While the single market for financial services created dense interconnections of cross-border banking activities and obligations, the supervisory architecture remained mostly national before the 2008 crisis. Minimum harmonization of regulations and supervisory principles in the European Union (EU) was guided by the internationally agreed standards set by the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision in its Core Principles for Effective Banking Supervision, and implemented through EU directives. Supervisory handbooks and practices varied across the euro area countries, reflecting among other things different market structures, underlying laws, taxes, and accounting rules. The European Banking Authority, established at the start of 2011 following a recommendation of the De Larosiere High Level Group, was set up as a cooperative body to enable EU bank supervisors to coordinate the supervision of cross-border banks in the European Union; it contributed to harmonizing the regulatory and supervisory standard settings of the European Union, but it lacked power to enforce decisions.
The crisis uncovered a clear drawback of having a national approach to supervision in an integrated financial system. National authorities may unduly favor their own national banking system and economy, regardless of outward spillovers that lie beyond their mandates. In good times, national authorities may not be stringent or capable enough to limit the buildup of excesses. In bad times, they may encourage reductions in cross-border activities by their banks and the ring-fencing of liquidity, exacerbating financial fragmentation. Delays in resolving stresses would only exacerbate the eventual cost of crisis resolution. And because a bank’s distress can have adverse cross-border externalities, other countries may have no choice but to support those whose banking systems run into trouble.
The establishment of the Single Supervisory Mechanism (SSM), which is a precondition for the possibility of direct recapitalization of banks by the European Stability Mechanism (ESM), will help correct some of these above-mentioned cross-border distortions for the countries belonging to the banking union. It will also bring about uniformly high standards of supervision. The next section of this paper describes the regulation agreed by the European Union to establish the SSM. That is followed by a discussion of the principles for setting up the SSM. The next-to-last section identifies the main risks in the transition toward the banking union, and the final section discusses risk mitigation measures.
The Single Supervisory Mechanism Regulation
Initial Proposal
The European Commission published a draft regulation on September 12, 2012, conferring supervisory tasks on the European Central Bank (ECB) as part of a roadmap toward establishing a banking union. The tripartite agreement on the SSM regulation was reached on March 19, 2013, and the roadmap agreed upon by the EU Council in December 2012 was reaffirmed. The legislation is based on Article 127(6) of the European System of Central Banks/ECB statute and provides a clear mandate and broad powers to the ECB to perform supervision of all euro area banks. While the ECB may start carrying out supervisory tasks on any institution from adoption of the SSM regulation on September 10, 2013, the draft regulation proposes that banks receiving or requesting public financial assistance would be targeted first. Systemically important banks were to be subject to ECB supervisory activities from July 2013, and from January 2014 all other credit institutions were.1 Agreement on the SSM regulation by the European Parliament (EP) was reached on September 12, 2013, after transparency and accountability requirements were strengthened, and at the Council on October 15, 2013.
Main Elements
The regulation, which provides clear tasks and strong supervisory powers to the ECB, covers all credit institutions authorized in the euro area. The main elements are the following.
Risk-Based Approach
The transition is rapid, sequenced in a pragmatic manner, with a focus first on banks requiring public support, then on systemic banks. The SSM will come into operation one year after the legislation enters into force or when the ECB considers itself ready, whichever is later, after a comprehensive assessment of euro area banks is completed. The December 2012 EU Council agreement provided that when the ESM requests the ECB to take over direct supervision of a credit institution as precondition for direct recapitalization, the ECB may immediately assume its supervisory duties concerning this bank, regardless of the starting date of the SSM. On October 23, 2013, the ECB announced key features of the comprehensive assessment of the banking system, which will be concluded prior to assuming supervisory tasks in November 2014.
Coverage
The SSM would cover all credit institutions established in participating countries, although most tasks related to the supervision of those institutions considered “less significant” would normally be carried out by the national authorities. The criteria under which banks would be under the direct supervision of the ECB include size, importance to the economy of the European Union or of a member state, and significance of cross-border activities.2 The ECB appropriately retains the power to bring any bank under its direct supervision, if it deems necessary.
Mandate
The ECB is provided with a clear mandate for bank safety and soundness and financial stability.
Tasks and Powers
The ECB is provided with broad powers that are available to competent supervisory authorities under EU legislation. Broad investigatory and supervisory powers include enforcing compliance with prudential norms regarding its own funds, large exposure limits, liquidity requirements, leverage, disclosure requirements, licensing and withdrawal of authorization, assessing mergers and acquisitions, performing on-site inspections, requesting all necessary information, carrying out stress tests and assessment for public recapitalization, imposing macroprudential (capital and liquidity) buffers, conducting consolidated supervision and supervision of financial holding companies, carrying out early intervention tasks in relation to the listed prudential requirements, and assessing governance and internal capital adequacy processes.
Operational arrangements now need to be specified. These must ensure an adequate division of labor between national authorities and the ECB, make incentives compatible, and provide for appropriate information sharing within the SSM to underpin effective supervisory decision making at the supervisory board. The ECB is to adopt a detailed framework for the practical modalities of supervisory cooperation within the SSM.
Other EU Countries and Institutions
Nonparticipating member states will be able to enter into close cooperation with the ECB, under the condition that the national authority will abide by ECB guidelines and requests and provide all necessary information that the ECB may require. The ECB is tasked to coordinate and express a common position of euro area national supervisors at the Board of Supervisors and with the management of the European Banking Authority for issues relating to the supervisory tasks conferred on the ECB.
Governance
A Supervisory Board (aided by a Steering Committee) will be created to achieve appropriate governance and facilitate timely supervisory decision making by, or subject to the oversight and responsibility of, the Governing Council. The council agreement strengthened the governance arrangements relative to the European Commission proposal, reflecting concerns related to the separation between monetary policy and supervision (to minimize conflicts of interest between the two functions) and to ensure that non-euro area countries have a voice in the SSM (since non-euro area “opt-ins” cannot be represented on the ECB’s Governing Council). Strict differentiation between monetary policy and supervision will apply, including by strengthening the power of the supervisory board with a complex voting procedure that ensures representation of the non-euro area members.
Draft decisions of the Supervisory Board will follow a “silent procedure,” that is, they will be deemed adopted unless the Governing Council objects within a short period (10 days in normal times, and two days in stressful times). A mediation panel and a Steering Committee are to be created to help resolve disagreements and aid decisions. In practice, it will be important to balance the representation of national interests and public officials from the ECB in the governance structure of the SSM. It will also be important to ensure that the complexity of the set-up does not undermine effective and prompt supervisory decision making.
Accountability
The Governing Council, and in particular the chair of the supervisory board, is accountable to the Eurogroup and the European Parliament, among other things through an annual report on the execution of the ECB’s supervisory tasks and the transparency of its supervisory budget. The European Parliament added transparency and accountability requirements stipulated in an Inter-institutional Agreement between the ECB and the EP. These will include, in particular, providing the ECON committee of the EP with comprehensive and meaningful records of the proceedings of the Supervisory Board to enable an understanding of the discussions, including an annotated list of decisions. Moreover, the ECB is subject to internal and external audits, also by the European Union Court of Auditors, and judicial scrutiny by the European Union Court of Justice. Both the ECB and the national authorities are responsible for the banks under their direct supervision, although the ECB is responsible for the effective and consistent functioning of the SSM.
Role of National Authorities
National authorities will prepare and implement ECB acts under the oversight of the ECB, perform day-to-day supervision activities, and directly supervise banks not classified as “significant.” They will remain exclusively responsible for consumer protection and anti-money laundering tasks, receiving notifications from credit institutions related to the right of establishment, supervising the activities of the branches of third countries’ credit institutions, and supervising payments services.
Macroprudential Policies
The ECB will be able to impose capital buffers, such as a countercyclical capital buffer, in addition to capital requirements and any other measures aimed at addressing systemic or macroprudential risks as specified in EU acts, such as the legislative package that yielded the Fourth Capital Requirement Directive and Capital Requirement Regulation. The Council agreement provided both national authorities and the ECB with powers to make use of macroprudential instruments, in close collaboration with each other, and included specific reporting to national parliaments to strengthen accountability. But the ECB powers are limited to those specified in the relevant EU directives. Either party that takes such a step needs to inform and hear the other party ahead of time. In practice, cooperation will be critical to ensure the coherence and effectiveness of measures.
Resources
Supervision could be financed partly by risk-based levies on credit institutions.
Assessment
There are many positive aspects to the regulation, which mentions all the elements necessary to make the SSM effective. Among these elements is the allowance that the ESM can request the ECB to take over direct supervision of a credit institution as a precondition for direct recapitalization, regardless of the starting date of the SSM—direct bank recapitalization by the ESM is critical for stabilization in the near term.3 This ambitious though risk-based approach will require rapidly putting into place the resources and frameworks needed for effectiveness. The proposal specifies a clear mandate and accountability of the ECB and appropriately confers upon it broad investigatory and supervisory powers. Moreover, the proposed fast adoption (by June 2013) of the draft directives on regulation—the Deposit Guarantee Schemes and Bank Recovery and Resolution—was a welcome step.4 The call for a single resolution mechanism is welcome, including the need for appropriate and explicit backstops.5
Greater Clarity Needed
However, further clarity is needed on a number of matters, including how the delegation of supervisory tasks and the associated control will be realized in practice. Greater clarity is also needed concerning macroprudential oversight, the powers to assume national discretion as defined in the Capital Requirement Regulation, the allocation of powers to intervene and to enforce administrative sanctions and trigger resolutions (alongside a single resolution authority to be established), home-host supervisory arrangements for non-EU banks, and the interaction with the European Banking Authority. While Article 127(6) ESCB/ECB Statute allows the European Union to confer some supervisory tasks on the ECB, strengthening the legal basis of the new framework with a view to minimizing litigation risk may require changes to the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union—hereafter the EU Treaty—over time.6
The regulation could risk becoming an incomplete framework. While it sketches a process for swiftly implementing an SSM, it lacks a roadmap for reaching a common safety net, which will be essential for depositor confidence and to weaken the sovereign—bank links.
Moreover, greater clarity in the agreement would be useful to specify how and when a single resolution authority (essential to complement the SSM) could be established, as it would be conditional on the adoption of the directives on deposit guarantee schemes (DGS Directive) and bank recovery and resolution (BRRD). In that respect, the European Commission proposal for an SRM, published on July 10, 2013, is a welcome step forward, but there are areas of concern and hurdles are significant (see Chapter 12).
Clarity is also needed to know whether the implementation of an SSM would require changes in national legislation, including banking laws.
Principles for the Design of a Single Supervisory Mechanism
Cross-Country Lessons
In federations such as the United States and Canada, banking supervision, safety nets, and resolution are all established at the federal or central level.7 Different models of organization may be chosen, whether delegation or full centralization. The Board of Governors of the U.S. Federal Reserve, for example, delegates supervisory tasks to regional reserve banks, with strong internal governance mechanisms, while the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC), a supervisory and resolution authority in the United States, operates as a fully centralized body. The experience of the United States and Canada demonstrates that supervision and resolution functions can be centralized in a monetary union. It also suggests the clear benefits of having in place mechanisms to ensure effective coordination and information flows between sister agencies (including between regulators and the resolution agency), the benefits of creating overlaps rather than living with gaps, the need for strong corrective action mechanisms and early intervention, and the value of having horizontal checks and balances between sister supervisory bodies.
International Standards
The “Core Principles for Effective Supervision” or Basel Core Principles (BCPs)8 issued by the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision are the accepted minimum standards for sound practices in prudential bank regulation and supervision. These principles provide guidance for designing and assessing the new SSM for the euro area.
Other Considerations
Designing an effective supervisory mechanism for the euro area has added complications. The ECB will be formally accountable for supervision but will have to rely on competencies and resources at the national level. This is not just because of resource constraints in the near term, but also differences in legal, accounting and tax frameworks, as well as differing local language, business and supervisory cultures, and local knowledge and relationships that are important to assess bank activities. In such an environment, the center will need to delegate, but also monitor supervisory operations to contain reputational risks. The design of this interaction between the center and national authorities, of the decentralization and delegation of tasks, and the allocation of powers between the two levels will play a key role in achieving effective supervision.
Preconditions and Prerequisites
Preconditions
According to the BCPs, a number of preconditions for sound banking supervision must be met in the longer term. A clear framework for financial stability policy must be in place, one that includes the provision of strong macroprudential oversight and, for the sake of crisis management and resolution, the provision of ways to deal effectively with bank failure and minimize disruptions. An appropriate common safety net is essential to deal with risks to confidence in the financial system and contagion to sound banks while minimizing distortions.9 Some preconditions are beyond the jurisdiction of supervisors, and some elements are not yet in place at the euro area level. For example, resolution regimes (and safety nets) remain national, and in most countries they need to be strengthened to be aligned with the Financial Stability Board’s “Key Attributes for Effective Resolution.”10
Prerequisites
A set of prerequisites is essential to establish a sound basis for the SSM. The supervisory mechanism should have operational independence consistent with its statutory responsibilities, legal protection for its supervisors, transparent processes, sound governance, and adequate resources, and it should be accountable for the discharge of its duties. Among these, the following considerations are noteworthy.
Objectives and mandates. As supervisor, the ECB should ensure the safety and soundness of credit institutions, while adopting a systemic approach to financial stability that helps preserve the integrity of the single market for financial services. Under the EU Treaty, the primary objective of the ECB is price stability, and its secondary objective is to support the general economic policy objectives of the European Union, such as a high level of employment and sustainable and non-inflationary growth. Involving the ECB in supervision will give it access to supervisory information in support of its monetary policy and lender-of-last-resort functions and will also provide the ECB with more information to separate illiquid from insolvent banks. Housing both supervision and monetary policy under one roof can also lead to difficult choices when monetary policy decisions impact the soundness of important banks. Therefore, a revision of ECB objectives through EU Treaty changes may be warranted to provide greater clarity with respect to the interaction between the ECB’s monetary mandate in the monetary union and its supervisory mandate in the banking union. It may also be warranted to explicitly specify that the ECB’s supervisory mandate includes financial stability and macroprudential oversight.
Operational independence and legal protection. Operational independence regarding the ECB’s supervisory mandate derives legally from the ECB/ESCB statutes. But bringing supervision under the umbrella of the ECB creates risks to the ECB’s independence (and hard-won reputation), given the added potential for political interference. Modifications to the Treaties should be considered to safeguard the ECB’s independence in its supervisory mandate as well and to strengthen legal protections for supervisors.
Governance. The Governing Council is the decision-making body of the ECB, and is responsible for supervisory tasks according to Article 127(6) of the EU Treaty. Sound governance will be crucial to ensure early identification of risks and timely and effective decision making in the interest of the whole banking union (and not of individual countries). Because supervisory decisions have distributive implications, the decision making body may have to adopt a mechanism that protects effective and timely decision-making (e.g., to ensure the “will to act”).
▪ A one-member-one-vote rule would ensure that regional interests are better accounted for and would provide a balance to large countries’ influence. On the other hand, allocating voting rights based on economic size would align countries’ rights with the relative importance of their economies. A balance between the two could be considered (perhaps a uniform set of basic votes, combined with voting rights relative to economic size). Consideration should be given to providing voting rights to non-euro area members that join the supervisory mechanism.
▪ Robust firewalls between monetary policy and supervision would protect the independence and credibility of each function of the ECB, ensure the confidentiality of supervisory information, and help limit potential conflicts of interest while ensuring that synergies between the two functions are exploited. (Conflicts of interest may arise when interest rate policies impact weak banks, or when the lender-of-last-resort function safeguards financial stability but risks lending to insolvent banks). In the United Kingdom, for example, the supervisory function is being established as a subsidiary of the central bank.
▪ One way to ensure swift decision making based on delegation is to establish a Supervisory Board within the ECB, assisted by a Steering Committee and a Supervisory Department, which could be given supervisory tasks and related decisions (as under the European Union regulation establishing the SSM). Under this model, which was agreed to by the European Union Council in December 2012, monetary policy and supervision decisions would be reconciled at the Governing Council. Alternatively, a separate body from the Governing Council could be established to provide stronger firewalls and ensure full representation of non-euro area countries. However, establishing a separate body in this way could make coordination and synergies more complex to achieve, could be legally complex to establish, and would require a change to the EU Treaty.
▪ Additional considerations relate to the delegation of supervisory tasks to national authorities and the need to establish clear chains of command and adequate incentives.
Accountability. Independence must be complemented with accountability to European citizens. Pursuant to the EU Treaty, the ECB’s standard monetary policy reporting is addressed to the European Parliament, the European Union Council, the European Commission, and the European Council. Given the fiscal implications of supervision, stronger (such as more frequent) reporting to the European Parliament and to the euro-group could be envisaged for the supervisory function. The EU regulation establishing the SSM also added accountability to national parliaments.
Resources. Any supervisor needs secure and adequate funding. Pragmatism will need to govern decisions related to funding and implementation, both in the near term and in the steady state, but the resources obtained should allow the ECB to build adequate capacity while protecting it from influence by national authorities or the industries. In particular, the ECB will need to establish highly trained and independent staff at the center, including but not only from national authorities, to be able to directly supervise a subset of banks (including globally systemic banks). In this regard, the challenge of developing the requisite competence at the ECB and building credibility in supervision should not be underestimated. At the same time, national supervisors must retain sufficient resources to perform their tasks. Funding models could consider combinations of industry levies (based on the size and the risk profile of supervised banks) and central bank support (seigniorage) that balance these considerations, provided that budgetary transfers from the ECB’s monetary policy leg (seigniorage income) to its supervisory leg do not hamper the execution of its monetary mandate.
Bank Coverage
The SSM will cover all of the roughly 6,000 credit institutions licensed in the eurozone, although only some 130 “significant” banks (accounting for about 85 percent of total bank assets) will be under the direct supervision of the ECB. The following are among the key reasons why this is so.
Sovereign-Bank Links
The motivations for forming the banking union include weakening, or severing, sovereign—bank links and limiting the buildup of systemic risk. Large and cross-border banks should be included. But, as the experience of Spain and others has demonstrated, small banks with correlated risks can represent a major fiscal risk to the sovereign and a systemic risk to the euro area. Covering only “systemic” banks (with the difficult decision of demarcating systemic from nonsystemic banks), while potentially easier to implement technically and politically, would only partially address these risks.
Competitive Distortions
A banking union covering only a subset of euro area banks would have implications for the level playing field and could encourage regulatory arbitrage between centrally and nationally supervised banks.
Uneven Distribution of Costs and Benefits
Because banking size and activities differ greatly across euro area countries, a partial banking union that covered only a subset of large banks would benefit some countries more than others and would therefore have implications for the distribution of costs and benefits of the banking union across countries.
BCP Principles, Tasks, and Powers
Principles
To ensure effective supervision, bank supervisors should have clear responsibilities and objectives for each authority involved in supervision (following BCP No. 1). To the extent that the ECB will be a supervisor in its own right, it will have to comply with the BCPs. Assessing the SSM will also require discerning how effective it is to have a supranational setup sharing some responsibilities with national authorities and delegating some of the tasks. The effectiveness of the SSM, which will be the responsibility of the ECB to ensure, will depend, among other things, on the functions delegated, the capacity constraints, and the accountability and control mechanisms used.
Tasks
The ECB should have clear responsibilities over the life cycle of banks to fulfill its safety and soundness mandate. This implies that the ECB should be tasked with authorizing banks; assessing and authorizing mergers and acquisitions; ensuring compliance with prudential requirements; imposing additional buffers (including countercyclical and systemic buffers); applying requirements regarding internal bank governance and processes; imposing all measures determined necessary to address, early on, banks’ unsafe and unsound practices; carrying out stress tests; conducting consolidated supervision; and taking on tasks related to home-host arrangements for cross-border banks. The EU regulation establishing the SSM broadly confers these tasks on the ECB.
Powers
To carry out its tasks effectively, possibly including the solo supervision of a set of banks (without delegation to national authorities), the ECB should have adequate formal powers to do all of the following:
Enforce minimum prudential standards and any restrictions prescribed by the supervisory review, including increasing the prudential requirements for individual banks and banking groups based on their risk profile and systemic importance (BCP No. 1 and No. 16).
Request information and have full access to banks’ boards, management, and staff records, and perform general investigations and onsite inspections (BCP No. 1 and No. 10).
Require all necessary early corrective actions to address unsafe and unsound practices or activities that could pose risks to banks or to the banking system, and prevent banks from breaching standards (BCP No. 11).
Ring-fence banks from the actions of parent companies, subsidiaries, parallel-owned banking structures, and other related entities in matters that could impair the safety and soundness of a bank or the banking system (BCP No. 11).
Take measures and sanctions in line with the gravity of the situation, including revoking licenses (BCP No. 11).
Determine supervisory plans (BCP No. 8).
Review, reject, and impose conditions on transfers of ownership and major acquisitions (BCP No. 7).
Perform consolidated supervision, including application of prudential standards for an entire group (BCP No. 12).
Withdraw licenses and collaborate with relevant authorities in deciding when and how to effect orderly resolution (BCP No. 11).
Identify and assess the buildup of risks, trends, and concentrations within and across the system, in coordination with other relevant authorities, and address proactively any serious threat to the stability of the banking system (BCPs No. 8 and No. 9). (See below on macroprudential responsibilities.)
Formal versus Real Powers
Distinguishing formal from real power is important. Because supervisory incentives are skewed at the national level, it is essential that the ECB has real powers (requiring adequate resources) and does not simply validate (and take responsibility for) decisions proposed by national authorities. A prerequisite is to confer formal supervisory powers on the ECB, and ensure monitoring of supervisory tasks during a transitional phase, since real powers may continue to reside partly with the national authority until supervisory decision-making and capacity are in place at the ECB. Having a mechanism for the effective delegation and monitoring of supervisory tasks is also important in the steady state when a common backstop is in place.
Ensuring Real Powers
To ensure that national incentives are aligned with those of the center, and that the center has real powers in the conduct of supervision, further arrangements could be considered. For instance, the ECB could be provided with the ability to immediately conduct peer reviews and joint inspections, including lead supervisors from other countries or the ECB, with cross-country teams. The ECB could use a range of metrics, including solvency and liquidity stress tests, to discern which banks warrant particularly close attention or review by the ECB.
Design of a Delegated Supervisory Mechanism
“Hub and Spokes” Model
Since all banks are to be included in the SSM, a division of labor between the center and national authorities is necessary, while all information should be shared among supervisory bodies of the SSM. Both of the two extreme models of the division of labor—full centralization and full decentralization—are neither practical nor desirable. A centralized system is not an option, given that supervisory knowledge and resources remain at the national levels. A decentralized mechanism, in which the center validates the decisions taken locally, is not desirable either, particularly when common backstops are fully in place at the euro area level, since consistency cannot be assured in the quality of the local implementation of supervisory practices. Conferring formal responsibilities on the ECB without adequate enforcement power could result in weak supervision and put the ECB’s reputation at risk.
Steady-State Framework
Common risk-based supervision in a supranational setting. A common analytical approach should be agreed to and applied to the SSM, comprising the ECB and national supervisory bodies. A risk-based framework would attribute a risk classification to each banking organization within the euro area. Based on this methodology, the ECB would develop a protocol for supervision and establish the frequency, level, and type of supervisory action to be conducted. The level of centralization and intrusiveness and the mix of multinational members in supervisory teams would be made proportionate to the supervisory assessment of risk. The model would also define a nonrigid perimeter of institutions subject to supplementary intense scrutiny by the ECB, allowing a fluid response to emerging information.
Principles. The framework should create a coherent and consistent supervisory mechanism with final decisions taken at the center. To promote incentive compatibility in the delegated supervisory mechanism, the extent to which the tasks or the supervision of a set of banks is divided between national authorities and the center could be derived from a set of principles, such as these:
The systemic dimension. The center will have a comparative advantage in adopting a systemic approach to supervision and internalizing cross-border externalities inherent to the supervision of systemically important financial institutions (SIFIs).
Local knowledge and know-how. National supervisors may have better specific knowledge about individual banks, and could therefore be more effective in supervising smaller banks.
Risks of regulatory capture. National supervisors may be more likely to favor national banks, which would create distortions that can have financial stability consequences for the region.
Discretion in decision making. The degree of delegation must decrease with the degree of discretion associated with specific tasks.
Consistency of delegation. When tasks are delegated, the consistency of approach among national authorities and between the national authority and the center is essential.
Bank classifications. An initial framework would classify each bank on the basis of size, interconnections, complexity, cross-border orientation, and whether the bank requires common funding, as follows.
Group I: Global systemically important financial institutions, banks identified as systemic for the euro area, and banks requiring (or nearly requiring) direct recapitalization by the ESM.
Group II: Banks of intermediate size, simple but potentially systemic for their sovereign (either individually or as a group).
Group III: Very small banks unlikely to be systemic or to require access to a common backstop.
Delegation by group. The degree of delegation of day-to-day supervision by the ECB would vary by group. Group I banks would be under the direct and intrusive supervision of the ECB, which would maintain an on-site supervisory presence, with a mix of international supervisors in teams led by an ECB supervisor. Group II could be supervised mainly by national authorities, which would maintain an on-site presence, with supervision performed by teams of mixed nationalities appointed and compensated by their home countries (e.g., for governance purposes), and off-site monitoring by the ECB and the local supervisor. Day-to-day supervision of Group III banks would be fully delegated to the national authority, but the ECB would be entitled and ready to request participation equivalent to the other groups at any time (e.g., if a group of banks became systemic because of correlated exposures). For all groups, off-site monitoring should be carried out by the ECB and the local supervisor. The SSM regulation defines two categories of banks—“significant” banks, which are brought under the direction supervision of the ECB, and “nonsignificant” banks, which remain under the supervision of national authorities—which provides a system of delegation by groups of banks.
Delegation by task. Tasks that are more difficult to standardize, that require more intrusion and discretionary decisions, or that are more critical for the system as a whole or are more subject to political interference would be less conducive to delegation. National authorities could perform day-to-day assessments of banks’ soundness and carry out some examinations (provided they are consistency with the allocation of tasks by groups of banks). The assessment and monitoring of internal risk models could be performed locally, under general guidance from the ECB. But supervisory reviews, licensing, corrective actions, inspections, and decisions about imposing higher individual or macroprudential buffers and about sanctioning and initiating resolutions should be less amenable to delegation. Also undertaken by the center or by supervisors of mixed nationalities would be approvals for the use of advanced approaches, approvals of certain capital instruments, model validations, and thematic/horizontal inspections. The ECB should be closely involved in stress tests to identify pockets of vulnerability among euro area banks and in performing (or requesting from national authorities) intrusive examinations, approving mergers and acquisitions, and initiating early corrective actions, if needed.
Escalation of decision making. Supervisory responses should be escalated appropriately. Preliminary recommendations to address problems detected during supervision would need to be left behind by each inspection team, regardless of their level of risk. For banks with a higher risk classification, such as I and II above, review by the center would be required. For less systemic banks, the national level would implement corrective action and only elevate the issue to the center if concerns had not been addressed by the institution in the established timeframe. As a first step in escalation, inspection reports could be shared with different teams for a peer review.
Two-dimensional delegation. The allocation of tasks within the supervisory mechanism between the ECB and the national authorities could be based on a flexible approach, combining delegation by bank category and by task, with tasks escalating to the center as institutions become more systemic and tasks become more critical to financial stability and subject to greater discretion.
Transitional Stages
Steps toward the steady-state supervisory mechanism include these three stages:
First stage. In a first, urgent phase of the transition, the ECB must be provided with the full legal powers and protections needed to perform its supervisory tasks, including the powers to impose a complete range of corrective actions and initiate resolution. An embryo off-site supervisory structure and a decision-making body must be created at the ECB; standardized templates of information should be developed and supervisory data should be shared; outstanding legal uncertainties must be clarified (e.g., regarding the respective responsibilities of the ECB and national authorities). The centralized analysis should be used to create the first thresholds for centralized supervisory actions, and the classification of banks should be established. A balance sheet assessment of the most important euro area banks must be performed before the SSM becomes effective; it will be key to establishing the credibility of the ECB.
Second stage. In a second stage, the ECB should develop a consistent risk-based supervisory approach, establishing protocols that would specify, for example, the frequency, level, and type of supervisory action, the levels of centralization and intrusiveness, and the mix of multinational members in supervisory teams. It should also establish the characteristics of supervisory processes that will prevail in the steady state. The development of common protocols for corrective action should, ideally, be front-loaded, including protocols for the minimum actions by supervisors. Common timeframes for banks to address detected deficiencies and common settings for the escalation of corrective actions and sanctions should also, ideally, be established up-front.
Third stage. In a third stage, systemically important banks and, more generally, banks higher in the supervisory risk matrix would be brought under the direct supervision of the ECB, and common protocols and design of the system of delegation would be finalized.11 When the ECB started supervising systemically important banks, international teams would start to perform risk assessments of each institution and develop supervisory plans for them. These plans would identify the areas that would need to involve mixed-nationality teams and would estimate the work force and skills needed at headquarters and at the national level. The ECB would decide the most suitable approach for the banks, including whether there was the need for a permanent presence, for intensive diagnostic on-site inspections before a regular cycle of on-site programs could be restored, or for the use of mixed-teams only for the supervisory review process and authorization for advanced approaches.
Macroprudential Oversight Within the Single Supervisory Mechanism
The Case for Centralization
The ECB should be given the responsibility and powers to perform macroprudential oversight in the euro area and involving national authorities.
Benefits. The ECB should act as a macroprudential oversight institution for euro area countries, with binding powers to use macroprudential instruments if it deems that necessary. The high degree of financial integration calls for a coherent approach to macroprudential policies, one that internalizes cross-border externalities and addresses information and home-host coordination problems when using macroprudential tools. Note, however, that the centralization of decision making does not imply a homogeneity of policies across countries. Policies would still need to be adapted flexibly to macrofinancial developments in particular countries or asset markets, and they would need to be applied to all financial institutions active in these countries or markets.
Costs and limitations. There are costs to building capacity for designing macroprudential policies tailored to specific country conditions. But given the ECB’s established expertise in financial stability, these costs might not be high. There could be an overlap with the role of the European Systemic Risk Board that would require some coordination. There could also be a risk that taking on macroprudential responsibilities could subject the ECB to political pressures or disagreements with national authorities, adding rigidities to the framework. Because the ECB mandate does not include insurance firms or securities markets, it would need to collaborate with competent authorities whenever such institutions were involved.
The Case for a Mixed Model
A pragmatic approach, as provided under the SSM regulation, may be a mixed model that would involve both the ECB and national authorities to ensure effective macroprudential oversight of the euro area, as implied in the legislative proposal for a SSM. In particular, the ECB could be conferred power to impose a systemic or countercyclical capital buffer if national authorities did not act, thus countering the lack of “will to act.” Other tools not included in the Fourth Capital Requirement Directive/Capital Requirement Regulation, such as limits on debt-to-income and loan-to-value ratios, could also be provided to the ECB when a common macroprudential toolkit was in place. Thus, the ECB would be provided a macroprudential mandate for the euro area as a whole and for individual countries.
Alternatively, if national authorities retained some macroprudential policies, as foreseen in the Council agreement, the use of tools might have to be coordinated and validated by the ECB, and mechanisms might need to be designed to resolve conflicts of interest that could arise between national authorities and the ECB (e.g., the ECB could be more prone to act than national authorities, who may be subject to political pressures).
The Risks of Proceeding With a Single Supervisory Mechanism in a Time of Crisis
This section identifies the main risks in the transition toward the banking union.
European Union Features that Constrain the Single Supervisory Mechanism
A range of risks can be ascribed to the design features of the European Union that constrain the construction of the SSM. Following are five of them.
The European Union Setup
The European Union can act only in those areas where it has exclusive or shared competencies, or can support the actions of the member states, as provided under the Treaty. When competencies are shared with EU member states (such as the single market for financial services), under the principle of subsidiarity the European Union may act only insofar as its objectives can be better achieved at the European Union level than at the member state level.
Legal Contours of the SSM
Regarding the supervisory sphere, Article 127 (6) of the EU Treaty provides that specific supervisory tasks may be conferred upon the ECB and therefore presumes the continued existence of “competent authorities of member states.” This implies a division of responsibilities between the ECB and national competent authorities and, consequently, constraints on the design of the SSM.
Governance
The governance arrangements of the ECB are not designed for a supervisory function, and country coverage is restricted to euro area member states. The Governing Council is the ultimate decision-making body of the ECB, as enshrined in the EU Treaty, including for any supervisory tasks conferred upon the ECB under Article 127 (6). The governance structure of the ECB hinges on its monetary mandate, since the Governing Council comprises the governors of the national central banks and the members of the Executive Board; heads of other national supervisory agencies cannot be part of the Governing Council. Given such predetermined design, a number of constraints, as well as legal, repu-tational, and implementation risks, may arise from the assumption by the ECB of supervisory tasks.
Legal Responsibility
Any ECB internal body established for a supervisory task, as foreseen under the draft SSM regulations, cannot have decision-making powers, which are ultimately vested with the Governing Council. Any delegation of activities to a supervisory board—composed of national and ECB representatives—cannot override such a setup.
Delegated Decision Making
The Governing Council will have to process a wealth of information on short deadlines. While being accountable for all supervisory decisions, the Governing Council will scarcely have the capacity to analyze each case brought to its attention. Rather, the Governing Council will validate the decisions prepared by the Supervisory Board, following a “silent procedure,” that is, the decisions will be deemed adopted unless the Governing Council objects within a short period (10 days in normal times, and two days in stressful times). The following risks are of potential concern.
There is a risk that, within the supervisory board or Governing Council, decision makers may not be fully independent from national interests.
There is a risk of conflicts of interest between the monetary policy function and the supervisory function. Given that the ECB Governing Council must pursue its primary objective of price stability, it may take decisions that from a supervisory perspective are not optimal.
Member states that are not part of the euro area but join the SSM cannot be represented in the Governing Council, which will nonetheless take decisions affecting them. This may open the door to conflicts and accountability problems within the SSM. At the same time, if such states have the possibility to opt out of decisions taken by the Governing Council, the level playing field of the single market may be tilted.
Transitional Risks
Bringing all euro area banks under the supervision of the ECB is a major task and entails many practical difficulties and risks. A swift transition to covering all banks would reduce the risk of an entrenchment of regulatory forbearance between the time the decision to create an SSM was announced and the actual transfer of supervisory responsibilities. An effective SSM would also make it possible to start direct ESM recapitalization of banks; on the other hand, there is a possibility that specific banks in need of direct recapitalization by the ESM could be brought under the SSM before it is generally effective. Unless supervisory capacity at the center is established quickly and incentives at the national and central levels are well aligned, there would be risks of information loss, supervisory drift, and regulatory forbearance. However, the challenge of putting in place an effective capacity at the center should not be underestimated, making it worthwhile to emphasize the urgency of efforts to plan for and ensure success under a realistic but ambitious timeline.
Taking on responsibilities in the crisis carries its own risks. By definition, in a crisis banks are likely to be weak and credibility in institutions is likely to be low. While it would be desirable for the ECB to conduct a relicensing exercise before taking responsibility for a bank, this will not be possible. Thus, the ECB may have to take early action against problem banks while its own expertise is not yet fully established and its credibility in supervision is not yet assured.
Risks in the Division of Responsibilities between the Center and the National Authorities
Serious risks could derive from the division of responsibilities between the ECB and the national authorities, particularly during the transition.
Banks under Direct ECB Supervision
To ensure stability, it is essential that the ECB be able to identify risks at an early stage, including for banks that will not be under its direct supervision. The regulation of the SSM specifies a set of criteria to identify which banks are “significant” for the euro area and should therefore be directly supervised by the ECB, and which banks should remain under the direct supervision of national authorities. These criteria relate to the importance of cross-border activities, domestic and EU significance, and size. Moreover, the ECB will be able to designate as “significant” and bring under its direct oversight institutions (or groups of institutions) that could jeopardize the stability of the euro area financial system—for instance through their impact on the balance sheet of the respective sovereign. The SSM regulation safeguards the capacity of the ECB to investigate all credit institutions and bring them under its direct oversight at any time. Nevertheless, at least during the transition stage, the process of taking over credit institutions from national authorities may be lengthy and unwieldy and could therefore allow risks to build up.
Identification of Macroprudential Risks
The ECB will have to be able to identify pockets of growing systemic risks and take action at an early stage. A purely microsupervisory approach is insufficient when banks are interconnected or take correlated exposures and also when localized macroeconomic conditions affect a specific region or a specific type of institution. Thus, the microprudential analysis will need to be complemented with a macroprudential approach to risk assessment.
Incentives under Decentralized Supervision
National authorities may be biased toward favoring the national banking system. Risk-based supervision will always rely, to some extent, on supervisory judgment, and the ECB may rely on such qualitative assessment by national authorities. Yet national authorities may tend to be too optimistic about their respective banks, thus increasing the risk of supervisory slippage at the SSM level. The accountability mechanisms could reinforce these incentives to the extent that the ECB would be responsible for the effective and consistent functioning of the SSM and for the supervision of “significant banks,” while the National Competent Authorities under the instruction of the ECB would be responsible for the direct supervision of all other banks. The risk could be compounded during the transition due to the very limited resources available to the ECB, including resources to control actions at the national level. As a result, the ECB’s ability to reach its own supervisory judgment on the soundness of institutions’ risk management could be put at risk during the transition.
National Supervisory Practices, Frameworks, and Enforcement
In practice, the ECB will need to operate with recourse to the national supervisors for ongoing supervision, especially on-site supervision. Moreover, in order to apply nonpecuniary administrative sanctions—different from the remedial measures provided under the draft SSM regulation—the ECB will need to instruct national authorities, which will implement the sanctioning actions according to national laws. Recent Financial Sector Assessment Programs in EU countries have identified supervisory laws and practices—and especially enforcement practices—that differ from country to country and diverge from international best practices and standards. Thus, ensuring uniformity of treatment may be difficult.
National Resolution Regimes
The ECB will be given powers to withdraw a license, but until an SRM based on a strong single resolution authority is established, the SSM may have to operate with multiple regimes and authorities. This will entail additional operational complexity because the ECB, local supervisors, resolution agencies, and DGSs will have to interact both in the preparation and validation of recovery and resolution plans for SIFIs and in decisions leading to the possible withdrawal of bank licenses. Lack of a credible resolution framework could also impede timely decision making by leaving national authorities to deal with the fiscal consequences of others’ supervisory decisions.
Operational Risks
Perhaps most immediately, the authorities need to be alert to operational risks. Establishing a critical new authority over the euro area and beyond without providing sufficient resources, both financial and human, would be self-defeating and would jeopardize the entire exercise.
Capacity, Expertise, and Resources of the ECB
Currently, the ECB has impressive human capital to conduct monetary policy and monitor financial stability in the euro area, but it has no supervisory expertise. Overall supervisory resources in the euro area are fixed in the near term; it will take time to build supervisory resources, skills, and expertise at the center without depleting the local level of its own needed experts. Although the dates for being operationally ready have been reasonably set in the SSM regulation, there is a risk that the ECB may be pressured to operate as a single supervisor before it is adequately resourced.
Data Management and Information Sharing
To operate, the ECB system and staff must be able to receive, store, and analyze large amounts of confidential information, and they must also be able to translate these analyses into supervisory operations and decisions. Establishing systems and internal mechanisms to handle these tasks will be demanding.
Mitigation of Risks
As the SSM is put into effect, comprehensive risk mitigation should be a central complement. Following are measures to mitigate risks related to the establishment of the SSM under EU Treaty constraints.
Addressing Risks While Establishing the Single Supervisory Mechanism
Harmonized Legislation
Agreement to and adoption of harmonized legislation should proceed swiftly, as should its transposition into national laws. From this perspective, it is important not only to adopt the Capital Requirement Regulation/Fourth Capital Requirement Directive, but to build a uniform single supervisory rule-book in the European Union. The rule-book should go beyond the necessary harmonization prompted by the Capital Requirement Regulation/Fourth Capital Requirement Directive, the BRRD, and the deposit insurance directive. The European Banking Authority can play a positive role here in ensuring that supervisory practices are harmonized.
Effective Governance
A steering committee, supporting the work of the Supervisory Board, will play a useful role in the chain of supervisory tasks that could avoid cumbersome processes at the higher level. The establishment of internal and external monitoring mechanisms or “watchdogs” would also enhance checks and balances, contribute to better scrutiny, and incentivize the effectiveness of the ECB supervision. Effectiveness could also be enhanced by a more significant representation of permanent, full-time officials or independent experts at the Supervisory Board who are not linked to national interests. In time, the governance structure could be buttressed by measures that would require a treaty change—for instance, allowing non-euro area countries to have representation in the Governing Council when deciding supervisory matters.
Accountability Mechanisms
Additional accountability mechanisms, such as the possibility of reporting to national parliaments in addition to the European Parliament, are provided in the SSM regulation. However, the respective responsibilities of the ECB and the NCAs should be clarified to help make the system of decentralization incentives compatible, given the ECB’s ultimate responsibility for ensuring the effectiveness of the SSM.
Addressing Risks during Transition
Risk Mapping Exercise
The ECB should receive from the national supervisors the risk assessments and local risk classifications of the local banks as soon as possible. Based on this information, the ECB would map banking risks and target supervisory actions accordingly—for instance, by requiring national supervisors to undertake additional due diligence on specific portfolios and capital planning, or by providing information on the availability of additional shareholder resources.
Asset Quality Assessment
The ECB must undertake an asset quality assessment or review for a set of banks as they are brought under the SSM. The exercise, which would need to be conducted with the involvement of the national supervisors and third parties, should follow harmonized guidance on how such assessments must be conducted, as issued by European Banking Authority, in coordination with efforts to review and harmonize data and relevant definitions (e.g., of nonperforming loans, provisioning rules, and risk weights). Such an asset quality review is critical to establish the credibility of the ECB as a supervisor. To ensure success, it should be based on a forward looking framework that incorporates risks to growth and is clearly communicated in advance of the exercise; it should cover all banks that will come under the direct supervision of the ECB.
Moreover, independent third-party involvement (preferably from the private sector), along with the ECB, the European Banking Authority for the stress tests, and national authorities, would be essential to ensure full credibility and transparency of the exercise. In the absence of such involvement, prospects for raising private capital would be jeopardized. There should be an agreed strategy on how to address capital shortfalls to avoid creating uncertainty and procyclical deleveraging. This would encourage a realistic write-down of assets and full recognition of losses, which would encourage private capital. Absent such a strategy, there is a high risk that the asset quality review (which will be followed by stress tests) would be counterproductive: if banks shed assets to preemptively build buffers, this could reinforce fragmentation rather than resolve it. The incentives to conduct a thorough and credible exercise could be distorted, whereas a clear plan would encourage a realistic write-down of assets and recognition of losses, which would help attract private capital. In the event that both private capital and fiscal space were limited, clarity about a common backstop would be critical to avoid reigniting adverse bank—sovereign links and to improve the incentives to recognize losses. The ECB announced the methodology for the comprehensive assessment of euro area banks on October 23, 2013. The exercise is expected to start in November 2013 and be completed in time for the SSM’s inauguration in January 2015 (see Box 11.1 for a description of the methodology of the comprehensive assessment).
The SSM Comprehensive Assessment1
The SSM assessment is broad and comprehensive in methodological and institutional coverage. About 130 credit institutions comprising 85 percent of euro area bank assets will be assessed. The assessment consists of three elements: (1) a supervisory risk assessment to review key risks quantitatively and qualitatively; (2) an asset quality review (AQR) of key risk exposures; and (3) a stress test to assess banks’ resilience to forward-looking stress scenarios.
The supervisory assessment examines key risks in a forward- and backward-looking manner, including risks relating to liquidity, leverage, and funding. This enables assessment of a bank’s intrinsic risk profile, its position in relation to its peers, and its vulnerability to a number of exogenous factors. The risk assessment methodology will in the future be a new supervisory tool of the SSM.
The AQR performs a comprehensive review of bank assets, including important elements such as restructured loans, collateral valuation, and provisions. It focuses on balance sheet items that are more risky or nontransparent. It is broad in scope, covering credit exposures—including nonperforming and restructured loans—and market exposures. It includes corporate, retail, interbank, and sovereign exposures (although the latter will continue to carry a zero risk weight); on- and off-balance-sheet positions; and both domestic and foreign exposures. While internal risk models will not be assessed, the exercise results in adjustments of risk weights.
The stress test will build on and complement the AQR by providing a forward-looking view of shock-absorption capacity under stress. It will be conducted in collaboration with the European Banking Authority (EBA), with the methodology and scenarios to be agreed upon in due course.
The announcement clarifies several important details of the exercise:
Harmonized definitions will be used for nonperforming exposures and forbearance, in line with recent guidance from the EBA.
Portfolio choice and sampling will be risk based. National authorities will propose, at the bank level, the portfolios to be assessed. The European Central Bank (ECB) will “review and challenge” these proposals before making selections. It will be important for the ECB to ensure that there is methodological consistency across countries and banks in this regard, and high-risk and nontransparent segments will be subject to higher sampling rates. A broad range of credit and market exposures, both domestic and foreign, will be included, although the review will concentrate on those elements of individual bank balance sheets that are believed to be the most risky. The exercise will be subject to minimum coverage criteria at both the country and bank levels, although those are yet to be specified.
The minimum capital requirement for the AQR is set at 8 percent of Common Equity Tier 1, which will be stricter than regulatory requirements. The capital definition of January 1, 2014 will apply for the AQR, whereas the definition that is valid at the end of the horizon will be used for the stress test—a difference being the phasing in of capital deductions for deferred tax assets and holdings in financial companies envisaged under the fourth Capital Requirements Directive (CRD IV).
Independent third-party involvement has been confirmed. Oliver Wyman will support the ECB, providing independent advice on methodology, while assisting in design and implementation.
Disclosure of the outcomes, at the country and bank levels, will conclude the exercise by end-October 2014, and will include recommended follow-up supervisory measures.
Several important aspects of the assessment remain to be agreed upon:
Backstops. Use of the European Supervisory Mechanism’s (ESM’s) direct recapitalization remains the first-best option to keep adverse bank-sovereign feedback loops at bay for countries that do not have fiscal space. National backstops—possibly via ESM sovereign loans—need to be established and communicated well in advance of the completion of the AQR, in line with the June 2013 European Council June agreement to establish national backstops ahead of the assessment.
Bail-ins. Agreement and clarity on an appropriate strategy for bailing-in private creditors while ensuring financial stability is essential. The revised state aid rules specify that, as a requirement for state aid to be granted, and to the extent that these measures do not endanger financial stability, “Hybrid capital and subordinated debt holders must contribute to reducing the capital shortfall to the maximum extent” while exceptions to this rules are possible to address financial stability concerns and “proportionality” considerations.
Recapitalization. Formulation and communication of details of the approach for follow-up and corrective actions, including a timeline for recapitalizations, will be critical. Filling capital gaps should be accompanied by a realistic write-down of assets, full recognition of losses and restructuring of nonviable bank businesses.
ESM Recapitalization
Reaching final agreement on the possibility of ESM recapitalization of banks is of the utmost importance. The possibility of direct recapitalization of banks would provide incentives to make progress in addressing solvency issues in countries by relieving pressures on weak sovereigns. The interpretation given to the ESM Treaty is that it is flexible enough to enable the ESM to recapitalize banks directly—subject to political agreement and unanimous consent of the ESM membership. Indeed, under Article 19 of the ESM Treaty, the Board of Governors may also review and change the range of financial assistance instruments that can be made available by the ESM. The Board of Directors may adopt guidelines for implementing financial assistance through recapitalization or loans.
Ultimately, the breadth of the investment decisions that can be made by the ESM rests upon the decision of its member states, in due consideration of the risks and potential upsides or downsides inherent in such investments. It will be important to agree on and clarify the investment mandate of the ESM as well as the specifics of ESM recapitalization, including the definition of legacy assets, the pricing of assets, the role of bail-ins, the principle for access, and the design of instruments. Moreover, if the ESM were to inject ordinary equity into banks, governance arrangements and ownership policies would need to be carefully elaborated. Possible conflicts arising from concurrent significant stakes in competing institutions would need to be dealt with, and disclosure requirements would need to be strengthened.
Lastly, it would be important to ensure that the ESM had adequate capital, not only to allay any investor concerns about ESM credit quality, with resulting rating implications, but also so it could leverage its capital to play the role of a common backstop for bank recapitalization. The Eurogroup agreement of June 20, 2013, on the “ESM direct bank recapitalization instrument” is an important step forward and provides the main features of the operational framework, including conditions for access, time of entry, burden sharing, valuation, conditionality, and governance. Nevertheless, the recapitalization instrument will require further clarification and detailed features, in particular regarding the timing (since the final agreement has been linked to the adoption of the BRRD and the DGS Directive), conditionality, burden sharing, size, and conditions for access (see Chapter 13 for greater details).
Addressing Risks Related to the European Central Bank
Measures to mitigate risks related to operations and the division of responsibilities between the ECB and the National Competent Authorities include the following.
Build Capacity and Expertise at the ECB
The ECB should be able to intervene in a timely manner in any bank, as deemed necessary, and it should be able to bring any bank under its direct supervision. The off-site supervisory structure should be established as soon as possible at the ECB. Specialist expertise should be hired externally and also obtained by secondments from national authorities. Cross-country teams led by an ECB supervisor should be in place as soon as possible for the most systemic or fragile banks (including those requiring ESM direct recapitalization). Funding of the ECB’s supervisory activities should be derived not only from transfers from the national supervisory authorities, but also from additional revenues, in part to minimize potential adverse effects on national supervisory resources.
Specify the Roles of National Authorities and the ECB
It will be important to specify the respective roles of national authorities and the ECB and how cooperative action under the SSM will be performed. The SSM hinges on a division of labor between the ECB and the national authorities. Clear, precise, and transparent rules defining such divisions of labor and the attribution of tasks given by the ECB to the national authorities will be important to prevent overlaps, gaps, or conflicts. For this purpose, the ECB should, as soon as possible, prepare a supervisory manual and clarify any outstanding legal uncertainties.
Define Steps Toward a Single Resolution Authority
EU authorities should define and agree on steps toward a single resolution authority and common backstops, and establish an SRM around the time the SSM is declared effective. It will reduce the risks of an incomplete framework and ensure that national interests do not prevail over that of the European Union. Pending the establishment of an EU-wide resolution framework, it is welcome that the prompt update of national resolution regimes has been agreed to be a priority. In the meantime, it is essential that an SRM be established for the countries participating in the SSM around the time that the SSM becomes effective. Leaving resolution at the national level while supervision was being centralized would carry significant risks, such as perpetuating bank—sovereign links and creating potential conflicts (and deadlocks) among national authorities. An SRM based on a strong centralized resolution authority would allow for swift decisions on burden sharing while ensuring stability and least-cost resolution.
An effective common fiscal backstop, combining a credit line to the ESM as a bridge to a more permanent solution and a single resolution fund backed by industry resources, would weaken sovereign-bank links. The European Commission proposal for an SRM, described in Chapter 12, is an important step forward, as it would provide the possibility for a strong central resolution authority backed by a single resolution fund, which are desirable characteristics, in time for the start of the SSM. However, the proposal itself would need to be strengthened along several dimensions and may be subject to legal challenges.
Develop the ECB’s Macroprudential Powers
The ECB should identify systemic risks, take early actions, and use macroprudential instruments when deemed necessary, in coordination with national authorities and the European Systemic Risk Board.
References
Goyal, Rishi, and others, 2013, “A Banking Union for the Euro Area,” IMF Staff Discussion Note No. 13/1 (Washington: International Monetary Fund).
International Monetary Fund, 2013, “European Union: Financial System Stability Assessment,” IMF Staff Country Report No. 13/75 (Washington).
These dates have subsequently been pushed back. The October 18–19, 2012, European Council meeting called for agreeing on the legislative framework by the start of 2013, with the effective operation of the SSM in the course of 2013. The draft of the regulation, agreed upon by EU leaders on December 13, 2012, calls for entry into force of the SSM regulation on March 1, 2013, while the Council conclusions postpone the adoption of the other EU draft legislation. The SSM regulation was adopted by the European Parliament on September 12, 2013, after transparency and accountability requirements were strengthened, and by the Council on October 15, 2013. The regulation was published in the Official Journal of the EU on October 29, 2013, and the ECB will be declared effective one year later or when the ECB declares itself ready.
Under the criteria specified in Article 5(4) of the Council agreement of the regulation, banks accounting for about 80 percent of euro area banking assets would be under the direct supervision of the ECB. A bank would be under the direct supervision of the ECB if any one of the following conditions were met: (1) assets exceeded €30 billion; (2) the ratio of total assets to GDP of the home member state exceeded 20 percent; or (3) national competent authorities considered the institution to be significant. An institution could also be considered as significant by the ECB if it had significant cross-border assets or liabilities, relied upon ESM financial assistance, or was among the three largest institutions in the home member state (to ensure direct supervision of banks of smaller countries).
The requirement for the SSM to be in place before direct recapitalization by the ESM is permitted was initially set out in the statement of euro area leaders at the European Union Summit of June 2012.
The target was met for the Fourth Capital Requirement Directive and the Capital Requirement Regulation, and agreement on the BRRD was also reached at the Council in June 2013, with the view of having adoption of both the BRRD and Deposit Guarantee Schemes Directive at the European Parliament by end-2013.
The European Council’s conclusions of June 27–28, 2013, reiterated the importance of an SRM to ensure effectiveness of the SSM.
In particular, the legality of the legal instrument establishing the SSM and its decisions could be challenged before the European Union Court of Justice by EU institutions (including the European Parliament), member states, and any private person or entity aff ected by SSM decisions. See Chapter 10 for a detailed discussion of legal considerations.
For example, there is more than one banking supervisory agency in the United States. While the Federal Reserve has a range of supervisory responsibilities, including supervising bank holding companies, and must coordinate with the Financial Stability Oversight Council for systemic issues, it shares supervisory and regulatory responsibilities for domestic banking institutions with the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency (OCC), the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC), and the Office of Th rift Supervision (OTS) at the federal level, and with the banking departments of the various states.
See “Core Principles for Effective Banking Supervision,” dated September 2012, available at the website of the Bank for International Settlements, at http://www.bis.org/publ/bcbs230.htm.
The BCP preconditions for effective supervision also include the implementation of coherent and sustainable macroeconomic policies and a well-developed public infrastructure and effective market discipline.
“Key Attributes of Effective Resolution Regimes for Financial Institutions”, Financial Stability Board, October 2011. See: http://www.fi nancialstabilityboard.org/.
Note that the draft regulation published by the Council of the European Union stipulates that the ECB may also start, from the date of entry into force of the SSM regulation, directly supervising a bank if the ESM unanimously requests the ECB to take over the direct supervision of this bank (Article 27(3)).