fiscal Multipliers.” The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, forthcoming.
Chor, D., and K. Manova. 2012. “Off the Cliff and Back? Credit Conditions and International Trade during the Global Financial Crisis.” Journal of International Economics 87: 117–33.
Christiano, L., M. Eichenbaum, and S. Rebelo. 2011. “When Is the Government Spending Multiplier Large?” Journal of Political Economy 119: 78–121.
Christiano, L., M. Eichenbaum, and M. Trabandt. 2014. “Understanding the Great Recession,” NBER Working Paper, No. 20040.
Chui, M., P. Levine, S. M. Murshed, and J. Pearlman. 2002. “North-South Models of Growth and Trade.” Journal of Economic Surveys 16: 123–43.
Cimilluca, D., A. Macdonald, and S. S. Munoz. 2008. “Lloyds TSB to Acquire HBOS as U.K. Seeks Bank Stability.” Wall Street Journal, September 18.
Claessens, S., and K. Forbes. 2001. “International Financial Contagion: An Overview of the Issues and the Book,” in International Financial Contagion, edited by S. Claessens and K. Forbes. Boston: Kluwer Academic Press.
Claessens, S., and M. A. Kose. 2009. “What Is a Recession?” Finance and Development 46 (1): 52–53.
———. 2014a. “Asset Prices and Macroeconomic Outcomes.” Forthcoming IMF Working Paper, International Monetary Fund, Washington.
———. 2014b. “Macroeconomic Implications of Financial Imperfections.” Forthcoming IMF Working Paper, International Monetary Fund Washington.
———. 2014c. “Financial Crises: Explanations, Types and Implications,” in Financial Crises: Causes, Consequences, and Policy Responses, edited by S. Claessens, M. A. Kose, L. Laeven, and F. Valencia. Washington: International Monetary Fund.
Claessens, S., M. A. Kose, and M. E. Terrones. 2008a. “When Crises Collide.” Finance and Development 45 (4).
———. 2008b. “Global Financial Crisis: How Long? How Deep?” VoxEU, October 7.
———.2009. “What Happens during Recessions, Crunches, and Busts?” Economic Policy 60: 653–700.
———. 2010. “The Global Financial Crisis: How Similar? How Different? How Costly?” Journal of Asian Economics 21 (3): 247–64.
———. 2011a. “Financial Cycles: What? How? When?” in NBER International Seminar on Macroeconomics (ISOM) 2010, edited by R. Clarida and F. Giavazzi. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 303–43.
———. 2011b. “Gyrations in Financial Markets.” Finance and Development 48 (1).
———. 2012. “How Do Business and Financial Cycles Interact?” Journal of International Economics 87 (1): 178–90.
Claessens, S., M. A. Kose, L. Laeven, and F. Valencia, eds. 2014. Financial Crises: Causes, Consequences, and Policy Responses. Washington: International Monetary Fund.
Cleveland, H., and B. Brittain. 1975. “A World Depression?” Foreign Affairs 53 (2): 223–41.
CNN. 2009. “G-20 Pumps $1 Trillion into Beating Recession,” April 2.
Cochrane, J. H., ed. 2006. “Financial Markets and the Real Economy,” in International Library of Critical Writings in Financial Economics (18): 11–19.
———. 2009a. “How Did Paul Krugman Get It So Wrong?” Unpublished.
———. 2009b. “Fiscal Stimulus, Fiscal Inflation, or Fiscal Fallacies?” University of Chicago, Booth School of Business.
———. 2012. “Austerity, Stimulus, or Growth Now?” The Grumpy Economist, March 21.
———. 2014. “An Autopsy for the Keynesians,” Wall Street Journal, December 26.
Coenen, G., C. J. Erceg, C. Freedman, D. Furceri, M. Kumhof, R. Lalonde, D. Laxton, J. Lindé, A. Mourougane, D. Muir, S. Mursula, C. de Resende, J. Roberts, W. Roeger, S. Snudden, M. Trabandt, and J. Veld. 2012. “Effects of Fiscal Stimulus in Structural Models.” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 4: 1–47.
Cogan, J. F., and J. B. Taylor. 2012. “What the Government Purchases Multiplier Actually Multiplied in the 2009 Stimulus Package,” in Government Policies and the Delayed Economic Recovery, edited by L. E. Ohanian, J. B. Taylor, and I. J. Wright. Stanford, California: Stanford University.
Cotis, J., and J. Coppel. 2005. “Business Cycle Dynamics in OECD Countries: Evidence, Causes and Policy Implications.” RBA Annual Conference Volume, in The Changing Nature of the Business Cycle, edited by C. C. Kent and D. D. Norman. Sydney: Reserve Bank of Australia.
Council of Economic Advisers. 2009. “Housing and Financial Markets.” Chapter 2, Economic Report to the President.
———. 2010. “Crisis and Recovery in the World Economy.” Chapter 3, Economic Report to the President.
———. 2012. “To Recover, Rebalance, and Rebuild.” Chapter 1, Economic Report to the President.
———. 2014a. “The Economic Impact of the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act Five Years Later.” Final Report to Congress.
———. 2014b. “The Fifth Anniversary of the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act.”
Coyle, D. 2014. GDP: A Brief but Affectionate History. Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press.
Currie, D., and D. Vines. 1988. Macroeconomic Interactions between North and South. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Curry, T., and L. Shibut. 2000. “The Cost of the Savings and Loan Crisis: Truth and Consequences.” FDIC Banking Review 13 (2): 26–35.
Daly, M. C., J. Fernald, O. Jorda, and F. Nechid. 2013. “Labor Markets in the Global Financial Crisis.” FRBSF Economic Letter 38.
D’Amico, S., W. English, D. Lopez-Salido, and E. Nelson. 2012. “The Federal Reserve’s Large-Scale Asset Purchase Programs: Rationale and Effects.” Finance and Discussion Series Paper 2012-85, Federal Reserve Board, Washington.
Dao, M., and P. Loungani. 2010. “The Human Cost of Recessions: Assessing It, Reducing It.” IMF Staff Position Note 10/17, International Monetary Fund, Washington.
Davies, G. 2011. “Monitoring the Risk of Global Recession.” Financial Times, September 5.
———. 2014. “Global Policy Mix Turns More Growth Friendly,” Financial Times, November 24.
Davies, P. 2012. “Asian Crisis: 10 Lessons for Europe.” Financial Times, June 8.
Davis, S. J. 2013. “Straw Man Bites the Dust: A Response to Paul Krugman on Policy Uncertainty.” Capital Ideas (website), University of Chicago, Booth School of Business.
Davis, S. J., and J. A. Kahn. 2008. “Interpreting the Great Moderation: Changes in the Volatility of Economic Activity at the Macro and Micro Levels.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 22 (4): 155–80.
De Gregorio, J. 2014. How Latin America Weathered the Global Financial Crisis. Washington: Peterson Institute for International Economics.
de Haan, J., R. Inklaar, and R. Jong-A-Pin. 2008. “Will Business Cycles in the Euro Area Converge? A Critical Survey of Empirical Research.” Journal of Economic Surveys 22 (2): 234–73.
DeLong, J. B. 2011a. “The Little Depression.” Blog, June 10.
———, J. B. 2011b. “The Anatomy of Slow Recovery.” Project Syndicate, March 31.
DeLong, and L. H. Summers. 2012. “Fiscal Policy in a Depressed Economy.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (March).
Dées, S., and N. Zorell. 2012. “Business Cycle Synchronization: Disentangling Trade and Financial Linkages.” Open Economies Review 23 (4): 623–43.
Department of the Treasury. 1992. “International Economic and Exchange Rate Policy.” Report to the U.S. Congress, May 12.
Dervis, K. 2012. “Convergence, Interdependence, and Divergence.” Finance and Development 49 (3).
———. 2013. “Catching up at Different Speeds.” Brookings Institution, December 17.
———. 2014. “Tailspin or Turbulence?” Brookings Institution, February 18.
Desai, S., and M. Jones. 2008. “Northern Rock Nationalised.” Reuters, February 17.
di Giovanni, J., and A. A. Levchenko. 2010. “Putting the Parts Together: Trade, Vertical Linkages, and Business Cycle Comovement.” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics Vol. 2: 95–124.
Diebold, F. X., and K. Yilmaz. 2009. “Measuring Financial Asset Return and Volatility Spillovers with Application to Global Equity Markets.” The Economic Journal 119 (534): 158–71.
———. 2014. “Measuring the Dynamics of Global Business Cycle Connectedness,” in Unobserved Components and Time Series Econometrics: Essays in Honor of Andrew C. Harvey, edited by S. J. Koopman and N. Shephard. Oxford: Oxford University Press, forthcoming.
Dixit, A. K., and R. S. Pindyck. 1994. Investment under Uncertainty. Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press.
Dornbusch, R. 1985. “Policy and Performance Links between LDC Debtors and Industrial Nations.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2: 303–56.
Dornbusch, R., T. Johnson, and A. Krueger. 1988. “Our LDC Debts,” in The United States in the World Economy, edited by Martin Feldstein. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Draghi, M. 2012 Speech at the Global Investment Conference in London, July 26.
Dua, P., and A. Banerji. 2010. “Synchronization of Recessions in Major Developed and Emerging Economies.” Journal of Applied Economic Research 4 (2): 197–223.
Dudley, W. C. 2014 “U.S. Monetary Policy and Emerging Market Economies.” Speech, March 27.
Du Plesis, S., and B. Smit. 2004. “Reconsidering the Business Cycle and Stabilization Policies in South Africa.” Paper presented at the Ninth Annual Conference on Econometric Modelling for Africa, June 30–July 2.
Durdu, C. B., and S. Sayan. 2010. “Emerging Market Business Cycles with Remittance Fluctuations.” IMF Staff Papers 57 (2): 303–25.
Durdu, C. B., E. G. Mendoza, and M. E. Terrones. 2009. “Precautionary Demand for Foreign Assets in Sudden Stop Economies: An Assessment of the New Mercantilism.” Journal of Development Economics 89 (2): 194–209.
Eckstein, O., and A. Sinai. 1986. “The Mechanisms of the Business Cycle in the Postwar Era,” in The American Business Cycle: Continuity and Change, edited by R. Gordon. Chicago: University of Chicago Press for National Bureau of Economic Research.
The Economist. 1971. “When the Dollar Was Devalued.” August 21.
———. 1973. “What’s the German for Stagflation?” November 10.
———. 1974a. “When the Balloon Goes Up.” December 21.
———. 1974b. “Who will survive the slump?” December 28.
———. 1974c. “A Cold, Dark, Three-Day Week.” January 5.
———. 1974d. “Oil Unblocked.” March 23, 50.
———. 1975a. “Beware the Coming Boom.” April 12.
———. 1975b. “A World of Slow Growth.” July 26.
———. 1975c. “Summit in a Slump.” November 15.
———. 1978a. “Iran’s Oil Strike: Time for a Little Studied Western Calm.” November 4.
———. 1978b. “Where Is the Oil to Replace Iran’s?” November 11.
———. 1979a. “Hello Freedom, If That’s What You Are.” January 20.
———. 1979b. “What to do about Oil Prices?” May 26.
———. 1979c. “Dollar Surgery.” October 13.
———. 1980a. “The Price of War.” November 15.
———. 1980b. “Face the Worst.” July 12.
———. 1981a. “1931 and 1981.” September 5.
———. 1981b. “Summer Slump and Less Inflation Won’t Bring Easier Money.” July 11.
———. 1982a. “Recyclers’ Recession.” August 7.
———. 1982b. “Recession as Usual.” August 21.
———. 1983. “Helmut Schmidt’s Prescription: The World Economy at Stake,” February 26.
———. 1989. “The Business Cycle Gets a Puncture.” August 5.
———. 1990. “All Fall Down.” September 22.
———. 1991. “Economics Focus—After the Recession.” March 16.
———. 1992a. “What Recession?” June 20.
———. 1992b. “Recession or Doom?” October 24.
———. 1998. “Puncture Ahead.” December 3.
———. 1999. “Depressing Jargon.” January 21.
———. 2001a. “A Global Game of Dominoes.” August 23.
———. 2001b. “Going Downhill.” September 27.
———. 2002. “After the Bubbles: Brace Yourself for a Bumpier Time Ahead.” September 26.
———. 2008a. “The Global Slumpometer.” November 6.
———. 2008b. “Diagnosing Depression.” December 30.
———. 2010. “The Volcker Recession: Who Beat Inflation?” March 31.
———. 2014. “Why Is Stagnation Bubbly?” January 6.
———. 2015. “Watch Out” June 13.
Edwards, S. 1995. Crisis and Reform in Latin America:From Despair to Hope. New York: Oxford University Press for World Bank.
Eggertsson, G., and N. Mehrotra. 2014. “A Model of Secular Stagnation.” Brown University Working Paper.
Eggertsson, G., and M. Woodford. 2003. “The Zero Bound on Interest Rates and Optimal Monetary Policy.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (Spring): 139–211.
Eichengreen, B. 1996. Golden Fetters. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
———. 2015. Hall of Mirrors: The Great Depression, The Great Recession, and the Uses-and Misuses-of History, Oxford University Press.
Eichengreen, B., and K. H. O’Rourke. 2009. “A Tale of Two Depressions.” VoxEU, September 1.
Eicher, T. S., S. F. Schubert, and S. J. Turnovsky. 2008. “Dynamic Effects of Terms of Trade Shocks: The Impact on Debt and Growth.” Journal of International Money and Finance 27 (6): 876–96.
El-Erian, M. A. 2009. “A New Normal.” Economic Outlook (May), pimco.com.
———. 2011. “Secular Outlook: Navigating the Multi-Speed World.” Economic Outlook (May), pimco.com.
———. 2015. “The Messy Politics of Economic Divergence,” Project Syndicate, March.
Elsby, M. W. L., B. Hobijn, and A. Sahin. 2010. “The Labor Market in the Great Recession.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 41: 1–69.
———, and R. G. Valletta. 2011. “The Labor Market in the Great Recession—An Update to September 2011.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (Fall): 353–84.
English, W. B., J. D. Lopez-Salido, and R. J. Tetlow. 2013. “The Federal Reserve’s Framework for Monetary Policy––Recent Changes and New Questions.” Paper Presented at the 14th Jacques Polak Annual Research Conference, November 7–8, Washington.
European Central Bank. 1998. “Euro Central Rates and Intervention Rates in ERM II.” Press release, December 31.
Faber, M. 2012. “Marc Faber: 100% Chance of Global Recession.” CNBC Interview by Lee Brodie, May 25.
Faruqee, H., and K. Srinivasan. 2012. “The G-20 Mutual Assessment Process—A Perspective from IMF Staff.” Oxford Review of Economic Policy 28 (3): 493–511.
Fatas, A., and I. Mihov. 2013. “Recoveries.” INSEAD Working Paper.
Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC). 1997. “The LDC Debt Crisis,” Chapter 5 in History of Eighties—Lessons for the Future, Vol. 1: An Examination of the Banking Crises of the 1980s and Early 1990s.
Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City. 2002. Rethinking Stabilization Policy. Symposium Publication, Jackson Hole, Wyoming.
Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC). 2008. “Minutes of the Federal Open Market Committee.” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, April 29–30.
———. 2009. “Minutes of the Federal Open Market Committee,” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, June 23–24.
———. 2010. “Minutes of the Federal Open Market Committee,” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, September 21.
———. 2013. “Minutes of the Federal Open Market Committee,” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, December 17-18. Feldstein, M. 2010 “Why Has America’s Economic Recovery Stalled?” Project Syndicate, October 25.
———. 2013. “The Taper Chase.” Project Syndicate, September 30.
Ferguson, R. W. 2005 “Recessions and Recoveries Associated with Asset-Price Movements: What Do We Know?” Speech given at the Stanford Institute for Economic Policy Research, Stanford, California.
Fernald, J. 2014. “Productivity and Potential Output Before, During, and After the Great Recession,” NBER Working Paper, No. 20248.
Fidrmuc, J., and I. Korhonen. 2010. “The Impact of the Global Financial Crisis on Business Cycles in Asian Emerging Economies.” Journal of Asian Economics 21 (3): 293–303.
Fisher, I. 1933. “The Debt-Deflation Theory of Great Depressions.” Econometrica 1: 337–57.
Fischer, S. 1998. “Lessons from a Crisis.” Economist, October 3.
———. 2014. “The Great Recession: Moving Ahead,” August 11, speech at a conference sponsored by the Swedish Ministry of Finance, Stockholm, Sweden.
———. 2015. “Conducting Monetary Policy with a Large Balance Sheet,” speech given on February 27.
———, R. Sahay, and C. Végh. 1996. “Stabilization and Growth in Transition Economies: The Early Experience.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 10 (2): 45–66.
Forbes, K. 2013. “The ‘Big C’: Identifying and Mitigating Contagion.” The Changing Policy Landscape 2012. Jackson Hole Symposium hosted by the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, 23–87.
———, and R. Rigobon. 2002. “No Contagion, Only Interdependence: Measuring Stock Market Comovements.” Journal of Finance 152: 2223–61.
Forbes, K. J., and F. E. Warnock. 2012. “Capital Flows Waves: Surges, Stops, Flight, and Retrenchment.” Journal of International Economics 88 (2): 235–51.
Foster, L., C. Grim, and J. Haltiwanger,. 2014. “Reallocation in the Great Recession: Cleansing or Not?” NBER Working Paper, No. 20427.
Frankel, J. 2011. “Are Bilateral Remittances Countercyclical?” Open Economies Review 22 (1): 1–16.
———. 2013. “Monetary Alchemy, Fiscal Science.” Project Syndicate, January 26.
———, and A. Rose. 1998. “The Endogeneity of the Optimum Currency Area Criteria.” Economic Journal 108 (149): 1009–25.
Frankel, J. A., and N. Roubini. 2001. “The Role of Industrial Country Policies in Emerging Market Crises.” NBER Working Paper 8634, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Massachusetts.
Freedman, C., M. Kumhof, D. Laxton, and J. Lee. 2009. “The Case for Global Fiscal Stimulus.” IMF Staff Position Paper 09/04, International Monetary Fund, Washington.
Freund, C. 2009. “The Trade Response to Global Downturns: Historical Evidence.” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 5015, World Bank, Washington.
Friedman, M. 1964. “The Monetary Studies of the National Bureau.” The National Bureau Enters Its 45th Year, 44th Annual Report, 7–25.
———. 1993. “The ‘Plucking Model’ of Business Fluctuations Revisited.” Economic Inquiry 31 (2): 171–78.
Fuerbringer, J. 1991. “Why a U.S. Recession Still Matters.” New York Times, January 6.
Furceri, D., and A. Zdzienicka. 2012. “How Costly Are Debt Crises?” Journal of International Money and Finance 31 (4): 726–42.
Furman, J. 2014. “The Fifth Anniversary of the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act.” Council of Economic Advisers, February 17.
Gagnon, J., M. Raskin, J. Remache, and B. Sack. 2011. “Large-Scale Asset Purchases by the Federal Reserve: Did They Work?” FRBNY Economic Policy Review (May): 41–59.
Gagnon, J., and B. Sack. 2014. “Monetary Policy with Abundant Liquidity: A New Operating Framework for the Federal Reserve.” Policy Brief, Peterson Institute for International Economics, Washington.
Garcia, R., and H. Schaller. 2002. “Are the Effects of Monetary Policy Asymmetric?” Economic Inquiry 40 (1): 102–19.
Geithner, T. F. 2014. Stress Test: Reflections on Financial Crises. New York: Crown.
Gerlach, H. M. S. 1988. “World Business Cycles under Fixed and Flexible Exchange Rates” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 20 (4): 621–32.
Gertler, M. 1988. “Financial Structure and Aggregate Economic Activity: An Overview.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 20 (3): 559–88.
———, and N. Kiyotaki. 2010. “Financial Intermediation and Credit Policy in Business Cycle Analysis,” in Handbook of Monetary Economics, edited by B. Friedman and M. Woodford. Amsterdam: Elsevier.
Giannone, D., M. Lenza, and L. Reichlin. 2011. “Market Freedom and the Global Recession.” IMF Economic Review 59: 111–35.
Gilchrist, S., J. Sim, and E. Zakrajsek. 2010. “Uncertainty, Financial Frictions, and Investment Dynamics.” 2010 Meeting Papers 1285, Society for Economic Dynamics.
Giuliano, P., and A. Spilimbergo. 2009. “Growing Up in a Recession: Beliefs and the Macroeconomy.” NBER Working Paper 15321, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Massachusetts.
Golden, S. 1975. “Is It a Depression—Or Just a Bad Recession.” New York Times, March 9.
Goldstein, M. 2008. “Bear Stearns’ Big Bailout.” Bloomberg Businessweek, March 14.
Goldstein, M., and M. S. Khan. 1982. Effects of Slowdown in Industrial Countries on Growth in Non-oil Developing Countries. Washington: International Monetary Fund.
Gomes, S., P. Jacquinot, R. Mestre, and J. Sousa, 2015. “Global Policy at the Zero Lower Bound In a Large-scale DSGE Model,” Journal of International Money and Finance 50: 134–53.
Goodfriend, M., and R. G. King. 2005. “The Incredible Volcker Disinflation.” Journal of Monetary Economics 52 (5): 981–1015.
Goodley, S. 2012. “How Black Monday Sowed the Seeds for the Current Financial Crisis.” Guardian, October 13.
Goodman, P. S. 2008. “U.S. and Global Economies Slipping in Unison.” New York Times, August 23.
Gordon, R. A. 1970. “How Obsolete Is the Business Cycle?” National Affairs 21: 127–39.
Gordon, R. J. 2009. “Is Modern Macro or 1978-era Macro More Relevant to the Understanding of the Current Economic Crisis?” Working Paper, Northwestern University.
———. 2012. “Is U.S. Economic Growth Over? Faltering Innovation Confronts the Six Headwinds.” NBER Working Paper 18315, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Massachusetts.
———. 2014. “The Demise of U.S. Economic Growth: Restatement, Rebuttal, and Reflections.” NBER Working Paper 19895, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Massachusetts.
Gorton, G. 2012. Misunderstanding Financial Crises: Why We Don’t See Them Coming. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Gourinchas, P. 2012. “Global Imbalances and Global Liquidity,” in Asia’s Role in the Post Crisis Global Economy, edited by M. Spiegel and R. Glick, 305–40.
———, and M. A. Kose. 2010. “Economic Linkages, Spillovers, and the Financial Crisis-1.” IMF Economic Review 58: 209–13.
———. 2011. “Economic Linkages, Spillovers, and the Financial Crisis-2.” IMF Economic Review 59: 1–5.
———. 2013a. “Labor Markets through the Lens of the Great Recession—1.” IMF Economic Review 61 (3): 405–9.
———. 2013b. “Labor Markets through the Lens of the Great Recession—2.” IMF Economic Review 61 (4): 561–65.
Gourinchas P., and M. A. Kose, 2014. “Crises: Yesterday and Today—1,” IMF Economic Review 62(4): 465-469.
———. 2015. “Crises: Yesterday and Today—2,” IMF Economic Review 63(1):1–5.
Gourinchas, P., and M. Obstfeld. 2012. “Stories of the Twentieth Century for the Twenty-First.” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 4 (1): 226–65.
Gourinchas, P., and H. Rey. 2014. “External Adjustment, Global Imbalances, Valuation Effects.” forthcoming in Handbook of International Economics.
Greenspan, A. 2013. “Uncertainty Unbundled: The Metrics of Activism,” in Government Policies and the Delayed Economic Recovery, edited by L. E. Ohanian, J. B. Taylor, and I. J. Wright. Stanford, California: Hoover Institution Press.
Gregory, A. W., and A. C. Head. 1999. “Common and Country-Specific Fluctuations in Productivity, Investment, and the Current Account.” Journal of Monetary Economics 44 (3): 423–51.
Gregory, A. W., and J. Raynauld. 1997. “Measuring World Business Cycles.” International Economic Review 38 (3): 677–701.
Gross, W. H. 2009 “On the ‘Course’ to a New Normal.” Investment Outlook (September), pimco.com.
Guajardo, J., D. Leigh, and A. Pescatori. 2011. “Expansionary Austerity: New International Evidence.” IMF Working Paper 11/158, International Monetary Fund, Washington.
Guardian. 1973. “OPEC Oil Embargo Leads to Global Fuel Crisis,” November 13.
Hall, R. E. 1993. “Macro Theory and the Recession of 1990–1991.” American Economic Review 83 (2): 275–79.
Hall, V., and J. McDermott. 2007. “Regional Business Cycles in New Zealand: Do They Exist? What Might Drive Them?” Papers in Regional Science 86 (2): 167–91.
Haltmaier, J. 2012 “Do Recessions Affect Potential Output?” International Finance Discussion Papers 1066, Federal Reserve Board.
Hamilton, J. D. 1989. “A New Approach to the Economic Analysis of Nonstationary Time Series and the Business Cycle.” Econometrica 57 (2): 357–84.
———. 2003. “Comment on ‘A Comparison of Two Business Cycle Dating Methods.’” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 27 (9): 1691–93.
———. 2009a. “Oil Prices and the Economic Recession of 2007–08.” VoxEU, June 16.
———. 2009b. “Causes and Consequences of the Oil Shock of 2007–08,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 40: 215–83.
———. 2011. “Historical Oil Shocks.” Unpublished, University of California, San Diego.
———, E. S. Harris, J. Hatzius, and K. D. West. 2015. “The Equilibrium Real Funds Rate: Past, Present and Future,” University of Chicago, Working Paper.
Hansen, A. 1939. “Economic Progress and Declining Population Growth.”American Economic Review 29 (1): 1–15.
Hansen, G. D., and E. C. Prescott. 1993. “Did Technology Shocks Cause the 1990–1991 Recession?” American Economic Review 83 (2): 280–86.
Harding, D., and A. Pagan. 2002. “Dissecting the Cycle: A Methodological Investigation.” Journal of Monetary Economics 49: 365–81.
Harding, R. 2014. “Yellen Says Emerging Market Turmoil Will Not Sway the Fed.” Financial Times, February 11.
Hassett, K., and G. Hubbard. 2012. “Obama Inconsistent on Pace of Economic Recovery.” Washington Post, August, 15.
He, D., and W. Liao. 2012. “Asian Business Cycle Synchronization.” Pacific Economic Review 17 (1): 105–35.
Helbling, T. 2009. “How Similar Is the Current Crisis to the Great Depression?” VoxEU, April 29.
Helbling, T., P. Berezin, M. A. Kose, M. Kumhof, D. Laxton, and N.Spatafora. 2007. “Decoupling the Train? Spillovers and Cycles in the Global Economy,” in World Economic Outlook. Washington: International Monetary Fund, April: 121–60.
Helbling, T., and M. E. Terrones. 2004. “Asset Price Booms and Busts—Stylized Facts from the Last Three Decades of the 20th Century.” Unpublished, International Monetary Fund, Washington.
Helbling, T., R. Huidrom, M. A. Kose, and C. Otrok. 2011. “Do Credit Shocks Matter? A Global Perspective.” European Economic Review 55: 340–53.
Henn, C., and B. McDonald. 2011. “Protectionist Responses to the Crisis: Damage Observed in Product-Level Trade.” IMF Working Paper 11/139, International Monetary Fund, Washington.
Herndon, T., M. Ash, and R. Pollin. 2013. “Does High Public Debt Consistently Stifle Economic Growth? A Critique of Reinhart and Rogoff.” Working Paper, University of Massachusetts, Amherst.
Higgins, B. 1993. “Was the ERM Crisis Inevitable?” Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Economic Review 78 (4): 27–40.
Hirata, H., M. A. Kose, and C. Otrok. 2013. “Globalization vs. Regionalization,” IMF Working Paper 13/19, International Monetary Fund, Washington.
———, and M. E. Terrones. 2012. “Global House Price Fluctuations: Synchronization and Determinants,” in NBER International Seminar on Macroeconomics 2012.
Hoffmaister, A., M. Pradhan, and H. Samiei. 1998. “Have North-South Growth Linkages Changed?” World Development 26 (5): 791–808.
Hoshi, T., and A. K. Kashyap. 2013. “Will the US and Europe Avoid a Lost Decade? Lessons from Japan’s Post Crisis Experience.” Paper presented at the 14th Jacques Polak Annual Research Conference, November 7–8, Washington.
Howard, G., R. Martin, and B. A. Wilson. 2011. “Are Recoveries from Banking and Financial Crises Really So Different?” International Finance Discussion Paper 1037, Federal Reserve Board, Washington.
Hutchens, G., and P. Martin. 2014. “OECD Warns of New Era of Low Economic Growth Globally.” Sydney Morning Herald, February 22.
Iacoviello, M. 2005. “House Prices, Borrowing Constraints, and Monetary Policy in the Business Cycle.” American Economic Review 95 (3): 739–64.
Imbs, J. 2004. “Trade, Finance, Specialization, and Synchronization.” Review of Economics and Statistics 86 (3): 723–34.
———. 2006. “The Real Effects of Financial Integration.” Journal of International Economics 68 (2): 296–324.
———. 2010. “The First Global Recession in Decades.” IMF Economic Review 58 (2): 327–54.
Independent Evaluation Office of the International Monetary Fund. 2012. “International Reserves: IMF Concerns and Country Perspectives.” Evaluation Report, Washington.
International Labour Organization (ILO). 2013. Global Employment Trends 2013. Geneva.
———. 2014. Global Employment Trends 2014. Geneva.
International Monetary Fund (IMF). 1998a. “Financial Crises: Causes and Indicators.” World Economic Outlook. Washington, May.
———. 1998b. “Financial Turbulence and the World Economy.” World Economic Outlook. Washington, October.
———. 2000. “Transition Economies: An IMF Perspective on Progress and Prospects.” Brief Note 00/08, Washington.
———. 2001a. “Fiscal Policy and Macroeconomic Stability.” World Economic Outlook. Washington, May.
———. 2001b. “The Information Technology Revolution.” World Economic Outlook. Washington, October.
———. 2001c. “The Global Economy after September 11,” World Economic Outlook Update Washington, December.
———. 2001d. “How Do Fluctuations in the G-7 Countries Affect Developing Countries?” World Economic Outlook. Washington, October.
———. 2008. “Housing and Business Cycle.” World Economic Outlook. Washington, April.
———. 2009a. “What’s the Damage? Medium-Term Output Dynamics after Financial Crises.” World Economic Outlook. Washington, October.
———. 2009b. “Executive Summary.” Regional Economic Outlook: Middle East and Central Asia. Washington, May.
———. 2010a. “A Policy-Driven, Multispeed Recovery.” World Economic Outlook Update. Washington, January.
———. 2010b. “Executive Summary.” Regional Economic Outlook: Asia and Pacific. Washington, October.
———. 2010c. “Executive Summary.” Regional Economic Outlook: Western Hemisphere. Washington, May.
———. 2011a. “Global Recovery Advances but Remains Uneven.” World Economic Outlook Update. Washington, January.
———. 2011b. “IMF Welcomes Agreement to Tackle Eurozone Crisis.” IMF Survey online, July 22.
———. 2012a. “Global Recovery Stalls, Downside Risks Intensify.” World Economic Outlook Update. Washington, January.
———. 2012b. “Coping with High Debt and Sluggish Growth.” World Economic Outlook. Washington, October.
———. 2013a. “Gradual Upturn in Global Growth during 2013.” World Economic Outlook Update. Washington, January.
———. 2013b. “Fiscal Monitor: Fiscal Adjustment in an Uncertain World.” World Economic and Financial Surveys. Washington, April.
———. 2013c. “Unconventional Monetary Policies—Recent Experience and Prospects.” Policy Paper, Washington, April.
———. 2013. “Transitions and Tensions,” World Economic Outlook. Washington, October.
———. 2014a. “Is the Tide Rising?” World Economic Outlook Update. Washington, January.
———. 2014b. “Recovery Strengthens, Remains Uneven.” World Economic Outlook. Washington, April.
———. 2014c. “Public Expenditures Reform: Making Difficult Choices.” Fiscal Monitor. Washington, April.
———. 2015a. “Uneven Growth: Short- and Long-Term Factors,” World Economic Outlook, April, Chapter 1, 1–42.
———. 2015b. “Slower Growth in Emerging Markets, a Gradual Pickup in Advanced Economies” World Economic Outlook Update, July 2015.
———. 2015c. “Where are we Headed? Perspectives on Potential Output,” World Economic Outlook, April, Chapter 3, 69–110.
Jansen, W. J., and A. C. J. Stokman. 2004. “Foreign Direct Investment and International Business Cycle Comovement.” ECB Working Paper 401, European Central Bank, Frankfurt.
Jeanne, O. 2007. “International Reserves in Emerging Market Countries: Too Much of a Good Thing?” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 38: 1–80.
———. 2014. “Macroprudential Policies in a Global Perspective.” IMES Discussion Paper 2014-E-1.Journal of Commerce. 1998. “Global Recession?” (September 2): 6A.
Joyce M., A. Lasaosa, I. Stevens, and M. Tong. 2010. “The Financial Market Impact of Quantitative Easing.” Bank of England Working Paper, London.
Kalemli-Ozcan, S., E. Papaioannou, and J. L. Peydró. 2013. “Financial Regulation, Financial Globalization and the Synchronization of Economic Activity.” Journal of Finance 68: 1179–228.
Kamin, S. B., and L. P. DeMarco. 2012. “How Did a Domestic Slump Turn into a Global Financial Crisis?” Journal of International Money and Finance 31: 10–41.
Kaminsky, G. L., C. M. Reinhart, and C. A. Végh. 2005. “When It Rains, It Pours: Procyclical Capital Flows and Macroeconomic Policies,” in NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2004 Vol. 19. Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research, 11–82.
Kanaya, A., and D. Woo. 2000. “The Japanese Banking Crisis of the 1990s: Sources and Lessons.” IMF Working Paper 00/7, International Monetary Fund, Washington.
Kannan, P. 2012. “Credit Conditions and Recoveries from Financial Crises.” Journal of International Money and Finance 31 (5): 930–47.
Karnitschnig, M., D. Solomon, L. Pleven, and J. E. Hilsenrath. 2008. “U.S. to Take over AIG in $85 Billion Bailout; Central Banks Inject Cash as Credit Dries Up.” Wall Street Journal, September 16.
Karras, G. 1996. “Why Are the Effects of Money-Supply Shocks Asymmetric? Convex Aggregate Supply or ‘Pushing on a String’?” Journal of Macroeconomics 18 (4): 605–19.
Katz, L. F., K. Kroft, F. Lange, and M. Notowidigdo. 2014. “Addressing long-term Unemployment in the Aftermath of the Great Recession,” VoxEU, December 3.
Kenen, P. B. 1983. “The Costly Blunders of Central Bankers.” New York Times.
Keynes, J. M. [1936] 1973. “The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money.” The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes, Vol. VII, edited by D. E. Moggridge. London: Macmillan.
Kiley, M. T. 2013. “The Response of Equity Prices to Movements in Long-Term Interest Rates Associated with Monetary Policy Statements: Before and after the Zero Lower Bound.” Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2013–15, Federal Reserve Board, Washington.
Kim, S. 2001. “International Transmission of U.S. Monetary Policy Shocks: Evidence from VAR’s.” Journal of Monetary Economics 48 (2): 339–72.
King, S. D. 2010. Losing Control: The Emerging Threats to Western Prosperity. New Haven, Connecticut: Yale University Press.
Kishor, N. K. 2007. “Does Consumption Respond More to Housing Wealth Than to Financial Market Wealth? If So, Why?” The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics 35 (4): 427–48.
Kiyotaki, N., and J. Moore. 1997. “Credit Cycles.” Journal of Political Economy105: 211–48.
Knoop, T. A. 2004. Recessions and Depressions: Understanding Business Cycles. Westport, Connecticut: Praeger.
Kocherlakota, N. 2010. “Modern Macroeconomic Models as Tools for Economic Policy.” The Region, Banking and Policy Issues Magazine of the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis (May 4): 5–21.
Kollmann, R., W. Roeger, and J. Veld. 2012. “Fiscal Policy in a Financial Crisis: Standard Policy versus Bank Rescue Measures.” American Economic Review 102 (3): 77–81.
Kose, M. A. 2002. “Explaining Business Cycles in Small Open Economies: How Much Do World Prices Matter?” Journal of International Economics 56 (2): 299–327.
Kose, M. A., and E. Prasad. 2010. Emerging Markets: Resilience and Growth Amid Global Turmoil. Washington: Brookings Institution Press.
Kose, M. A. and E. O. Ozturk, 2014. “A World of Change: Taking Stock of the Past Half Century,” Finance and Development, September, 6–11.
———. 2015. “How Has the Global Economy Changed? A Summary of the Past Fifty Years,” Working Paper, World Bank.
Kose, M. A., and A. Rebucci. 2005. “How Might CAFTA Change Macroeconomic Fluctuations in Central America?: Lessons from NAFTA.” Journal of Asian Economics 16 (1): 77–104.
Kose, M. A., and R. Riezman. 2001. “Trade Shocks and Macroeconomic Fluctuations in Africa.” Journal of Development Economics 65 (1): 55–80.
Kose, M. A., and M. E. Terrones. 2012. “How Does Uncertainty Affect Economic Performance?” World Economic Outlook. Washington: International Monetary Fund, October.
———. 2015. “Global Recessions.” Forthcoming IMF Working Paper, International Monetary Fund, Washington.
Kose, M. A., and K. Yi. 2001. “International Trade and Business Cycles: Is Vertical Specialization the Missing Link?” American Economic Review 91 (2): 371–75.
———. 2006. “Can the Standard International Business Cycle Model Explain the Relation between Trade and Comovement?” Journal of International Economics 68 (2): 267–95.
Kose, M. A., P. Loungani, and M. E. Terrones. 2009. “Out of the Ballpark.” Finance & Development 46: 25–28.
———. 2012. “Tracking the Global Recovery.” Finance & Development 49 (2): 10–13.
———. 2013a. “The Great Divergence of Policies.” World Economic Outlook. Washington: International Monetary Fund, April.
———. 2013b. “From the Global to the National Cycle: An Intricate Liaison.” Pacific Economic Review 18 (3): 270–402.
Kose, M. A., G. M. Meredith, and C. M. Towe. 2005. “How Has NAFTA Affected the Mexican Economy? Review and Evidence.” Monetary Policy and Macroeconomic Stabilization in Latin America. Berlin: Springer), 35–81.
Kose, M. A., C. Otrok, and E. Prasad. 2012. “Global Business Cycles: Convergence or Decoupling?” International Economic Review 53: 511–38.
Kose, M. A, C. Otrok, and C. H. Whiteman. 2003. “International Business Cycles: World, Region, and Country Specific Factors.” American Economic Review93:1216–39.
———. 2008. “Understanding the Evolution of World Business Cycles.” Journal of International Economics 75 (1): 110–30.
Kose, M. A., E. Prasad, K. Rogoff, and S. Wei. 2010. “Financial Globalization and Economic Policies.” Handbook of Development Economics 5 (6): 4283–359.
Kose, M. A., E. S. Prasad, and M. E. Terrones. 2003a. “How Does Globalization Affect the Synchronization of Business Cycles?” American Economic Review 93 (2): 57–62.
———. 2003b. “Financial Integration and Macroeconomic Volatility.” IMF Staff Papers 50 (Special Issue): 119–43.
———. 2005. “Growth and Volatility in an Era of Globalization.” IMF Staff Papers 52: 31–63.
———. 2006. “How Do Trade and Financial Integration Affect the Relationship between Growth and Volatility?” Journal of International Economics 69: 176–202.
———. 2009a. “Does Financial Globalization Promote Risk Sharing?” Journal of Development Economics 89 (2): 258–70.
———. 2009b. “Does Openness to International Financial Flows Contribute to Productivity Growth?” Journal of International Money and Finance 28(4): 549–738.
Kowsmann, P. 2011. “Portugal Bailout Plan Detailed” Wall Street Journal, May 5.
Krishnamurthy, A., and A. Vissing-Jorgensen. 2011. “The Effects of Quantitative Easing on Interest Rates: Channels and Implications for Policy.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (Fall): 215–65.
———. 2013. “The Ins and Outs of LSAPs.” Proceedings–Economic Policy Symposium, Jackson Hole, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City.
Krugman, P. 1993. “Lessons from Massachusetts for EMU,” in Adjustment and Growth in the European Monetary Union, edited by F. Torres and F. Giavazzi. London: Centre for Economic Policy Research and Cambridge University Press.
———. 2008a. “Stimulus Math (Wonkish).” New York Times, November 10.
———. 2008b. “Synchronized Sinking,” New York Times, August 23.
———. 2009a. The Return of Depression Economics and the Crisis of 2008. New York: W.W. Norton.
———. 2009b. “How Did Economists Get It So Wrong?” New York Times, September 2.
———. 2011a. “The Lesser Depression,” New York Times, July 21.
———. 2011b. “This Week Transcript: Gen. Jim Jones (Ret.).” ABC News interview, March 27.
———. 2012a. “Financial Crisis Denialism.” New York Times, October 17.
———. 2012b. “The ‘Uncertainty’ Scam.” New York Times, October 22.
———. 2013a. “How the Case for Austerity Has Crumbled.” New York Review of Books.
———. 2013b. “Phony Fear Factor.” New York Times, August 8.
———. 2013c. “Secular Stagnation, Coalmines, Bubbles, and Larry Summers.” New York Times, November 16.
———. 2014a. “The Stimulus Tragedy.” New York Times, February 21.
———. 2014b. “The Inflation Obsession.” New York Times, March 2.
———. 2014c. “Euphemistic at the IMF.” New York Times, April 4.
———. 2014d. “Inflation Targets Reconsidered.” Draft paper for European Central Bank Sintra conference, May.
Kuczynski, P. 1982. “Latin American Debt.” Foreign Affairs 61(2): 344.
Laeven, L., and F. Valencia. 2008. “Systemic Banking Crises: A New Database.” IMF Working Paper 08/224, International Monetary Fund, Washington.
———. 2011. “The Real Effects of Financial Sector Interventions during Crises.” IMF Working Paper 11/45, International Monetary Fund, Washington.
———. 2012. “Systemic Banking Crises Database: An Update.” IMF Working Paper 12/163, International Monetary Fund, Washington.
———. 2013. “Systemic Banking Crises Database.” IMF Economic Review 61(2): 225–70.
Lagarde, C. 2011. “Global Action for Global Recovery.” Project Syndicate, September 25.
———. 2014. “The Global Economy in 2014.” Speech at the National Press Club, January 15.
Lane, P. R. 2012. “Financial Globalization and the Crisis.” BIS Working Paper 397, Bank for International Settlements, Basel.
Lane, P. R., and G. M. Milesi-Ferretti. 2007. “The External Wealth of Nations MarkII: Revised and Extended Estimates of Foreign Assets and Liabilities, 1970–2004.” Journal of international Economics 73: 223–50.
———. 2011. “The Cross-Country Incidence of the Global Crisis.” IMF Economic Review 59: 77–110.
———. 2012. “External Adjustment and the Global Crisis.” Journal of International Economics 88 (2): 252–65.
Lang, S. 2010. “Economist Alfred Kahn, ‘Father of Airline Regulation’ and Former Presidential Adviser, Dies at 93.” Cornell Chronicle, December 27.
Leamer, E. E. 2007. “Housing Is the Business Cycle.” Proceedings, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, 149–233.
———. 2008. “What’s a Recession, Anyway?” NBER Working Paper 14221, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Massachusetts.
———. 2009. Macroeconomic Patterns and Stories. Springer.
Lee, W. 2014. “Policy Uncertainty Stalls Global Investment.” Citi GPS: Global Perspectives & Solutions opinion article.
Levchenko, A., L. T. Lewis, and L. L. Tesar. 2010. “The Collapse of International Trade during the 2008–09 Crisis: In Search of the Smoking Gun.” IMF Economic Review 58 (2): 214–53.
Lewis, A. 1980. “The Slowing Down of the Engine of Growth.” American Economic Review 70 (4): 555–64.
Lewis, M. 2010. The Big Short: Inside the Doomsday Machine. New York: W.W. Norton.
Lo, A. W. 2012. “Reading about the Financial Crisis: A Twenty-One-Book Review.” Journal of Economic Literature 50: 151–78.
Loungani, P. 2012. “Seven Questions: Unemployment through the Prism of the Great Recession.” IMF Research Bulletin 13 (1).
Lucas, R. E. 1975. “An Equilibrium Model of the Business Cycle.” Journal of Political Economy 83: 1113–44.
———. 1977. “Understanding Business Cycles,” in Stabilization of the Domestic and International Economy, edited by K. Brunner and A. H. Meltzer. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 5. Amsterdam.
———. 1995. “Monetary Neutrality.” Economic Science Prize Lecture.
———. 2012. “Interview on Modern Macroeconomics.” Economic Dynamics 14 (1).
———, and T. Sargent. 1978. “After Keynesian Economics, After the Phillips Curve: Persistence of High Inflation and High Unemployment.” Federal Reserve Bank of Boston Conference volume.
Luce, E. 2014. “RIP Obama’s Stimulus: Funeral for a Policy Success.” Financial Times, February 23.
Lumsdaine, R., and E. S. Prasad. 2003. “Identifying the Common Component of International Economic Fluctuations: A New Approach.” Economic Journal 113: 101–27.
Magnus, G. 2011. Uprising: Will Emerging Markets Shape or Shake the World Economy? Hoboken, New Jersey: John Wiley and Sons.
Mandelman, F. S., and A. Zlate. 2012. “Immigration, Remittances and Business Cycles.” Journal of Monetary Economics 59 (2): 196–213.
Mankiw, N. G. 2007. “How to Avoid Recession? Let the Fed Work.” New York Times, December 23.
———. 2009. “Are Fiscal Multipliers Now Big or Small?” Blog, March 5.
———. 2012. Macroeconomics. Worth Publishers.
Matthews, D. 2011. “Did the Stimulus Work? A Review of the Nine Best Studies on the Subject.” Wonkblog, Washington Post, August 24.
McKinsey Global Institute. 2013. Financial Globalization: Retreat or Reset? Seoul.
Meltzer, A. 2010. A History of the Federal Reserve, Vol. 2, Book 2. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
———. 2012. “Federal Reserve Policy in the Great Recession.” Cato Journal 32 (2): 255–63.
Mendoza, E. G. 2001. “Credit, Prices, and Crashes: Business Cycles with a Sudden Stop.” NBER Working Paper 8338, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Massachusetts.
———. 2010. “Sudden Stops, Financial Crises and Leverage.” American Economic Review 100: 1941–66.
Mendoza, E. G., and M. E. Terrones. 2008. “An Anatomy of Credit Booms: Evidence from Macro Aggregates and Micro Data.” IMF Working Paper 08/226, International Monetary Fund, Washington.
———. 2012. “An Anatomy of Credit Booms and their Demise.” NBER Working Paper 18379, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Massachusetts.
Mian, A., and A. Sufi. 2012. “What Explains High Unemployment: The Aggregate Demand Channel.” Unpublished, Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University.
———. 2014. House of Debt. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Milesi-Ferretti, G. M., and C. Tille. 2011. “The Great Retrenchment: International Capital Flows During the Global Financial Crisis.” Economic Policy 26: 285–342.
Miller, P. J. 1994. The Rational Expectations Revolution. Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press.
Mishkin, F. 2009. “Is Monetary Policy Effective During Financial Crises?” American Economic Review 99 (2): 573–77.
Mitchell, W. C. 1927. “The Processes Involved in Business Cycles.” Business Cycles: The Problem and Its Setting, Chapter 1, 1–60.
Mitchener, B. 1992. “EC Devalues the Lira by 7%; Bundesbank to Lower Rates.” New York Times, September 14.
Mokyr, J. 2014. “Secular Stagnation? Not In Your Life,” in Secular Stagnation: Facts, Causes and Cures, edited by Coen Teulings and Richard Baldwin, pp. 83–90, CEPR Press.
Mollenkamp, C., S. Craig, S. Ng, and A. Lucchetti. 2008. “Lehman Files for Bankruptcy; Merrill Is Sold, AIG Seeks Cash.” Wall Street Journal, September 16.
Moneta, F., and R. Rüffer. 2009. “Business Cycle Synchronisation in East Asia.” Journal of Asian Economics 20: 1–12.
Mullaney, T. E. 1977. “A Slow World Recovery.” New York Times, June 19.
Mulligan, C. 2012. The Redistribution Recession: How Labor Market Distortions Contracted the Economy. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Mumtaz, H., S. Simonelli, and S. Surico. 2011. “International Comovements, Business Cycle and Inflation: A Historical Perspective.” Review of Economic Dynamics 14 (1): 176–98.
Mussa, M. 2009. “World Recession and Recovery: A V or an L?” Peterson Institute for International Economics Working Paper, Washington.
National Association for Business Economics. 2014. “Economists Align on Monetary Policy but not on Fiscal Issues.”
NBER Business-Cycle Dating Committee. 2003. “The NBER’s Business-Cycle Dating Procedure.” National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Massachusetts.
———. 2010. “US Business Cycle Expansions and Contractions.” National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Massachusetts.
———. 2011. “Determination of the December 2007 Peak in Economic Activity.” National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Massachusetts.
———. 2013. “The NBER’s Business-Cycle Dating Procedure: Frequently Asked Questions.” National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Massachusetts.
Ncube, M., Z. Brixiova, and Q. Meng. 2014. “Can Intra-Regional Trade Act as a Global Shock Absorber in Africa?” African Development Bank Group Working Paper 198.
Neumeyer, P. A., and F. Perri. 2005. “Business Cycles in Emerging Economies: The Role of Interest Rates.” Journal of Monetary Economics 52 (2): 345–80.
New York Times. 1987. “Arthur F. Burns Is Dead at 83; A Shaper of Economic Policy.” June 27.
———. 1990. “Washington Considers a Clear Iraqi Defeat To Be Necessary to Bolster Its Arab Allies.” August 22.
———. 2007. “BNP Paribas Suspends Funds because of Subprime Problems.” August 9.
———. 2008. “As Goldman and Morgan Shift, a Wall St. Era Ends.” September 21.
———. 2009. “Deal Reached in Congress on $789 Billion Stimulus Plan.” February 11.
Norrbin, S. C., and D. E. Schlagenhauf. 1996. “The Role of International Factors in the Business Cycle: A Multi-Country Study.” Journal of International Economics 40 (1–2): 85–104.
Nossiter, B. D. 1974. “Global Headache.” Washington Post, September 22.
Obstfeld, M. 2012. “Financial Flows, Financial Crises, and Global Imbalances.” Journal of International Money and Finance 31: 469–80.
———. 2013. “Crises and the International System.” International Economic Journal 27 (2): 143–55.
Obstfeld, M., and K. Rogoff. 2002. “Global Implications of Self-Oriented National Monetary Rules.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 117 (2): 503–35.
———. 2010. “Global Imbalances and the Financial Crisis: Products of Common Causes,” in Asia and the Global Financial Crisis, edited by R. Glick and M. M. Spiegel. Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, 131–72.
Obstfeld, M., D. Cho, and A. Mason, eds. 2012. Global Economic Crisis: Impacts, Transmission, and Recovery. Edward Elgar.
Office of the Historian. 2013. “Milestones: 1989–1992,” article published at history.state.gov /milestones/1989-1992/fall-of-communism.
Ohanian, L., J. Taylor, and I. J. Wright. 2012. Government Policy and the Delayed Economic Recovery. Stanford, California: Hoover Institution Press.
O’Neill, J. 2011. The Growth Map: Economic Opportunity in the BRICs and Beyond. Portfolio/Penguin.
———, and A. Terzi. 2014. “Changing Trade Patterns, Unchanging European and Global Governance.” Bruegel Working Paper 2014/02.
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD). 2002. Measuring the Information Economy. Paris.
———. 2009. “The Jobs Crisis: What Are the Implications for Employment and Social Policy?”OECD Employment Outlook.
———. 2012a. OECD Employment Outlook.
———. 2012b. OECD Internet Economy Outlook.
———. 2014. Economic Policy Reforms: Going for Growth.
Orlowski, L. T. 2001. Transition and Growth in Post-Communist Countries: The Ten-Year Experience. Cheltenham, United Kingdom; Edward Elgar.
Osborne, G. 2014. “What the Economic Pessimists Are Missing.” Wall Street Journal, April 10.
Otker-Robe, I., and A. M. Podpiera. 2013. “The Social Impact of Financial Crises: Evidence from the Global Financial Crisis.” Policy Research Working Paper 6703, World Bank, Washington.
Otto, G., G. Voss, and L. Willard. 2001. “Understanding OECD Output Correlations.” RBA Research Discussion Paper 2001–05, Reserve Bank of Australia, Sydney.
Oudiz, G., and J. Sachs. 1985. “International Policy Coordination in Dynamic Macroeconomic Models,” in International Economic Policy Coordination, edited by W. H. Buiter and R. C. Marston, 274–330.
Pagan, A. R., and K. A. Sossounov. 2003. “A Simple Framework for Analyzing Bull and Bear Markets.” Journal of Applied Econometrics 18 (1): 23–46.
Paletta, D., and M. Phillips. 2011. “S&P Strips U.S. of Top Credit Rating.” Wall Street Journal, August 6.
Panizza, U., and F. Presbitero. 2013. “Public Debt and Economic Growth in Advanced Economies: A Survey.” Swiss Journal of Economics and Statistics 149 (2): 175–204.
Papell, D. H., and R. Prodan. 2011. “The Statistical Behavior of GDP after Financial Crises and Severe Recessions.” Working Paper, University of Houston, Houston, Texas.
Parikh, S. H. 2013. “A Secular View of Assets: Surfing the Wedge.” PIMCO Asset Allocation Focus, June 11.
Paulson, H. M. 2011. On the Brink: Inside the Race to Stop the Collapse of the Global Financial System. New York: Business Plus.
Perotti, R. 2012. “The ‘Austerity Myth’: Gain without Pain?” in Fiscal Policy after the Financial Crisis. Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research, 307–54.
Perri, F., and V. Quadrini. 2011. “International Recessions.” NBER Working Paper 17201, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Massachusetts.
Porter, E. 2013. “Economists Agree: Solutions are Elusive.” Economic Scene, New York Times, April 23.
Prasad, E. 2014. “The Fed Is Not to Blame for Turmoil in Emerging Markets.” Financial Times, February 12.
Queralto, A. 2013. “A Model of Slow Recoveries from Financial Crises.” International Finance Discussion Paper 1097, Federal Reserve Board.
Rabobank. 2013. “The Mexican 1982 Debt Crisis.” Economic Report.
Rajan, R. G. 2011. Fault Lines: How Hidden Fractures Still Threaten the World Economy. Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press.
———. 2012. “The True Lessons of the Recession.” Foreign Affairs 91 (3): 69–79.
———. 2014. “Competitive Monetary Easing: Is It Yesterday Once More?” Remarks at the Brookings Institution, April 10.
Ramey, G., and V. A. Ramey. 1995. “Cross-Country Evidence on the Link between Volatility and Growth.” American Economic Review 85 (5): 1138–51.
Ramey, V. A. 2011. “Identifying Government Spending Shocks: It’s All in the Timing.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 126 (1): 1–50.
Ratha, D. 2005. “Remittances: A Lifeline for Development.” Finance and Development 42 (4).
Reifschneider, D., W. Wascher, and D. Wilcox. 2013. “Aggregate Supply in the United States; Recent Developments and Implications for the Conduct of Monetary Policy.” Federal Reserve Board Finance and Economics Discussion Series 77.
Reinhart, C. M., and K. S. Rogoff. 2008. “Is the 2007 U.S. Subprime Crisis So Different? An International Historical Comparison.” American Economic Review 98 (2): 339–44.
———. 2009. This Time Is Different: Eight Centuries of Financial Folly. Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press.
———. 2010a. “Growth in a Time of Debt.” American Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings 100: 573–78.
———. 2010b. “Growth in a Time of Debt.” NBER Working Paper 15639, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Massachusetts.
———. 2011. “A Decade of Debt.” NBER Working Paper 16827, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Massachusetts.
———. 2012a. “This Time is Different, Again? The US Five Years after the Onset of Subprime,” VoxEU, October 22.
———. 2012b. “Five Years after Crisis, No Normal Recovery.” Bloomberg, April 2.
———. 2012c. “Sorry, U.S. Recoveries Really Aren’t Different.” Bloomberg, October 15.
———. 2014. “Recovery from the Financial Crises: Evidence from 100 Episodes.” NBER Working Paper 19823, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Massachusetts.
Reinhart, C., and V. R. Reinhart. 2010. “After the Fall.” Proceedings—Economic Policy Symposium, Jackson Hole, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, 17–60.
Reuters. 2010. “S&P Downgrades Greece Ratings into Junk Status.” April 27.
———. 2012. “Cyprus Seeks EU Bailout for Banks Budget.” June 25.
Robinson, K. 2013. “Savings and Loan Crisis.” federalreservehistory.org.
Rodrik, D. 2012. The Globalization Paradox: Democracy and the Future of the World Economy. New York: Norton.
———. 2013. “The Past, Present, and Future of Economic Growth.” Global Citizen Foundation Working Paper 1.
———. 2014. “Death by Finance.” Project Syndicate, February 10.
———. 2015. “Economists vs. Economics.” Project Syndicate, September 10.
Rodrik, D., and A. Subramanian. 2014. “Emerging Markets’ Victimhood Narrative.” Bloomberg.com, January 31.
Rogoff, K. S. 2002a. “Press Conference on the World Economic Outlook.” April 18. http://www.imf.org/external/index.htm.
———. 2002b. “The Recession That Almost Was.” Financial Times, April 5.
———. 2008. “Inflation Is Now the Lesser Evil.” Project Syndicate, December 2.
———. 2011. “The Second Great Contraction.” Project Syndicate, August 2.
———. 2013. “What’s the Problem with Advanced Economies?” Project Syndicate, December 4.
Rogoff, K. S., D. Robinson, and T. Bayoumi. 2002. “Was It a Global Recession?” World Economic Outlook. Washington: International Monetary Fund, April.
Romer, C. 2009a. “Lessons from the Great Depression for Economic Recovery in 2009.” Presented at the Brookings Institution, Washington, March 9.
———. 2009b. “The Economic Crisis: Causes, Policies, and Outlook.” Testimony before the Joint Economic Committee of the U.S. Congress, April 30.
———. 2013. “Lessons from the Great Depression for Policy Today.” Teach-In on the Great Depression and World War II, University of Oklahoma.
Romer, C., and D. Romer. 2002. “The Evolution of Economic Understanding and Postwar Stabilization Policy.” Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Proceedings: 11–78.
———. 2004. “A New Measure of Monetary Shocks: Derivation and Implications.” American Economic Review 94 (4): 1055–84.
Rose, A. K., and M. M. Spiegel. 2010. “The Causes and Consequences of the 2008 Crisis: International Linkages and American Exposure.” Pacific Economic Review 15: 340–63.
———. 2011. “Cross-Country Causes and Consequences of the Crisis: An Update.” European Economic Review 55 (3): 309–24.
Rotemberg, J. J. 2013. “Patience after Accusations of Error: 100 Years of Monetary Policy at the U.S. Federal Reserve.” Harvard Business School Working Paper, Cambridge, Massachusetts.
Rothstein, J. 2012. “The Labor Market Four Years into the Crisis: Assessing Structural Explanations.” ILR Review 65 (3): 467–500.
Roubini, N. 2008. “The Perfect Storm of a Global Recession.” Project Syndicate, August 13.
———. 2009. “Green Shoots or Yellow Weeds.” Forbes, May 14.
———. 2011. “That Stalling Feeling.” Project Syndicate, June 21.
Roubini, N., and S. Mihm. 2011. Crisis Economics: A Crash Course in the Future of Finance. New York: Penguin Books.
Rowen, H. 1974. “Experts Hedge on ’74 Outlook: Oil Crisis May Trigger Worldwide Recession.” Washington Post, January 13.
———. 1989. “Warning—Global Recession Ahead.” Washington Post, April 6.
Sachs, J. D. 2008. “A Sustainable Recovery.” Project Syndicate, November 30.
———. 2009. “The Economic Need for Stable Policies, Not a Stimulus.” Scientific American, February 16.
———. 2015. “Paul Krugman and the Obama Recovery,” Project Syndicate, January 5.
Sahadi, J. 2008. “Bailout is Law.” CNN Money, October 3.
Samuelson, R. J. 2012. “Why the Recovery Is Feeble,” Washington Post, November 25.
———. 2013. “Times Have Changed, and Our Economic Vocabulary Can’t Keep Up.” Washington Post, December.
———. 2014. “The Recovery: DéjÀ Vu All Over?” Washington Post, February 26.
Sargent, T. J. 2002. “Commentary: The Evolution of Economic Understanding and Postwar Stabilization Policy.” Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Proceedings 2002: 79–94.
———, and N. Wallace. 1975. “‘Rational’ Expectations, the Optimal Monetary Instrument, and the Optimal Money Supply Rule.” Journal of Political Economy 83 (2): 241–54.
Sensier, M., D. R. Osborn, and N. Ocal. 2002. “Asymmetric Interest Rate Effects for the UK Economy.” Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 64 (4): 315–39.
Shabecoff, P. 1975. “The Question in Capital: Recession or Depression?” New York Times, March 7.
Sharma, R. 2012. Breakout Nations: In Pursuit of the Next Economic Miracles. New York: Norton.
Sharma, R. 2015. A Global Recession May Be Brewing in China. Wall Street Journal, August 16.
Shiller, R. J. 2009. “The Ghost in the Recovery Machine.” Project Syndicate, November 13.
Shin, H. S. 2009. “Reflections on Northern Rock: The Bank Run That Heralded the Global Financial Crisis.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 23 (1): 101–19.
Sichel, D. E. 1994. “Inventories and the Three Phases of the Business Cycle.” Journal of Business & Economic Statistics 12 (3): 269–77.
Sidel, R., D. Enrich, and D. Fitzpatrick. 2008. “WaMu Is Seized, Sold Off to J.P. Morgan, in Largest Failure in U.S. Banking History.” Wall Street Journal, September 26.
Sims, J. 2013. “Latin American Debt Crisis of the 1980s.” federalreservehistory.org.
Sinai, A. 1992 “Financial and Real Business Cycles.” Eastern Economic Journal 18 (1): 1–54.
———. 2010. “The Business Cycle in a Changing Economy: Conceptualization, Measurement, Dating.” American Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings 100: 25–29.
Solomou, S. 1998. Economic Cycles since 1870: Long Cycles and Business Cycles since 1870. Manchester University Press.
Sommerville, G. 2008. “U.S. Seizes Fannie, Freddie, Aims to Calm Markets.” Reuters, September 7.
Sorkin, A. S. 2011. Too Big to Fail: The Inside Story of How Wall Street and Washington Fought to Save the Financial System and Themselves. New York: Penguin Group.
Spence, M. 2011. The Next Convergence: The Future of Economic Growth in a Multispeed World. New York: Farrar, Straus, and Giroux.
———. 2014. “Overshooting in Emerging Markets.” Project Syndicate, February 20.
Spilimbergo A., S. Symansky, O. Blanchard, and C. Cottarelli. 2008. “Fiscal Policy for the Crisis.” IMF Staff Position Note 08/01, International Monetary Fund, Washington.
Stein, J. C. 2013. “Yield-Oriented Investors and the Monetary Transmission Mechanism.” Remarks presented at Banking, Liquidity, and Monetary Policy Symposium Sponsored by the Center for Financial Studies in Honor of Raghuram Rajan, September 26.
Stiglitz, J. E. 2009. “Developing Countries and the Global Crisis.” Project Syndicate, April 6.
Stock, J. H., and M. W. Watson. 2005. “Understanding Changes In International Business Cycle Dynamics.” Journal of the European Economic Association 3 (5): 968–1006.
———. 2012. “Disentangling the Channels of the 2007–09 Recession.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (Spring): 81–156.
Stone, C. 2013. “Testimony of Chad Stone,” Speech delivered at the Center on Budget and Policy Priorities, September 24.
Summers, L. 2009. “Remarks of L. H. Summers, Director of the National Economic Council Responding to an Historic Economic Crisis: The Obama Program.” Brookings Institution, March 13.
———. 2013. “Why Stagnation Might Prove to be the New Normal.” Financial Times¸ December 15.
———. 2014. “What the World Must Do to Kickstart Growth.” Financial Times, April 6.
Swagel, P. 2009. “The Financial Crisis: An Inside View,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 40 (1): 1–78.
———. 2013. “Financial Crisis Reading List.” New York Times, July 15.
Swanson, E., and J. C. Williams. 2013. “Measuring the Effect of the Zero Lower Bound on Medium- and Longer-Term Interest Rates.” Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco.
Tapsoba, S. J. A. 2009. “Trade Intensity and Business Synchronicity in Africa.” Journal of African Economics 18 (2): 287–318.
Taylor, J. B. 2012. “An Unusually Weak Recovery as Usually Defined.” Economics One (blog), October 26.
———. 2013a. “International Monetary Policy Coordination: Past, Present, and Future.” BIS Working Paper 437, Bank for International Settlements, Basel.
———. 2013b. “With Better Policy, the Recovery Could Have Been V-Shaped.” Economics One (blog), September 16.
———. 2013c. “Causes of the Financial Crisis and the Slow Recovery: A 10-Year Perspective.” SIPR Discussion Paper 13-026.
———. 2014a. “The Role of Policy in the Great Recession and the Weak Recovery.” American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings 104 (5): 61–66.
———. 2014b. “The Economic Hokum of ‘Secular Stagnation’,” Wall Street Journal, January 1.
Temin, P. 1976. Did Monetary Factors Cause the Great Depression? New York: Norton.
———. 1991. Lessons from the Great Depression. Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press.
Terrones, M. E., A. Scott, and P. Kannan. 2009. “From Recession to Recovery: How Soon and How Strong?” World Economic Outlook. Washington: International Monetary Fund, April.
Time Magazine. 1978. “Business: Yes, We Have No Bananas,” December 11.
Totaro, L., and E. Ross-Thomas. 2011. “Italy, Spain Ratings Cut by Fitch; Belgium Is Put Under Review by Moody’s.” Bloomberg, October 7.
Turner, A. 2012. Economics after the Crisis: Objectives and Means. Lionel Robbins Lectures. Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press.
Tylecote, A. 1992. “Why World Recession Has a Long Time to Run.” Guardian, September 12.
Uchitelle, L. 1991. “Plea by U.S. on Rate Cut Is Rejected.” New York Times, April 29.
United Nations. 1990. “United Nations Iraq-Kuwait Observation Mission.” Resolution 678.
USA Today. 1996. “1991 Gulf War Chronology.” September 3.
U.S. Department of the Treasury. 2013. “The Financial Crisis Five Years Later: Response, Reform, and Progress.” Treasury Note, Washington.
van Dijk, M. 2013. “The Social Costs of Financial Crises.” Working Paper, Erasmus University, Rotterdam.
Végh, C. A., and G. Vuletin. 2013. “The Road to Redemption: Policy Response to Crises in Latin America.” Paper presented at the 14th Jacques Polak Annual Research Conference, November 7–8, Washington.
Voice of America. 2009. “Study: 2009 Likely to See Weakest Global Economy in Half-Century.” November 1.
Volcker, P. A. 1978. Rediscovery of the Business Cycle. The Free Press.
Walker, A. 2009. “What Is a Global Recession?” BBC News, February 10.
Wallop, H. 2007. “Northern Rock Shares Crash as Customers Queue” Telegraph, September 14.
Walsh, C. E. 1993. “What Caused the 1990–1991 Recession?” Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Economic Review 2: 33–48.
Washington Post. 1994. “After the Worldwide Recession.” Editorial, December 22.
Wearden, G. 2008. “British Government Unveils £37bn Banking Bail-out Plan.” Guardian, October 13.
Weber, S. 1997. “The End of the Business Cycle?” Foreign Affairs 76 (4): 65–82.
Werning, I. 2012. “Managing a Liquidity Trap: Monetary and Fiscal Policy.” Unpublished, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Cambridge, Massachusetts.
Wessel, D. 2010. In FED We Trust: Ben Bernanke’s War on the Great Panic. New York: Crown Publishers.
Wilkinson, M. 1982. “Prospects for Global Economic Revival Are Worsening.” Financial Times, September 13.
Williamson, J. 2005. “The Potential of International Policy Coordination.” Peterson Institute for International Economics.
Williamson, S. 2013. “The Balance Sheet and the Fed’s Future.” New Monetarist Economics (blog), March 10.
Wolf, M. 2009. “Why the G20 Must Focus on Sustaining Demand.” Financial Times, March 10.
———. 2010a. “What We Can Learn from Japan’s Decades of Trouble.” Financial Times, January 12.
———. 2010b. “What the World Must Do to Sustain Its Convalescence.” Financial Times, February 3.
———. 2010c. “Why Plans for Early Fiscal Tightening Carry Global Risks.” Financial Times, June 17.
———. 2013a. “Austerity in the Eurozone and the UK: Kill or Cure?” Financial Times, May 23.
———. 2013b. “How Austerity Has Failed.” Nybooks.com, July 11.
———. 2014. “We Are Trapped in a Cycle of Credit Booms, Financial Times, October 7.
Woodford, M. 2010. “Financial Intermediation and Macroeconomic Analysis.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 24 (4): 21–44.
———. 2012. “Methods of Policy Accommodation at the Interest-Rate Lower Bound.” 2012 Economic Policy Symposium, Jackson Hole, Wyoming.
World Bank. 2010. The MDGs After the Crisis: Global Monitoring Report 2010. Washington.
———. 2011. “Global Development Horizons 2011—Multipolarity: The New Global Economy.” Washington.
———. 2013. “World Development Report on Jobs.” Washington.
Wynne, M. A. 2011. “The Sluggish Recovery from the Great Recession: Why There Is No ‘V’ Rebound This Time.” Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Economic Letter 6 (9): 1–4.
Yellen, J. 2013a. “Panel Discussion on ‘Monetary Policy: Many Targets, Many Instruments. Where Do We Stand?’” Remarks at International Monetary Fund Conference on Rethinking Macro Policy II, Washington.
———. 2013b. “Challenges Confronting Monetary Policy.” Speech delivered at the 2013 National Association for Business Economics Conference.
Yilmaz, K. 2010. “International Business Cycle Spillovers.” CEPR Working Paper 7966, Centre for Economic Policy Research, London.
Zandi, M. 2013. “The Impact of Political Uncertainty on Jobs and the Economy.” Testimony before the U.S. Senate Budget Committee.
Zarnovitz, V. 1992. Business Cycles: Theory, History, Indicators and Forecasting. Chicago: University of Chicago press for National Bureau of Economic Research.
Credits
Art
Video icon created by Mike Arndt from the Noun Project, https://thenounproject.com/.
Timeline icon created by Leinad Lehmko from the Noun Project, https://thenounproject.com/.
Podcast icon created by Nate Eul from the Noun Project, https://thenounproject.com/.
Great Recession Over Color by Bob Englehart, The Hartford Courant.
Video Images
Signing of Bretton Woods Agreements in July 1944, photo by Keystone-France/Gamma-Keystone via Getty Images.
A trader holding his head at the floor of the New York Stock Exchange, photo by MARIA BASTONE/AFP/Getty Images.
The Dollar Falls Under 100 Yens In Tokyo, photo by Kurita KAKU/Gamma-Rapho via Getty Images.
A trader shouts out his transactions 11 January at the Lima stock exchange at the closing of trading, photo by RENZO UCCELLI/AFP/Getty Images.
A child sits inside cardboard box during a rally by the Association of Community Organizations for Reform Now outside the U.S. Treasury, photo by Chip Somodevilla/Getty Images.
Epigraphs
Quotes from the The Economist are reprinted with permission. Please see reference list for individual issues.
Quote by Andrew Walker is taken from “What Is a Global Recession,” February 10, 2009, courtesy of BBC News.
Quote by Paul Volcker is reprinted with the permission of the Free Press, a Division of Simon & Schuster, Inc. from The Rediscovery of the Business Cycle by Paul A. Volcker.
Quote by Arthur Burns and Wesley C. Mitchell is taken from Burns, Arthur F. and Wesley C. Mitchell. 1946. “Working Plans.” In Measuring Business Cycles, Arthur F. Burns and Wesley C. Mitchell, 3–22. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Quote by Stephen Castle is taken from the New York Times, November 28, 2012 © 2012 All rights reserved. Used by permission and protected by the Copyright Laws of the United States. The printing, copying, redistribution, or transmission of this Content without express written permission is prohibited.
Quote by Saumil Parikh is taken from Parikh, S. H. 2013. “A Secular View of Assets: Surfing the Wedge.” PIMCO Asset Allocation Focus (June 11).
Quote by Nouriel Roubini is taken from Forbes, May 14, 2009, © 2009 Forbes LLC. All rights reserved. Used by permission and protected by the Copyright Laws of the United States. The printing, copying, redistribution, or transmission of this Content without express written permission is prohibited.
Quote by Nouriel Roubini is taken from “The Perfect Storm of a Global Recession,” August 13, 2008, and is reprinted courtesy of Project Syndicate.
Quote by Peter S. Goodman is taken from the New York Times, August 24, 2008 © 2008. All rights reserved. Used by permission and protected by the Copyright Laws of the United States. The printing, copying, redistribution, or transmission of this Content without express written permission is prohibited.
Quote by Paul Krugman is taken from the New York Times, August 23, 2008 © 2008. All rights reserved. Used by permission and protected by the Copyright Laws of the United States. The printing, copying, redistribution, or transmission of this Content without express written permission is prohibited.
Quote by Michael D. Bordo is taken from “Financial Recessions Don’t Lead to Weak Recoveries.” Wall Street Journal, September 27, 2012. Reprinted with permission.
Quote by John Taylor is taken from “With Better Policy, the Recovery Could Have Been V-Shaped.” Economics One (blog), September 16, 2013. Reprinted with permission.
Quote by Carmen M. Reinhart and Kenneth S. Rogoff is taken from “Sorry, U.S. Recoveries Really Aren’t Different.” Bloomberg, October 15, 2012. Reprinted with permission.
Quote by Martin Wolf is taken from “Why Plans for Early Fiscal Tightening Carry Global Risks.” Financial Times, June 17, 2010. Reprinted with permission.
Quote by Christina Romer is taken from “Lessons from the Great Depression for Policy Today.” Teach-In on the Great Depression and World War II, University of Oklahoma 2013. http://freedom.ou.edu/christina-romer-lessons-from-the-great-depression-for-policy-today. Reprinted with permission.
Quote by Alan Greenspan is taken from “Uncertainty Unbundled: The Metrics of Activism,” in Government Policies and the Delayed Economic Recovery, edited by L. E. Ohanian, J. B. Taylor, and I. J. Wright. Stanford, California: Hoover Institution Press, 2013. Reprinted with permission.
Quote by Ben S. Bernanke is taken from ‘‘Why Are Interest Rates So Low?’’ Ben Bernanke’s blog, Brookings Institution 2015. Reprinted with permission.
Quote by Max Wilkinson is taken from “Prospects for Global Economic Revival Are Worsening.” Financial Times, September 13, 1982. Reprinted with permission.
Quote by Narayana Kocherlakota is taken from “Modern Macroeconomic Models as Tools for Economic Policy.” The Region, Banking and Policy Issues Magazine of the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis 2010 (May 4): 5–21. Reprinted with permission.
Quote by Mohamed El-Erian is taken from “The Messy Politics of Economic Divergence,” Project Syndicate, March 2015. Reprinted with permission.
Index
Activity declines, in global recessions, 59
Activity variables
in advanced economies, 61f, 63t
capital flows, 40f, 53
capital flows over GDP, 54f, 55t, 199
consumption, 55t, 199
in developing economies, 63t
in downturns, 65, 66t
in emerging market economies, 61f, 63t
global expansions in, 86–87, 86f, 87f
in global recessions, 39–41, 40f, 54f, 55t
in global recoveries, 71, 72f, 73t, 75f
industrial production, 40f, 53, 54f, 55t, 199
investment, 55t, 199
oil consumption, 40f, 53, 54f, 55t, 199
output, 40f, 53, 54f, 55t, 199
output, following financial crises, 111f
residential investment, 199
in synchronized recessions, 99f
trade flows, 54f, 55t, 199
trade in, 40f, 53
unemployment, 40f, 54f, 55t, 199
unemployment, in global recoveries, 72f, 73t, 75, 78f
Advanced economies
activity variables in, 61f, 63t
financial channels of, in global business cycle transmission, 155–56
fiscal and monetary policies in, 5, 20
global and national business cycles linked in, 152–53, 152f
global business cycles in, 15–16, 16f, 21–22
global expansions in, 86f, 87f
in global recession (2009), 5, 47, 62, 161, 167–68
in global recessions, 62–64, 63t
in global recoveries, compared to world, 81f
in global recovery (post-2009), 76, 78f, 79t, 80–82, 80f, 84, 161
government expenditures of, in global recession (2009), 131, 132–33, 133f, 134f, 136
growth contributions of, 64f
income inequality in, 3
inflation in, 139f
interest rates in, 135f
monetary policies in, 133–34
national business cycles and world interest rates in, 152f
national business cycles transmitted by, 154–56
output of, 15–16, 16f
output of, in global recoveries, 113f
output projections of, 115f
public debt in, 132, 136, 137f
trade channels of, in global business cycle transmission, 154–55
uncertainty in, 121, 122–23, 126, 127, 128
Aggregate and per capita variables, weights used in, 201
Aggregate productivity shocks, 155
Aid and remittance flows, 155–56
Annual growth rates, of output and population, 26–28, 27t
Arab-Israeli conflict, 44–45
Argentina, 46
Asset prices
busts in, 118, 213
in financial crises, 106, 108, 117–18
in global recession (1991), 47, 48, 213
in global recession (2009), 47
global recession comparisons of, 49
in global recessions, 4, 41, 53
in global recoveries, 4, 41, 108, 162
Assets, of central banks, 132, 136f, 202
Austerity, in fiscal policies, 132–33
Austria, 138f
Banking crisis, 208, 214
Bank of Japan, 139
Bankruptcies, 69
Baxter, M., 102
Belgium, 138f
Bernanke, Ben S., 129
Big Five financial crises, 49, 105, 107f, 114
Blanchard, Olivier, 35, 119
Bordo, Michael, 103
Brazil, 46
Brown, Gordon, 5, 133
Burns, Arthur F., 23, 28–29
Business cycle. See Global business cycle; National business cycle; National business cycles
Canada, 45
Capital flows
activity variables for, 40f, 53
in global recession (2009), 60
global recovery activity variables in, 72f, 73t
over GDP, activity variables for, 54f, 55t, 199
Castle, Stephen, 51
Central banks
assets, 132, 136f, 202
global recession (2009) interventions of, 3
macroeconomic turning points of, 48–49
monetary policies of, 133, 134, 137, 141
Centre for Economic Policy Research (CEPR), 18, 28–29
Chicago Board Options Exchange Volatility Index, 122
Chile, 46
China, 62, 65
Claessens, S., 118
Commodity prices
in downturns, 65, 66t
food prices in, 42f, 56t, 74t 185
in global recoveries, 74t
gold prices in, 42f, 56t, 74t, 200
oil prices in, 42f, 45, 47, 56t, 74t, 84, 200
Communist bloc countries, 46, 47
Consumption
activity variables, 55t, 199
activity variables in synchronized recession, 99f
evolution of, 40–41, 41f
in financial crises, 106, 108, 109f, 111f, 112, 114, 118
in global recoveries, 108, 111f, 112
global recovery activity variables in, 71, 73t, 75f
house prices linked to, 118
Country group. See Advanced economies; Developing economies; Emerging market economies
Credit
in financial crises, 108, 110f, 112, 112f, 117, 118
financial variables in, 200
in global expansions, 85–86, 86f
in global recession (2009), 83
global recession comparisons of, 49
in global recessions, 4, 41, 42f, 53, 56t, 57f, 59
in global recoveries, 4, 41, 42f, 74t, 112f, 162
in global recovery (post-2009), 82, 162
in synchronized recession and downturns, 99f, 100
uncertainty and, 121, 126, 162
Currency crisis, 209
D’Amico, S., 141
Debt, deficit, and inflation, 138f
Debt crisis, 210
LDC, in global recession (1982), 213
Debt-to-GDP ratios, country-specific (2012), 136, 138f
Deficit, debt, and inflation, 138f
Developing economies
activity variables for, 63t
advanced economies transmitting national business cycles to, 154–56
emerging market economies compared to, 25–26
global and national business cycles linked in, 152–53, 152f
in global recessions, 62–64, 63t
in global recoveries, 79t, 80f
growth contributions of, 64f
national business cycles and world interest rates in, 152f
in world output distribution, 15–16, 16f
Double-dip recession, U.S., 212–13
Downturns, 65–67, 65f, 66t, 160
credit synchronization in, 99f, 100
financial crises in, 105–6, 106f
global recession compared to, 167
house price synchronization in, 99f, 100
synchronized, 97f, 100
Draghi, Mario, 83, 128
Eastern European economies, in global recession (1991), 215
Econometric model, 148, 153
Economic policy
debate on, 131
global recession (2009)’s divergence of, 131–41
growth promoted by, 131
for macroeconomic stabilization, 131
uncertainty measures, 201
understanding divergence of, 132
See also Fiscal policies; Monetary policies
The Economist, 1, 11, 35, 51, 69, 145
El-Erian, Mohamed, 114, 157
Emerging market economies
activity variables in, 61f, 63t
advanced economies transmitting national business cycles to, 154–56
developing economies compared to, 25–26
global and national business cycles linked in, 152–53, 152f
global business cycles in, 21
global expansions in, 86f, 87f
in global recession (2009), 5, 161
in global recessions, 62–64, 63t
in global recovery (post-2009), 76, 78f, 79t, 80, 80f, 161
government expenditures in, 133, 133f
growth contributions of, 64f
inflation in, 139f
interest rates in, 135f
national business cycles and world interest rates in, 152f
public debt in, 137f
in world output distribution, 15–16, 16f
Equity prices, 42f, 56t, 57f, 200
in financial crises, 110f, 117–18
in global expansions, 86f
in global recoveries, 74t, 76, 77f, 84f
house prices compared to, 118
ERM. See European Exchange Rate Mechanism
Euro area
central bank assets of, 136f
in global recession (2009), 3, 216–17
global recovery in, 83–84, 84f
government expenditures of, 134f
interest rates in, 135f
output in global recoveries of, 113f
output projections of, 115f
uncertainty in, 121, 122, 123, 124f, 126
European Central Bank (ECB), 83–84, 128, 139
European Exchange Rate Mechanism (ERM) crisis, 37, 38f, 46, 83, 214
Expansion, financial crises following, 108, 109f, 110f
Export activity variables in synchronized recession, 99f
Federal Open Market Committee, 119
Federal Reserve, 131, 139
Financial channel, of global business cycle transmission, 155–56
Financial crises
asset prices in, 106, 108, 117–18
Big Five, 49, 105, 107f
consumption in, 106, 108, 109f, 111f, 112, 114, 118
credit expansions prior to, 110f
credit in, 108, 110f, 112, 112f, 117, 118
cyclical outcomes in, 106
in downturns, 105–6, 106f
equity prices in, 110f, 117–18
expansions prior to, 108, 109f, 110f
in global recessions, 105–6, 106f
global recessions and recoveries impacted by, 20
in global recoveries, 105–6, 107f, 108, 111f, 112, 112f, 162
house prices and, 108, 110f, 112f, 117–18
investment in, 106, 108, 111f, 112, 114, 116, 118
output and, 107f, 112, 117–18
unemployment and, 106, 108, 109f, 111f
Financial flows, in global recession (2009), 167
Financial integration
in global business cycles, 17, 17f
globalization of, 102
in global recession (2009), 50, 161
synchronization in, 101
Financial linkages, in globalization and synchronization, 93, 95–96, 101, 102
Financial markets
in global recessions, 57f, 59
in global recoveries, 74t, 76, 77f
Financial openness, 202
Financial sector problems, in global recession (2009), 215–16
Financial variables
in credit, 200
in downturns, 65, 66t
in equity prices, 200
global expansions in, 86f
in global recessions, 4, 56t, 57f
in global recoveries, 74t
in house prices, 200
in inflation rates, 200
in LIBOR overnight/3 month, 200
short-term interest rates, 200
synchronization of, in recession, 99f
Finland, 46, 49
Fiscal policies
activity impacted by, 140, 141
divergence of, 132, 135–39
in global recession (2009), 5–6, 20, 162–63
in global recessions and recoveries, 5–6, 20, 162–63
in global recovery (post-2009), 82, 162–63
government expenditures as, 131, 132–33, 133f, 134f, 136
of stimulus then austerity, 132–33
U.S., as loose, 5–6
Fiscal stimulus. See Government expenditures
Fisher, I., 117
Food prices, 42f, 56t, 74t, 200
Foreign demand shocks, 154
France, 45, 113f, 115f, 138f
Friedman, Milton, 121
GDP. See Gross domestic product
Germany, 45
debt-to-GDP ratios (2012), 138f
in ERM crisis (1992), 46
in global recovery (post-2009), 82
output in global recoveries of, 113f
output projections of, 115f
Global business cycle, 11
in advanced economies, 15–16, 16f, 21–22
changing nature of, 15–17
country group linkages in, 151–53, 152f
country-specific, importance of, 153
defined, 15
econometric model for, 148, 153
in emerging market economies, 21
financial channel in, 155–56
future research on, 166
GDP in, 18, 26–30
globalization and synchronization in, 101–2
global recession and recovery as unavoidable in, 6, 14–15, 167–68
in global recession (2009) debates, 13
growth and synchronization, 149f
judgmental method for, 28–30, 39–43
measuring, 18, 23, 26–30
national business cycle growth in, 148
national business cycles linked to, 14, 20, 147–56, 149f, 151f, 152f
NBER and CEPR measures of, 28–29
regional business cycles linked to, 14
research on, 21–22
statistical method for, 28, 29, 37–39, 38f, 39f
trade channel in, 154–55
turning points in, 18, 19
uncertainty in, 123, 125f, 127–28
U.S. output in, 15
world trade and financial integration in, 17, 17f
Global expansions, 85–87, 86f, 87f
Globalization
financial linkages in, 93, 95–96, 101, 102
in global business cycle, 101–2
national business cycles and, 93
synchronized recessions linked to, 93, 101–2
Global recession
activity declines in, 59
activity variables in, 39–41, 40f, 54f, 55t
asset prices in, 4, 41, 53
average duration of, 37
balanced growth strategy for, 165
commodity prices in, 42f, 56t
comparisons between, 49–50
consumption evolution, 41f
credit in, 4, 41, 42f, 53, 56t, 57f, 59
databases for, 25–26
defined, 4, 13–18, 30, 159–60
downturns compared to, 167
duration and amplitude of, 96–98, 97f
effects by country group, 62–64, 63t
equity prices in, 42f, 56t, 57f
events surrounding, 44–47
financial crises in, 105–6, 106f
financial crises linked to, 20
financial markets in, 57f, 59
financial variables in, 4, 56t, 57f
fiscal and monetary policies in, 5–6, 20, 162–63
frequency of, 51, 67
future research on, 165–67
GDP in, 13, 18, 26, 30–31, 38–39, 39f, 53, 160
growth contributions, by county group in, 64f
growth prior to, 58
house prices in, 42f, 56t, 57f, 99f, 100, 117–18
human and social costs in, 85, 166
inflation rates in, 53, 56t, 57f, 59
interest rates in, 53, 56t, 57f, 59
investment evolution, 41f
macroeconomic variables declining in, 4
main features of, 19, 160–61
main similarities in, 53–60
output distribution during, 95f
output per capita in, 4
policy messages and coordination for, 164–65
policy space in, 164
real economy in, 53, 55t, 56f, 58–59
synchronization during, 93–99 82f, 95f, 96f, 97f, 98f, 99f, 160
turning points in, 37–43
as unavoidable, 6, 14–15, 167–68
uncertainty in, 121, 123, 125f, 126, 127–28, 128f
unemployment in, 59
U.S.’s historical impact on, 13
Global recession (1975), 11, 19
events surrounding, 44–45
gold standard ended, 211
Group of Seven in, 45
macroeconomic turning points in, 48
oil embargo (1973–74) in, 44–45, 160, 211
stagflation in, 45, 48, 211
supply shocks in, 166
synchronized recessions, 93, 94–95, 211
timeline of, 211
turning points in, 37–43
Global recession (1982), 19, 160
events surrounding, 44, 45–46
inflation highs in, 45
Latin American debt crisis in, 44, 45–46, 50
LDC debt crisis in, 213
macroeconomic turning points in, 48
monetary policies as tight in, 166, 212
oil crisis (1978–80) in, 212
oil prices in, 45
synchronized recessions in, 14, 95, 213
timeline of, 212–13
turning points in, 37–43
unemployment in, 45
U.S. double-dip recession, 212–13
Volcker disinflation in, 44
Global recession (1991), 19, 160
asset price busts in, 47, 48, 213
banking crises in, 214
communist bloc countries in, 46, 47
Eastern European economies transitioning in, 215
ERM Crisis in, 37, 38f, 46, 83, 214
events surrounding, 44, 46–47
Japan in, 46, 47, 48, 83
macroeconomic turning points in, 48
market weights in, 37, 38f
monetary policy in, 166
oil prices in, 45
Persian gulf war in, 46, 47, 84, 215
synchronized recessions in, 95, 214
timeline of, 213–15
turning points in, 37–43
unemployment in, 46
U.S. in, 46, 48, 83
Global recession (2009), 19, 160
advanced economies in, 5, 47, 62, 161, 167–68
asset prices in, 47
capital flows in, 60
central bank interventions in, 3
credit in, 83
as deepest, 58, 159–61
economic policy divergence in, 131–41
emerging market economies in, 5, 161
euro area crisis in, 3, 216–17
events surrounding, 44, 47
financial channel of global business cycle transmission in, 155–56
financial flows in, 167
financial integration in, 50, 161
financial sector problems in, 215–16
fiscal and monetary policies in, 5–6, 20, 162–63
global business cycles debated in, 13
government expenditures for, 131, 132–33, 133f, 134f, 136
Great Depression compared to, 5, 19, 25, 44, 47, 60, 100
housing prices in, 50, 60, 62, 83
Ireland in, 83
key lessons in, 161–64
Lehman Brothers bankruptcy in, 3, 5, 47, 114
leverage increases in, 50
list of events (2013–15) in, 217–18
macroeconomic turning points in, 48
macroeconomic uncertainty in, 5, 19, 20, 161, 166
oil prices in, 47
output contraction in, 161
policy uncertainty in, 5, 19, 162–63
securitization in, 50
Spain in, 83
Sub-Saharan Africa in, 132
synchronization in, 5, 19, 47, 59, 93–96, 101, 161, 216
timeline of, 215–18
trade collapse in, 60
turning points in, 37–43
uncertainty in, 121–22, 123, 126, 127, 128, 162
unemployment in, 60, 61f, 85
uniqueness of, 4–5, 19, 60, 62, 161
United Kingdom in, 83
U.S. as central in, 47, 49–50, 83
Global recovery, 69
activity variables in, 71, 72f, 73t, 75f
advanced economies compared to world in, 81f
asset prices in, 4, 41, 108, 162
commodity prices in, 74t
consumption in, 108, 111f, 112
credit in, 4, 41, 42f, 74t, 112f, 162
databases for, 25–26
defined, 4, 13–18, 30, 159–60
developing economies in, 79t, 80f
duration and amplitude of, 96–98, 97f
in euro area, 83–84, 84f
financial crises in, 105–6, 107f, 108, 111f, 112, 112f, 162
financial crises linked to, 20
financial markets in, 74t, 76, 77f
financial variables in, 74t
fiscal and monetary policies in, 5–6, 20, 162–63
future research on, 165–67
GDP in, 71
global expansions in, 85–87, 86f, 87f
growth during, 75, 80f
inflation rates in, 74t, 76, 77f
interest rates in, 74t, 76, 77f
investment in, 71, 108, 111f
main similarities, 71–76, 160–61
oil prices in, 74t, 84
output distribution during, 96f
output of advanced economies in, 113f
output per capita in, 4, 71, 75
policy messages for, 164–65
real economy in, 71–75, 72f, 73t, 74t, 75f
synchronization during, 96, 97–98, 99f
as unavoidable, 6, 14–15, 167–68
uncertainty in, 121–22, 123, 125f, 127–28, 128f
uncertainty linked to, 114
unemployment activity variables in, 72f, 73t, 75, 78f
unemployment and, 108, 111f
Global recovery (post-2009)
advanced economies in, 76, 78f, 79t, 80–82, 80f, 84, 161
credit in, 82, 161
emerging market economies in, 76, 78f, 79t, 80, 80f, 161
fiscal and monetary policies in, 82, 162–63
GDP in, 76
housing prices in, 82
investment in, 82
monetary policies for, 133–34, 162–63
unemployment in, 82
Gold prices, 42f, 56t, 74t, 200
Gold standard, global recession (1975) ending of, 211
Goodman, Peter S., 91
Government expenditures, 202
of advanced and emerging market economies, 133, 133f
by countries and regions, 134f
in global recession (2009), 131, 132–33, 133f, 134f, 136
Great Depression, 5, 19, 25, 44, 47, 60, 100
Great Moderation era, 159
Great Recession. See Global recession (2009)
Greece, 138f
Greenspan, Alan, 129
Gross, Bill, 114
Gross domestic debt, 202
Gross domestic product (GDP)
capital flows over, activity variables for, 54f, 55t, 199
in downturns, 65
in global business cycle, 18, 26–30
in global recessions, 38–39, 39f, 53, 160
in global recoveries, 71
in global recovery (post-2009), 76
market weights in growth of, 26–28, 27t, 39f
per capita, in global recessions, 13, 18, 26, 30–31
population growth and, 26–28, 27t
PPP in growth of, 26–28, 27t
in world output, 38–39, 39f
Group of Seven, 45
Growth, 6
balanced strategy for, 165
by country group, in global recessions, 64f
economic policies for promoting, 131
global impacting national, 148, 149f, 150, 151–52, 152f, 163–64
during global recoveries, 75, 80f
prior to global recessions, 58
and synchronization, 149f
uncertainty impacting, 123, 126–27, 127f
Gulf War, 46, 47, 84, 215
Hirata, H., 21–22
House prices, 42f, 56t, 57f, 200
consumption linked to, 118
equity prices compared to, 118
in financial crises, 108, 110f, 112f, 117–18
in financial variables of synchronized recession, 99f
in global expansions, 85–86, 86f
in global recession (2009), 50, 60, 62, 83
in global recoveries, 74t
in global recovery (post-2009), 82
output linked to, 118
in synchronized recession and downturns, 99f, 100
systemic risk in, 49
Human and social costs, 85, 166
Iceland, 138f
Imbs, J., 102
Income inequality, 3
India, 62, 65
Industrial production
activity variables, 40f, 53, 54f, 55t, 199
global recovery activity variables in, 71, 72f, 73t, 75f
Inflation, deficit, and debt, 138f
Inflation rates, 200
in advanced and emerging market economies, 139f
in global recession (1982), 45
in global recessions, 53, 56t, 57f, 59
in global recoveries, 74t, 76, 77f
Interest rates
in advanced economies, 135f
in emerging market economies, 135f
in euro area, 135f
in global recessions, 53, 56t, 57f, 59
in global recoveries, 74t, 76, 77f
monetary policies on, 132, 133, 135, 137, 141
national business cycle and, 151f, 152f
nominal short-term, 56t, 57f, 59, 74t
real short-term, 56t, 57f, 74t
uncertainty and, 123, 126
in United Kingdom, 135f
in U.S., 135f
zero lower bound, 133–34, 135, 137, 141, 163
Investment
activity variables for, 55t, 199
evolution of, 40–41, 41f
in financial crises, 106, 108, 111f, 112, 114, 116, 118
in global recoveries, 71, 108, 111f
in global recovery (post-2009), 82
Iraq, 47
Ireland, 46, 83, 138f
Italy, 45, 46, 113f, 115f, 138f
Jansen, W. J., 102
Japan, 3
in Big Five banking crises, 49, 114
central bank assets of, 136f
debt, deficit and inflation in, 138f
debt-to-GDP ratios (2012), 136, 138f
in global recession (1975), 45
in global recession (1991), 46, 47, 48, 83
government expenditures of, 134f
interest rates of, 135f
lost decade of, 47, 117
output in global recoveries of, 113f
output projections of, 115f
Judgmental method, 28–30, 39–43
Kalemli-Ozcan, S., 102
Keynes, J. M., 117
Keynesian policymaking, 48, 141
Kocherlakota, Narayana, 157
Kose, M. A., 21, 102, 118
Kouparitsas, M. A., 102
Krugman, Paul, 91
Kuwait, 47
Lagarde, Christine, 167
Latin American debt crisis, 44, 45–46, 50
LDC. See Less-Developed-Countries
Lehman Brothers failure, 3, 5, 47, 114
Less-Developed-Countries (LDC), debt crisis of, 213
Leverage increases, in global recession (2009), 50
LIBOR. See London interbank offered rate
Linkages between global and national cycles, 228–31
London interbank offered rate (LIBOR), 74t, 148–49, 200
Lost decade
Japan’s, 47, 117
Latin America’s, 46
Macroeconomics
economic policies for stabilizing, 131
future research on, 166–67
Keynesian, 48
policies for surveillance of, 164–65, 166
turning points in, 48–49
uncertainty in, 121–23, 124f, 126–27, 128
uncertainty in, in global recession (2009), 5, 19, 20, 161, 166
Macroeconomic uncertainty measures, 201
central bank assets in, 202
government expenditures, 202
gross domestic debt, 202
net debt, 202
overall balance, 202
public debt-to GDP ratio, 202
short-term interest rates, 202
Macroeconomic variable declines, 4
Market regulations, global recession comparisons of, 50
Market weights
in aggregate and per capita variables, 201
evolution of, 38f, 207
in evolution of output, 37, 38f
in GDP growth, 26–28, 27t, 39f
Medicare, 123
Mexico, 46
Mitchell, Wesley C., 23, 28–29
Monetary policies
activity impacted by, 140–41
in advanced economies, 133–34
of central banks, 133, 134, 137, 141
debate on, 131
divergence of, 132, 135–37, 139
divergence of effectiveness of, 135
of Federal Reserve, 131, 139
in global recession (1982), 166, 212
in global recession (1991), 166
in global recession (2009), 5–6, 20, 162–63
in global recovery (post-2009), 133–34, 162–63
on interest rates, 132, 133, 135, 137, 141
U.S., as loose, 5–6
Mortgage markets, U.S., 47
National Association for Business Economics, 122
National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER), 18, 28–29
National Business Cycle Dating Committee, 29
National business cycles
advanced economy transmission of, 154–56
country group linkages in, 151–53, 152f
country-specific, importance of, 153
defined, 29
econometric model for, 148, 153
evolution of, 29f
future research on, 166
global business cycle growth in, 148
global business cycle linked to, 14, 20, 147–56, 149f, 151f, 152f
globalization and, 93
interest rates in, 151f, 152f
National recession, U.S., 43–44
NBER. See National Bureau of Economic Research
Net debt, 202
Netherlands, 138f
Nominal short-term interest rates, 56t, 57f, 59, 74t
Norway, 46, 49
Obama, Barack, 105
Oil consumption
activity variables, 40f, 53, 54f, 55t, 199
global recovery activity variables in, 72f, 73t
Oil crisis (1978–80), 212
Oil embargo (1973–74), 44–45, 160, 211
Oil prices, 42f, 56t, 200
in global recession (1982), 45
in global recession (1991), 45
in global recession (2009), 47
in global recoveries, 74t, 84
in Gulf War, 47
Organization of the Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC), 44–45
Otrok, C., 21
Otto, G., 102
Output
activity variables, 40f, 53, 54f, 55t, 199
activity variables in synchronized recession, 99f
of advanced economies, 15–16, 16f
of advanced economies, in global recoveries, 113f
advanced economies activity variables for, 61f
distribution of, 15–16, 16f
distribution of, in global recessions, 95f
distribution of, in recoveries, 96f
in downturns, 65, 65f
emerging markets activity variables for, 61f
in financial crises, 107f, 111f, 112, 117–18
GDP in, 38–39, 39f
in global expansions, 86f, 87f
in global recession (2009), 161
in global recessions and recoveries, 4
in global recoveries, 4, 71, 75
global recovery activity variables in, 71, 72f, 73t, 75f
growth, by country groups, 149f
growth and synchronization in, 149f
house prices linked to, 118
market weights in evolution of, 37, 38f
population and, annual growth rates of, 26–28, 27t
PPP in evolution of, 37, 38f
projections of, past and current, 115f
in recessions and recoveries with financial crises, 107f
rolling averages of growth in, 58f
statistical method for, 37–39, 38f, 39f
of U.S., 15
Outright Monetary Transactions program, 83–84
Overall balance, as macroeconomic uncertainty measures, 202
Pacific Investment Management Company, 114
Papaioannou, E., 102
Parikh, Saumil H., 51
Per capita growth variables, weights in, 201
Persian gulf war, 46, 47, 84, 215
Peydró, J. L., 102
Policies
global recession coordination and messages on, 165
global recession (2009) uncertainty of, 5, 19, 162–63
for macroeconomic surveillance, 164–65, 166
uncertainty of, 121–23, 124f, 126, 127f, 128, 162–63
See also Economic policy; Fiscal policies; Monetary policies
Policy space, 164
Population, output and annual growth rates, 26–28, 27t
Portugal, 46, 138f
PPP. See Purchasing-power-parity
Prasad, E., 102
Private capital flows, 155
Public debt
in advanced economies, 132, 136, 137f
in emerging market economies, 137f
Public debt-to GDP ratio, 202
Purchasing-power-parity (PPP)
in aggregate and per capita variable weights, 201
evolution of, 207
in evolution of world output, 37, 38f
in GDP growth rate, 26–28, 27t
Real economy
in global recessions, 53, 55t, 57f, 58–59
in global recoveries, 71–75, 72f, 73t, 74t, 75f
Real interest rate, 202
Real short-term interest rates, 56t, 57f, 74t
Regional business cycle, 14, 21–22, 26, 167
Regression variables, 202
Reinhart, Carmen M., 103, 114
Residential investment, 199
Rest of the world per capita output growth, 202
Rogoff, Kenneth S., 1, 30–31, 67, 103, 114, 116
Romer, Christina, 129
Roubini, Nouriel, 69, 91
Savings and loan crisis, U.S., 46
Sectoral independence, 156
Secular stagnation, 114, 116
Securitization, 50
Short-term interest rates, 59, 200, 202
Slowdown (1998), 4
Slowdown (2001), 4
Social Security, 123
Sovereign debt markets, 83, 123, 133, 136
S&P. See Standard and Poor’s
Spain, 46, 49, 83, 138f
Stagflation, 45, 48, 211
Standard and Poor’s (S&P), 122
Statistical method, 28, 29, 37–39, 38f, 39f
Stock returns, uncertainty measured by, 122, 124f, 125f, 128f
Stokman, A. C. J., 102
Sub-Saharan Africa, 132
Summers, Lawrence, 114, 122
Supply shocks, 166
Sweden, 46, 49
Synchronization
activity variables in recession, 99f
in credit downturns, 99f, 100
downturn, 97f, 100
duration and amplitude of recession and recovery, 96–98, 97f
financial integration in, 101
financial linkages in, 93, 95–96, 101, 102
financial variables in recession, 99f
global business cycle, 101–2
globalization linked to, 93, 101–2
global recession, 82f, 93–99, 95f, 96f, 97f, 98f, 99f, 160
in global recession (1975), 93, 94–95, 211
in global recession (1982), 14, 95, 213
in global recession (1991), 95, 214
in global recession (2009), 5, 19, 47, 59, 93–96, 101, 161, 216
in global recovery, 96, 97–98, 99f
growth and, 149f
house prices in recession and downturns, 99f, 100
trade, 93, 95–96, 101, 102
Systemic risks, recession comparisons of, 49
Taylor, John B., 103, 116
Taylor rule, 140
Technology transfers, 155
Terms-of-trade fluctuations, 155
Terrones, M. E., 102, 118
Timelines, of global recessions and recoveries, 211–18
Trade
activity variables, 40f, 53
advanced economies activity variables for, 61f
emerging markets activity variables for, 61f
in global business cycle, 17, 17f
in global expansions, 86f, 87f
globalization of, 101
in global recession (2009), 60
global recovery activity variables in, 71, 72f, 73t, 75f
openness, 202
synchronization in, 93, 95–96, 101, 102
Trade channel, of global business cycle transmission, 154–55
Trade flow activity variables, 54f, 55t, 199
Turning points, 18, 19
in global recessions, 37–43
judgmental method for, 28–30, 39–43
in macroeconomics, 48–49
statistical method for, 28, 29, 37–39, 38f, 39f
Uncertainty, 119
in advanced economies, 121, 122–23, 126, 127, 128
credit and, 121, 126, 162
in euro area, 121, 122, 123, 124f, 126
in global business cycle, 123, 125f, 127–28
in global recession (2009), 121–22, 123, 126, 127, 128, 162
and global recessions, 121, 123, 125f, 126, 127–28, 128f
in global recoveries, 114, 121–22, 123, 125f, 127–28, 128f
in global recovery (post-2009), 162
growth impacted by, 123, 126–27, 127f
interest rates and, 123, 126
macroeconomics in, 121–23, 124f, 126–27, 128
measuring, 122–23
policy, 121–23, 124f, 126, 127f, 128, 162–63
stock returns for measuring, 122, 124f, 125f, 128f
in U.S., 121, 122, 123, 124f, 125f
Uncertainty, Business Cycles, and Growth, 226–27
Uncertainty measures
economic policy, 201
macroeconomic, 201
Unemployment
activity variables for, 40f, 54f, 55t, 199
activity variables in synchronized recession, 99f
advanced economies activity variables for, 61f
emerging market activity variables for, 61f
in financial crises, 106, 108, 109f, 111f
in global expansions, 85, 86f, 87f
in global recession (1982), 45
in global recession (1991), 46
in global recession (2009), 60, 61f, 85
in global recessions, 59
in global recoveries, 108, 111f
in global recovery (post-2009), 82
global recovery activity variables in, 72f, 73t, 75, 78f
United Kingdom
central bank assets of, 136f
debt-to-GDP ratios (2012), 138f
in ERM crisis (1992), 46
in global recession (1975), 45
in global recession (1982), 45
in global recession (2009), 83
government expenditures of, 133, 134f
interest rates in, 135f
output in global recoveries of, 113f
United States (U.S.)
central bank assets of, 136f
debt-to-GDP ratios (2012), 136, 138f
double-dip recession in, 212–13
fiscal and monetary policies as loose in, 5–6
in global recession (1975), 45
in global recession (1982), 45
in global recession (1991), 46, 48, 83
global recession (2009) centrality of, 47, 49–50, 83
global recessions historically impacted by, 13
government expenditures of, in global recession (2009), 131, 132–33, 133f, 134f, 136
interest rates in, 135f
mortgage markets of, 47
national recessions of, 43–44
output in global recoveries of, 113f
output of, in global business cycle, 15
output projections of, 115f
savings and loan crisis of, 46
secular stagnation in, 114, 116
uncertainty in, 121, 122, 123, 124f, 125f
Venezuela, 46
Viñals, José, 35
Volcker, Paul A., 11
Volcker disinflation, 44
Voss, G., 102
Walker, Andrew, 1
Weights, in aggregate and per capita variables
per capita growth variable, 201
PPP, 201
See also Market weights
Werning, I., 141
Wilkinson, Max, 145
Willard, L., 102
Wolf, Martin, 129
World Economic Outlook (IMF), 25, 30–31
World Series, of baseball, 13
Zero lower bound interest rates, 133–34, 135, 137, 141, 163