2. Reforming the Judiciary: Learning from the Experience of Central, Eastern, and Southeastern Europe
Author:
International Monetary Fund. European Dept.
Search for other papers by International Monetary Fund. European Dept. in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close

Abstract

The countries of Central, Eastern, and Southeastern Europe (CESEE) have made major progress in raising living standards over the past two and a half decades. This progress was supported by a radical transformation of their economies and institutions. Using case studies and empirical analysis, this chapter explores the role of internal and external factors, particularly accession to the European Union (EU), in supporting reforms to strengthen the effectiveness of the judiciary. The findings suggest that, beyond initial conditions, an enabling environment for judicial reforms was created by factors and policies that (1) improved the distribution of resources and opportunities, (2) upgraded rules and procedures to recruit and train civil servants, and (3) increased transparency and accountability. The European Union and the Council of Europe (CoE) acted as strong external anchors in catalyzing reforms. However, there were also some reversals of reforms, and the sustainability of reforms appears to depend mainly on domestic factors. These findings might offer insights in particular for countries aiming to join the European Union, but also for others seeking to improve the effectiveness of their judiciary.

The countries of Central, Eastern, and Southeastern Europe (CESEE) have made major progress in raising living standards over the past two and a half decades. This progress was supported by a radical transformation of their economies and institutions. Using case studies and empirical analysis, this chapter explores the role of internal and external factors, particularly accession to the European Union (EU), in supporting reforms to strengthen the effectiveness of the judiciary. The findings suggest that, beyond initial conditions, an enabling environment for judicial reforms was created by factors and policies that (1) improved the distribution of resources and opportunities, (2) upgraded rules and procedures to recruit and train civil servants, and (3) increased transparency and accountability. The European Union and the Council of Europe (CoE) acted as strong external anchors in catalyzing reforms. However, there were also some reversals of reforms, and the sustainability of reforms appears to depend mainly on domestic factors. These findings might offer insights in particular for countries aiming to join the European Union, but also for others seeking to improve the effectiveness of their judiciary.

Why Focus on Judicial Reforms?

CESEE countries have made significant progress in improving institutions since the transition to market economies, but they need a new wave of structural reforms to sustain the rapid convergence of incomes. The fast convergence before the global financial crisis, particularly in the CESEE EU countries, was supported by high productivity gains from rapid integration into European supply chains, strong capital inflows attracted by underbanked economies, and extensive economic and institutional reforms implemented during the transition and EU accession. However, total factor productivity growth dropped substantially after the global financial crisis, and investment suffered. Projected declines in the working-age population, partly because of continued emigration, along with skill shortages compound the looming headwinds. With external conditions expected to be less supportive than during the transition, boosting potential growth requires a better environment for domestic savings and investment and, hence, new and more difficult institutional and governance reforms (Thomsen 2017a, 2017b). Sound legal institutions are vital in this regard.

Judicial reform and control of corruption are viewed as key structural reform priorities in many European countries. For example, the IMF has highlighted enhancing justice systems’ efficiency and capacity to facilitate debt resolution in several countries (IMF 2015); improving contract enforcement and protection of property rights in Kosovo, Serbia, and Slovenia; and strengthening anticorruption efforts in Bulgaria, Greece, Hungary, Italy, Romania, and Ukraine. Recognizing progress made in many other structural reform areas, the May 2016 Regional Economic Issues: Central, Eastern, and Southeastern Europe suggested that incomplete reforms of judicial systems and protection of property rights in many CESEE economies may explain a significant part of the productivity gaps with the EU15.1 Hence, judicial reforms may have considerable potential to boost incomes in the region (Figure 2.1). Judicial reforms continue to be high on policymakers’ agendas and are relevant for all EU countries, but particularly for countries that aspire to join the European Union.

Figure 2.1.
Figure 2.1.

CESEE: Estimated Efficiency Gains from Institutional Reforms

(Percent; potential improvement in total factor productivity)

Source: IMF May 2016, Regional Economic Issues: Central, Eastern, and Southeastern Europe.Note: Data labels use International Organization for Standardization (ISO) country abbreviations.

The IMF has long recognized the importance of good governance, including the rule of law, for long-term, inclusive growth (IMF 1997, 2017a). Institutions that contribute to good governance need to be effective in serving the well-being of all in society as opposed to only a few (Box 2.1). Recently, the IMF has highlighted the pernicious effects of corruption, especially on inclusive growth and on citizens’ trust (IMF 2016a). In discussing the 2017 Board Paper on the IMF’s role in governance, Directors called for further work in this area. In the October 2017 Global Policy Agenda, the IMF Managing Director stated that “[s]trengthening governance is essential in building support for reforms needed to raise long-term growth and ensure a domestic level-playing field” and that “[t]he Fund will strengthen its engagement on governance and corruption issues” (IMF 2017d). This study seeks to contribute to this work stream.

CESEE countries greatly improved their institutions, including the judiciary, during the transition and EU accession, and hence their experiences can provide useful insights. By choosing to join the European Union, most countries in the region have committed to the goal of effective rule of law. The differences in the institutional quality in these countries— despite somewhat similar settings, major reforms everywhere, and the common goal of EU accession—provide historical and recent background to study the factors affecting institutional progress. Hence, this chapter focuses on the 20 CESEE countries that are EU members or seek to join the European Union.2

This chapter focuses on the effectiveness of justice systems and, to a more limited extent, the protection of property rights.3 A country’s legal framework is a critical element of its business environment, as it affects all economic interactions and hence economic outcomes. The World Bank’s 2017 World Development Report emphasizes that the rule of law is “the very basis of good governance needed to realize full social and economic development,” but that the existence of laws does not assure these outcomes (World Bank 2017). Hence, the report calls for a focus on “the role of law,” which means its effect on the functions of the legal system rather than its form. Effective rule of law also plays a key role in control of corruption (Lagarde 2016, 2017). Within the rule of law, the effectiveness of the justice system and protection of property rights— which depend on the justice system to a large extent, but also on other elements—are critical to economic outcomes.4

This chapter explores the question of what might encourage judicial reforms. It adds several country case studies to the literature, as well as a comprehensive empirical analysis, with a view to distilling concrete policy lessons for countries that endeavor to improve the effectiveness of their judiciary systems. Importantly, the analysis does not provide legal assessments, but tries to address the following questions:

  • What were the specific reforms of the justice system and protection of property rights and the context in which they took place?

  • How have judicial reforms evolved over time, and how do they compare across countries?

  • Which factors facilitated these reforms?

  • What was the role of domestic factors and of the European Union in enabling change?

The chapter begins with an analytical framework that explores factors affecting institutional quality. Drawing on the framework, the section that follows presents country experiences. The chapter then offers a stocktaking of CESEE progress on judicial effectiveness, discusses factors that may have contributed to judicial reforms, and puts forth conclusions.

How to Analyze Institutional Quality: Conceptual Framework

The literature offers several theories to analyze differences in institutional quality that are combined in this chapter into a unified framework. As factors affecting judicial effectiveness are likely to be similar to those determining broader institutional quality, this section draws on the literature on institutions. Institutions that contribute to good governance need to be effective in serving the well-being of everyone in society.5 Institutional theories can be grouped into several approaches (Annex 2.1). This chapter adopts a political economy framework, building mainly on Acemoğlu, Johnson, and Robinson (2005), a seminal paper on the political economy approach. This framework encompasses two critical features: (1) economic institutions’ distributional consequences, which in turn affect institutions, giving rise to important feedback loops; and (2) politicians’ inability to commit to act only in the public interest, exacerbating collective action problems (Figure 2.2).6 De jure political power depends on political institutions, which result from initial conditions, ideology, and state capacity. De facto political power also depends on resource distribution and how different groups in society interact via bargaining. Given preferences of different groups in society, those with the most political power (both de facto and de jure) determine prevailing institutions and use them in their interest. Institutions then affect economic outcomes, the distribution of resources, and state capacity in subsequent periods, generating feedback loops between resource distribution and political and economic institutions.

Figure 2.2.
Figure 2.2.

Factors Shaping Institutional Quality1

1 The figure builds on the framework presented in Acemoğlu, Johnson, and Robinson (2005) and includes some extensions to incorporate other channels summarized in Annex 2.1.

According to this framework, in societies without dominant players, gaining political power is more competitive, leading to rules-based decision making and effective institutions. A concentrated distribution of resources and opportunities limits possibilities for many people to gain power. Many have expressed concern about large firms’ influence on the rules of the game (Guriev 2017; Zingales 2017). Conversely, civil society tends to promote participatory processes and effective institutions.

The greater a society’s ability to solve collective action problems, the more likely it is to establish effective institutions. Societies with less fragmentation along various dimensions (for example, ethnicities and cultures) tend to find it easier to reach agreement and solve their collective action problems (Trumbull 2012). Fragmentation in this context measures divisiveness and power imbalances as opposed to diversity. More diverse societies, particularly those where the views of different groups are well represented and respected (that is, minority rights), might actually be better at finding common ground. Higher levels of transparency and accountability alleviate information asymmetries, discourage rent-seeking behavior, and may help overcome trust deficits, thereby facilitating time-consistent behavior in the pursuit of long-term goals, coordination, and cooperation (World Bank 2017).

The capacity of the public administration is also important for institutional quality. In countries with established rules and procedures for hiring and training public employees, political interference in public administration decision making is more limited and public service provision is better (Andrews, Pritchett, and Woolcock 2012). However, the capacity of the public administration itself may depend on powerful groups’ decisions regarding state capacity.

Initial conditions and the external environment influence many of the above-mentioned elements through different channels:

  • Initial conditions: History, geography, culture, societal norms, the initial level of development, and legal origins can matter in various ways.

  • External shocks: Treats to sovereignty or crises could create a common purpose and make it easier to solve collective action problems, though the opposite could also occur. Technological change and other shocks could alter the distribution of resources and change the balance of power.

  • Openness: Greater openness may promote a better judiciary to the extent that investors reward rules-based business environments and businesses adapt to global standards. Import competition in domestic markets may reduce the monopolization of power.

  • External anchors: A prominent example is the European Union. The expected benefits from EU accession may have outweighed the loss of domestic policy autonomy for politically powerful groups, helping overcome domestic resistance to reforms (Box 2.2). The CoE (all countries concerned except Kosovo are members) has also helped CESEE countries advance judicial reforms through its binding and nonbinding legal standards. Assistance from international financial institutions may also provide incentives for broader institutional reforms.

The empirical analysis in this chapter considers all the factors presented in the above framework, while most previous studies test the relevance of specific hypotheses. The September 2005 World Economic Outlook found that openness and accountability were associated with higher institutional quality, while natural resource abundance was negatively associated with it. More recent studies suggest that imperfect accountability, limited transparency, and high income inequality hinder institutional quality (Ganiou Mijiyawa 2013; EBRD 2013). Several studies provide evidence of the beneficial role of an external anchor, such as the European Union (EBRD 2013; September 2005 World Economic Outlook). However, others argue that institutional reforms slowed after countries were offered EU membership and even reversed in some cases after the countries joined (Mungiu-Pippidi 2015). Prima facie, high and positive correlations are observed between the current level of economic aspects of the rule of law and the initial equality of resource distribution, transparency, and the capacity of public administration (Figure 2.3).7 However, more analysis is needed to understand causality given the feedback loops between institutions and economic outcomes.

Figure 2.3.
Figure 2.3.

CESEE: Initial Level of Fundamentals and Aspects of the Rule of Law1

(Index; 0 = worst, 10 = best)

Sources: World Economic Forum; University of Gothenburg; Varieties of Democracy Institute (V-Dem); and IMF staff calculations.Note: EU15 countries are listed in text footnote 1.1 Based on available worldwide distribution of advanced and emerging market economies.

This section refers to the EU concepts of effective justice systems and protection of property rights. The European Commission’s Aquis Judiciary and Fundamental Rights Chapter states that “the establishment of an independent and efficient judiciary is of paramount importance. Impartiality, integrity and a high standard of adjudication by the courts are essential for safeguarding the rule of law. Equally, member states must fight corruption effectively, as it represents a threat to the stability of democratic institutions and the rule of law.” The Acquis notes that effective protection of property rights—established by the European Human Rights Convention and the EU Charter of Fundamental Rights—hinges on enforcement capacity, which requires an effective judiciary. This section focuses on the judiciary’s efficiency, independence, and impartiality in order to capture the overall effectiveness of the judicial system.

This chapter uses a wide range of information sources. It relies extensively on the standard setting and evaluations of the CoE bodies—the European Commission for the Efficiency of Justice (Commission européenne pour l’efcacité de la justice—CEPEJ) and the Group of States against Corruption (GRECO)—and the European Commission’s reports, as well as on other studies and experts. However, CEPEJ data and the EU Justice Scoreboards start in 2010 or later. To have quantitative indicators over a long period for more countries and dimensions, and following most previous studies, we also employ data from the World Bank’s Worldwide Governance and Doing Business Indicators, the World Economic Forum, the Varieties of Democracy Institute, and other sources (Annex 2.2). Most of these data are perception based and thus more subjective than other economic indicators. Nevertheless, economic decisions are based on agents’ perceptions of many factors, including governance, effectiveness of the judiciary, and property rights protection. CoE 2015 notes that “… other factors, such as public perception, political culture and safeguards against corruption have a clear impact on the ability of courts and judges to command legitimacy and do their job.” The case studies that follow here rely on many sources to understand the context in which judicial reforms took place.

Country Case Studies

This section analyzes judicial reform episodes in six countries: Bosnia and Herzegovina, Croatia, Estonia, Poland, Romania, and Serbia. Employing the framework presented earlier, the section discusses factors shaping judicial effectiveness, such as the equality of resource distribution, transparency and accountability, state capacity, political power, and the role of external anchors. The mix of cases aims to ensure adequate representation across the region. We include countries with initial conditions more conducive to an effective judiciary (Estonia, Poland), a country that faced more challenging domestic fundamentals (Romania), and countries that went through civil strife (Bosnia and Herzegovina, Croatia, Serbia). For each country, the analysis focuses on periods when significant judicial reforms occurred in order to uncover drivers of change.

Estonia

Conducive initial conditions and carefully designed policies helped establish effective institutions in Estonia. Estonia’s favorable initial conditions included a vibrant civil society. A relatively inclusive reform process ensured widespread distribution of privatized assets and eliminated barriers to foreign trade and investment by reducing high tariffs and nontariff restrictions. This limited the formation of national oligopolies and enhanced transparency and accountability to enable the involvement of citizens in the political process. Significant early investment in the capacity of the judiciary was also instrumental for judicial independence.

Estonia’s transition involved a major and rapid overhaul of the institutional framework. Initial reforms laid out solid foundations for an independent judiciary. The Court Act and the Legal Status of Judges Act, adopted in 1991, regulated the functions of the judiciary (Gherasimov 2015). Drawing on Estonia’s 1938 constitution, a new constitution adopted in 1992 provided the basis for the separation and balance of powers and guarantees for judicial independence. The new constitution reinstated a parliamentary democracy founded on legal continuity with the pre-Soviet Estonia (Pärna 2005). The guarantees took the form of life tenure for judges and protection against their removal from office (OSI 2001), while decisional independence and impartiality were assured by limits on judges’ cross-branch or outside activity (GRECO 2013). The new judicial system became operational in 1993.

Subsequent reforms solidified the judiciary’s independence and efficiency. The 2002 Courts Act helped reduce the influence of the Ministry of Justice and eliminated political involvement in disciplining judges by transferring the authority to initiate proceedings against judges from the ministry to the Legal Chancellor. Further, the 2010 Courts Act introduced shared oversight of the administration of courts by the Ministry of Justice and the Court Administration Advisory Council (leaving the Ministry of Justice in charge of budgetary issues, however). In recent years, the integrity of the judiciary improved further (for example, via supervision of judges’ assets and interest declarations), and so did efficiency (Figure 2.4).

Figure 2.4.
Figure 2.4.

Estonia: Judicial Independence and Protection of Property Rights

(Index; 0 = worst, 10 = best)

Sources: World Economic Forum; and IMF staff calculations.

The privatization process ensured broad distribution of resources, fostering effective institutions. Estonia’s privatization aimed at putting assets into the hands of those with the incentives and skills to use them effectively, while ensuring wide participation across society (Nellis 1996). The 1993 Privatization Law guaranteed broadly equal rights to domestic and foreign investors and physical and legal persons, while entities with more than a 30 percent public stake were excluded. By 1995, divestiture was largely completed, having turned many people into private owners and contributed to attaining income inequality levels similar to the EU average (Taube and Weber 1999; Laar 2007).8

The rapid and sustained progress on institutional reforms was underpinned by favorable domestic factors (Figure 2.5). Specifically:

  • The distribution of resources and opportunities in Estonia in the mid-1990s was similar to the EU average.

  • The strength of civil society and the control of political corruption were similar to the EU15 average by the mid-1990s, providing checks and balances.9

  • Government censorship was effectively abolished following the establishment of a private press and private broadcasting during 1991–94. Further, the media assumed a watchdog role regarding political scandals (Vihalemm and Masso 2003). Legal guarantees of access to information and extensive use of e-government increased transparency and accountability.

  • The introduction of a modern legal and administrative framework for the civil service greatly strengthened public sector capacity, with assistance from various countries and institutions. A large part of the civil service was replaced with new personnel selected based on merit. This was considered one of the most comprehensive administrative reforms in the region (Sarapuu 2012; Tõnnisson and Randma-Liiv 2008).

Figure 2.5.
Figure 2.5.

Estonia: Factors Affecting Institutional Quality1

(Index; 0 = worst, 10 = best)

Sources: Varieties of Democracy Institute (V-Dem) database (version 6.2); and IMF staff calculations.Note: EU15 countries are listed in text footnote 1.1 Equal distribution of resources measures poverty and the distribution of goods and services as well as the levels of inequality in these distributions and the proportion of the population ineligible for social services.

Given the strong domestic drive for reforms, the European Union mainly provided benchmarks guaranteeing high standards in Estonia. EU accession negotiations began informally in 1993. The Free Trade Agreement with the European Union came into force in 1995 (Figure 2.6). The European Commission deemed Estonia’s respect for the rule of law and protection of property rights in line with its requirements in 1998.

Figure 2.6.
Figure 2.6.

Estonia: EU Accession Timeline

Source: European Commission.

Poland

Favorable initial conditions combined with the commitment to EU membership helped Poland achieve significant progress in judicial reform, but the process has been neither smooth nor linear. While Poland had strong initial conditions in terms of an active civil society and freedom of information that promoted significant reforms early in the transition, these conditions were not enough to ensure sustained progress in judicial reforms. Insufficient efforts to build the capacity of the judiciary, combined with deterioration in the equality of incomes and opportunities, appear to have contributed to some reversals in judicial independence. Commitment to EU membership supported by the country’s vibrant civil society helped overcome some of these setbacks. However, in 2017 the European Commission launched an infringement procedure against Poland over legislation regarding the judiciary on concerns that the legislation may undermine its independence.

Poland’s active civil society before the transition provided some favorable initial conditions for institutional reform (Figure 2.7). According to Bruszt and others (2009), political opposition before 1989 was more intense in Central and Eastern Europe, especially in Poland, compared with other communist countries. A vibrant civil society, and notably the role of the trade unions, was important for the formation of institutions that provided checks and balances. Moreover, a massive expansion of media outlets enabled debates over social problems.

Figure 2.7.
Figure 2.7.

Poland: Factors Affecting Institutional Quality1

(Index; 0 = worst, 10 = best)

Sources: Varieties of Democracy Institute (V-Dem) database (version 6.2); and IMF staff calculations.Note: EU15 countries are listed in text footnote 1.1 Equal distribution of resources measures poverty and the distribution of goods and services as well as the levels of inequality in these distributions and the proportion of the population ineligible for social services.

With a strong civil society and freedom of information, reforms of property rights and the judiciary started early. The 1989 constitutional amendments sanctioned the independence of judges and introduced the separation of the judiciary from other branches of government. Together with the 1988 Law on Economic Activity, this laid the foundation for freedom of business activity and property rights protection (Figure 2.8). A critical step in establishing judicial autonomy was the creation of the National Judicial Council, which recommends judgeship candidates to the president. When the preaccession process started in 1994, the judiciary had already been deeply transformed. In its first report, the European Commission stated that “the independence of the Polish judiciary vis-à-vis other institutions appears secured” (EC 1997). A new constitution approved in 1997 further separated powers and strengthened the Constitutional Tribunal and property rights protection. Perceived judicial independence was at a high level already in 1995, but deteriorated thereafter.

Figure 2.8.
Figure 2.8.

Poland: Judicial Independence and Protection of Property Rights1

(Index; 0 = worst, 10 = best)

Sources: World Economic Forum; and IMF staff calculations.1 Missing data for 1996–99 have been interpolated.

While privatization was not smooth, neither was it hasty, which helped limit resource concentration. About 70 percent of small and medium enterprises (SMEs) were privatized by the end of the 1990s (Iwanek and Wellisz 1993). However, large-scale privatization took much longer than expected (Patena 2015). This slow process allowed private firms to emerge and compete for acquisition of public assets, which may have limited resource concentration. Meanwhile, state-owned enterprises (SOEs) still play an important role in the economy and dominate some sectors.

However, Poland’s judicial system witnessed a considerable deterioration during 1997–2003. The systemic judicial reforms and sizable changes in the opportunities available in the private and public sectors—as growth rapidly expanded jobs and pay in the former, while the latter did not adjust as quickly—created significant challenges for judiciary effectiveness. The system was not prepared for the large influx of cases caused by the systemic changes to the legal system and the economy (Freedom House 2003; Kucharczyk and Zbieranek 2010). This resulted in long processing times for legal cases and difficulties in enforcing court decisions (EC 1997). Many low-paid judges left to join the private sector, further diminishing judiciary capacity. Instances of corruption among the judiciary were observed in the 2000s, as long waits for routine commercial court decisions created incentives for bribery (EC 2000). The perception of corruption, the capacity of public administration, and equality of incomes and opportunities deteriorated during 1998–2003 (Kucharczyk and Zbieranek 2010).

Despite these setbacks, the commitment to reforms under the EU accession framework provided a strong impulse to rebuild trust in the judiciary (Figure 2.9). Poland’s vibrant civil society once again fostered a civil movement resulting in a high turnout in the 2007 elections. Voters expressed dissatisfaction with some government measures viewed as undermining the rule of law. The EU oversight combined with the media’s role helped address these challenges, as reflected in the improvement in Poland’s ranking on the control of corruption index over its 2006 ranking (Ekiert and Soroka 2013). Another positive development was the reestablishment of an open and competitive process for recruiting senior government officials after 2007, resulting in a notable improvement in Poland’s ranking on the index of public administration capacity.

Figure 2.9.
Figure 2.9.

Poland: EU Accession Timeline

Source: European Commission.

The confluence of these positive developments may have contributed to the improvement in the 2007–09 perceived judicial independence. In response to several rulings by the European Court of Human Rights against Poland due to the length of proceedings, the government passed a law in 2004 aimed at addressing the undue length of court proceedings (Kucharczyk and Zbieranek 2010). In 2009, the government also increased judges’ salaries in response to massive protests (Kucharczyk and Zbieranek 2010). In October 2009, the Parliament revised the 1985 Act on Public Prosecution, separating the Ministry of Justice and the Office of the Public Prosecutor General, although this was reversed in 2016. The CoE acknowledged the constitutional independence of the Polish judiciary, pointing to only limited involvement of the Justice Minister (GRECO 2013).

In the summer of 2017, the EC launched an infringement procedure against Poland on concerns about judicial independence arising from new legislation. The government is undertaking judicial changes with the stated purpose “to meet people’s expectations and increase the democratization of the judiciary” (Polish Justice Ministry 2017), including raising the efficiency of courts and reducing case backlogs. In 2016, the European Commission used a new EU framework (see Box 2.2) and initiated the rule of law investigation regarding the amendments to the Constitutional Tribunal adopted during 2015–16. The 2017 Law on Ordinary Courts Organization gives discretionary power to the minister of justice to prolong the mandate of judges who have reached retirement age (differentiated for women and men), as well as to dismiss and appoint court presidents. The EC is concerned that the minister’s discretionary power will undermine the courts’ independence, and it is also concerned about gender discrimination. The EC launched the infringement procedure in July 2017 and issued a reasoned opinion in September 2017 after receiving the Polish authorities’ letter regarding the approved law (EC 2017a, 2017c). Two additional draft laws that concern the Supreme Court and the National Judicial Council, vetoed by the president in July 2017, are currently being redrafted. Discussions between the Polish authorities and the EC are ongoing.

Romania

Romania’s experience demonstrates the key role of an external anchor when domestic dynamics pose challenges to strengthening institutions. Civil society had been suppressed and the post-transition government did not have an appetite for reform. Privatization resulted in more concentrated resource distribution. Little investment in the capacity of the judiciary left the system with politically connected judges who resisted reforms. The EU accession played a catalytic role in strengthening civil society, freedom of information, and state capacity. This led to greater demand for and improvement in judicial independence and capacity. Nevertheless, Romania’s achievements in judicial reform remain incomplete, and problems persist with the implementation of court decisions (EC 2016a; GRECO 2016).

In an environment of weak civil society, the government that came to power in 1990 made little progress on reforms. The austerity program introduced in the 1980s to repay the country’s national debt resulted in shortages of basic goods and frequent electricity blackouts (Dăianu 2004). Oppression coupled with feelings of mistrust and secrecy cultivated by the old regime weakened civil society (Rossi 2012). Neither the student movement nor peripheral grassroots movements had the organizational capacity to replace the National Salvation Front (NSF) Party, which originated in the Communist Party. The NSF stayed in power longer than the originally expected interim role (Agh 2004; Siani-Davies 2005; Pralong 2004; Paramio 2002; Rossi 2012). Also, prevalent corruption hindered reforms, which previous elites bitterly opposed (Roman 2002; Dallara 2014).

In this challenging environment, judicial reforms faced many difficulties despite the EU accession process. Magistrates were generally loyal to the old regime, which limited judiciary independence (Demsorean, Parvulescu, and Vetrici-Soimu 2009). In 2002, the European Union postponed Romania’s accession until 2007. The 2003 constitution institutionalized a powerful Superior Council of the Magistracy (SCM) charged with the careers, appointments, promotions, and evaluations of magistrates. However, de facto, all these competencies were exercised by the Justice Ministry (Coman 2009). The lack of judicial independence also weighed on property rights protection.

Romania’s postcommunist privatizations contributed to the emergence of political and business elites who resisted reforms to the judiciary and protection of property rights. The privatization of large enterprises was long and contentious. Many viable large-scale enterprises were sold at fire sales, while the insolvent ones continued to burden the state (Gabanyi 2004; Bacon 2004). Members of the elite used their political power and control over state resources to solidify their control over the economy, politics, and the judiciary (Gabanyi 2004). Moreover, several nationalist political forces opposed foreign investors’ participation in privatization (Paramio 2002). All this resulted in a significant concentration of resources, with the Gini coefficient—a measure of inequality—rising by 10 percentage points by the late 1990s.

A turning point came in 2004, when civil society gathered strength, capitalizing on the move toward EU accession. Civil society organizations launched an anticorruption campaign for the 2004 election, offering to screen political parties’ candidates on integrity criteria (Mungiu-Pippidi 2015). The earlier adoption of freedom of information legislation driven by EU accession facilitated this campaign. Civil society organizations used it to expose politicians’ dishonest behavior and won several litigation cases against the government. This coincided with some decline in the perception of the corruption in politics. These factors, together with the prospect of EU accession, created common ground for the formation of an opposition coalition, despite unfavorable initial conditions (Vachudova 2006).

Figure 2.10.
Figure 2.10.

Romania: Factors Affecting Institutional Quality1

(Index; 0 = worst, 10 = best)

Sources: Varieties of Democracy Institute (V-Dem) database (version 6.2); and IMF staff calculations.Note: EU15 countries are listed in text footnote 1.1 Equal distribution of resources measures poverty and the distribution of goods and services as well as the levels of inequality in these distributions and the proportion of the population ineligible for social services.

Tangible reforms started in 2004 (Figure 2.11). Following the elections, the new minister of justice quickly implemented judicial reforms and an anticorruption strategy to fulfill EU requirements (Dallara 2010; Mendelski 2012). A law envisaging the appointment of the courts’ presidents and prosecutors was approved against the SCM’s opposition (Coman 2007; Carp 2007), but declared unconstitutional by the Constitutional Court, which included several members of the SCM and the old Communist Party (Dallara 2014). A revised version of the law was adopted, which included weaker provisions for judicial reforms. Although the European Union accepted this version, it introduced the Cooperation and Verification Mechanism (CVM) to address areas deemed in need of further progress, including the judiciary’s independence and impartiality and the fight against corruption (EC 2007; Dallara 2014).

Figure 2.11.
Figure 2.11.

Romania: Judicial Independence and Protection of Property Rights

(Index; 0 = worst, 10 = best)

Sources: World Economic Forum; and IMF staff calculations.

After EU accession in 2007, judicial reform slowed (Figure 2.12). The reform-minded minister of justice was replaced in the reshuffling of the government in 2007. Parliament endorsed a revised criminal code providing legal ways to protect corrupt officials, although adoption of the code was postponed and it was later modified (Dallara 2014). In addition, the government attempted to restrict the Constitutional Court’s powers and threatened to impeach judges (Blokker 2013; Dallara 2014). The European Union also criticized Romania for not respecting values of democracy and the rule of law (EC 2009), and the country’s ranking on the index of perceived judicial independence deteriorated.

Figure 2.12.
Figure 2.12.

Romania: EU Accession Timeline

Source: European Commission.

The situation improved after 2011 with the emergence of a new generation of judges more open to reforms and a further strengthening of civil society. The National Institute for the Magistracy, which implemented the EU-driven reform of judicial training, started to graduate a new generation of well-trained judges (Piana and others 2013). Many Romanian judges involved in some CoE expert committees and other international judicial networks supported the diffusion of best practices (Piana 2009). GRECO’s recommendations and the CVM promoted transparency, independence, and accountability of the justice system. The judiciary’s efficiency also improved, as evidenced by a 30 percent decline in disposition time for noncriminal cases over 2010–14 and more recently supported by increased resources allocated to the judiciary.

The trend regarding judicial reforms in Romania was positive until 2016, but since early 2017 some signs of slowing down seem to be emerging. As described in several CVM reports, a track record pointing to good progress and growing irreversibility of the reforms was evident with stronger judicial institutions and strengthened corruption prevention. However, “a number of key issues already identified in earlier reports have remained outstanding” (January 2017 CVM). This includes areas such as the independence of the judiciary and the effectiveness of the anticorruption framework. The authorities’ comprehensive “Strategy for the Development of the Judiciary 2015–2020” sets out the structural reform steps to be taken until 2020. The strategy is now underway and should bring major benefits to the users of the justice system and improve public trust in the system, provided its implementation is sufficiently robust. The population has been alert to signs of reversal as of 2017, as evidenced by public demonstrations. Overall the Romania case study shows that significant progress is possible, but requires sustained efforts for the reforms to become embedded and deliver a better functioning judiciary for all its citizens.

Croatia

Institutional reforms in Croatia were slow during the initial stages of the transition, mainly owing to military conflict, but prospects for EU accession catalyzed reforms. Citing national security concerns, the government monopolized power, including over the justice system, during 1991–2000 (Blitz 2003; Dallara 2014; Jović 2006). The 1993 Court Act created the State Judicial Council (SJC), an independent body responsible for the selection and dismissal of judges. However, in practice, the SJC became a “lever in the hands of the executive” (Uzelac 2003) and political influence over judges’ removals and appointments continued until 2000 (GRECO 2014). A large outflow of judges limited the judiciary’s capacity (Dallara 2014). After the war ended, civil society increasingly demanded institutional changes, and transparency improved. EU accession prospects were instrumental in encouraging reforms, though implementation gaps remain.

The judiciary’s inefficiency and poor implementation of privatization hindered property rights protection. Slow and inefficient court proceedings, poor case management, and low administrative and professional capacity were factors that undermined trust in effective enforcement of creditors’ and property rights. Privatization, which mostly took place in the 1990s, at times involved appointing new managers close to the ruling party, a trend that discouraged foreign investors and concentrated resources (Bartlett 2007).

The power of civil society groups increased and transparency improved starting in the late 1990s, catalyzing reforms (Figure 2.13). With the end of the war, and despite the unfavorable initial conditions, civil society gained some strength. The Croatian Judges Association became more critical of government actions and recorded significant victories against SJC rulings (Dallara 2014). In the late 1990s, the first public survey conducted regarding the Croatian judiciary highlighted the long duration of proceedings and case backlogs, helping to build reform momentum (Dallara 2014).

Figure 2.13.
Figure 2.13.

Croatia: Factors Affecting Institutional Quality1

(Index; 0 = worst, 10 = best)

Sources: Varieties of Democracy Institute (V-Dem) database (version 6.2); and IMF staff calculations.Note: EU15 countries are listed in text footnote 1.1 Equal distribution of resources measures poverty and the distribution of goods and services as well as the levels of inequality in these distributions and the proportion of the population ineligible for social services.

EU accession prospects and membership in several CoE bodies incentivized reforms. The government that took office in 2000 embarked on major reforms, including judicial reform. The signing of the association agreement with the European Union followed in 2001 (Figure 2.14). After 2000, the appointment procedures for judges were radically modified, providing limitations on political appointments (Dallara 2007). The main measures aimed at reducing political interference and making SJC membership incompatible with being chief justice. Other provisions gave the Constitutional Court broader powers to appeal SJC decisions.

Figure 2.14.
Figure 2.14.

Croatia: EU Accession Timeline

Source: European Commission.

The process of EU accession was instrumental in advancing judicial reforms (Figure 2.15). Croatia adopted the first Justice System Reform Strategy in 2005 and implemented one of the best rationalization reforms for the territorial reorganization of courts, achieving a 50 percent reduction in backlogged cases (Madir 2011; Carnevali 2013). In 2008, Croatia adopted a revised Justice System Reform Strategy that broadened justice reform as a prerequisite for continuing negotiations with the European Union. In 2010, the constitution was amended to strengthen judicial independence and reduce political interference in the SJC. Also, new selection procedures based on verified qualifications were introduced for the appointment of judges and prosecutors, limiting the Justice Ministry’s power and increasing the autonomy of the SJC and the State Prosecutorial Council. In 2010, a new strategy was adopted for the period until 2015 as a requirement for closing negotiations with the European Union. Due to a challenging political environment, initially the Croatian government’s cooperation with the International Criminal Tribunal for the Former Yugoslavia (ICTY) was erratic, despite this being a condition of European Union membership (Rajkovic 2012; Menz 2013). By 2013, however, Croatia complied, which was deemed a major step in judicial reform progress, paving the way to its joining the European Union.

Figure 2.15.
Figure 2.15.

Croatia: Judicial Independence and Protection of Property Rights

(Index; 0 = worst, 10 = best)

Sources: World Economic Forum; and IMF staff calculations.

By 2008, the EC deemed the protection of property rights to be generally assured, but enforcement to be weak. While the legal system put heavy emphasis on the rule of law, in practice, legal certainty was often limited. Regulations were sometimes inconsistent, and administrative bodies frequently lacked legal expertise. Thus, executive ordinances did not always comply with the original legal mandate. As a result, citizens and companies often lacked confidence in administrative procedures and frequently perceived acts of administrative bodies as arbitrary (Bartlett, Bönker, and Petak 2014). Reported threats and harm to prosecutors also undermined judicial independence (CoE 2016).

Serbia

Serbia’s institution-building path was uneven, as lingering effects of civil strife adversely affected domestic factors and relations with the European Union, weakening its role as an external anchor. The limited progress in judicial independence achieved after the fall of President Slobodan Milošević was not sustained. Reforms were stop-and-go, probably owing to increased concentration of resources related to flawed privatization and limited progress on transparency (Figure 2.16).

Figure 2.16.
Figure 2.16.

Serbia: Factors Affecting Institutional Quality1

(Index; 0 = worst, 10 = best)

Sources: Varieties of Democracy Institute (V-Dem) database (version 6.2); and IMF staff calculations.Note: EU15 countries are listed in text footnote 1.1 Equal distribution of resources measures poverty and the distribution of goods and services as well as the levels of inequality in these distributions and the proportion of the population ineligible for social services.

After the war, improving the effectiveness of the justice system became a priority as part of the broader reform agenda and possible EU accession (Figure 2.17). The efficiency of the judiciary had been undermined by an uneven workload between urban and rural courts, case backlogs, and the lack of a free legal aid system (EC 2016b). Political influence over the selection and appointment of judges was common (Dallara 2014). When reforms started, about half of active judges were dismissed. In 2001, a temporary government embarked on overhauling legislation and strongly encouraged judges in important positions to resign. But because of the lack of sufficient candidates to fill positions, this measure had a limited effect compared with that in other CESEE countries (Pavlovic 2003).

Figure 2.17.
Figure 2.17.

Serbia: Judicial Independence and Protection of Property Rights

(Index; 0 = worst, 10 = best)

Sources: World Economic Forum; and IMF staff calculations.

Various domestic players continued to resist judicial reforms, though increased transparency helped achieve some progress. In 2001, several laws were enacted to provide a legal basis for the operation of general and specialized courts and prosecutors’ offices, and for professional freedoms and guarantees for judges and public prosecutors (OSCE 2011). The introduction of a self-governed body responsible for recruiting and selecting magistrates was a major change. However, its establishment was delayed when the National Assembly attempted to amend the bill to control nominations. Under pressure from civil society, freedom of information improved, which appeared to promote more rules-based systems.

Increased cooperation with the European Union succeeded in advancing judicial reforms in the early and mid-2000s, the period that saw the greatest improvement. In 2001, the European Union launched the Stabilization and Association Process with Serbia and identified the country as a potential EU candidate in 2003 (Figure 2.18). Cooperation with the European Union helped overcome political resistance to judicial reforms, particularly concerning the self-governing body (Dallara 2014). With the new 2006 constitution approved, a new wave of judicial reforms established the self-governing High Judicial Council and reformed the State Prosecution Council (GRECO 2015a). These steps led to a considerable improvement in perceived judicial independence in 2005–07.

Figure 2.18.
Figure 2.18.

Serbia: EU Accession Timeline

Source: European Commission.Note: FRY = Federal Republic of Yugoslavia; SAA = Stabilization and Association Agreement; SAP = Stabilization and Association Process.

However, reforms stalled, reflecting continued power struggles and a deteriorating relationship with the European Union as a consequence of lingering effects of the war. In 2006, the European Union suspended negotiations with Serbia due to lack of collaboration with the ICTY. A distinct antireform alliance formed between judges worried about losing their jobs and political parties seeking to maintain effective control over the judiciary (Begović and Hiber 2006). The lack of further progress on transparency and accountability, and considerable deterioration in income inequality, may have supported the formation of this alliance. Serbia’s 2005 Gini coefficient was 5 percentage points higher than in 2000. Moreover, privatization was hasty, and special groups, some connected to the ruling party, received special treatment and protection for their firms (Radulović and Dragutinović 2014). Domestic business elites utilized their connections with politicians to preserve and even tighten barriers to entry (Pesic 2007; Begović 2013). The independence of self-governing bodies was hampered by the selection of the High Judicial Council members by the National Assembly instead of by peers (GRECO 2015a). The country still faces important challenges in cooperating with the ICTY, and such cooperation remains one of the European Union’s demands during Serbia’s accession talks (Ristic 2016).

In this environment, the improvement in judicial independence and efficiency was not sustained, though some progress has been made recently. The 2009 judicial reforms failed to improve judicial efficiency (GRECO 2015a). The perceived independence of the judiciary deteriorated, and by 2010 it was at the level of 2005. The main concern was related to the provision requiring reappointment of judges, which limited judges’ protection against removal and was denounced by the CoE (Murret 2010). Despite this criticism, in 2009 many judges were dismissed without clear criteria and without the right to contest the decision (Dicosola 2012). Closer integration with the European Union after 2010 provided a new impetus for judicial reforms, and the Constitutional Court reversed the 2009 decision on reappointment of all judges. Despite the improvement, perceived judicial independence in 2015 did not return to the level achieved in the mid-2000s, and trust in the judiciary remained limited (GRECO 2014, 2015a). As of 2014, a significant portion of judges (25 percent) and prosecutors (33 percent) reported that the judiciary was not independent, according to the World Bank Judicial Review. Judicial efficiency also remained troublesome, with disposition time some 30 percent higher than in other non-EU CESEE countries. The 2016 EC report notes that “the judicial system has reached some level of preparation,” but that further steps are needed to tackle its independence (EC 2016b).

Bosnia and Herzegovina

Bosnia and Herzegovina has made some progress in institutional reforms, but its case demonstrates that external intervention cannot substitute for a domestic reform drive. The rigid and decentralized structure enshrined by the Dayton Peace Agreement has allowed ethnicity-based politics to weaken reform efforts, including judicial reforms. Bosnia and Herzegovina’s current governance framework resulted from the 1995 Dayton Peace Agreement, which vested most government functions in the two semiautonomous entities— the Federation of Bosnia and Herzegovina and the Republika Srpska—and established above these entities the Institutions of Bosnia and Herzegovina (or “State”), though with a limited mandate. The countries guaranteeing the peace settlement installed the Office of the High Representative, which has extraordinary power to dismiss elected governments and officials. Although this architecture has succeeded in maintaining peace for a quarter century, it has not helped the country develop effective institutions (Figure 2.19).

Figure 2.19.
Figure 2.19.

Bosnia and Herzegovina: Factors Affecting Institutional Quality1

(Index; 0 = worst, 10 = best)

Sources: Varieties of Democracy Institute (V-Dem) database (version 6.2); and IMF staff calculations.Note: EU15 countries are listed in text footnote 1.1 Equal distribution of resources measures poverty and the distribution of goods and services as well as the levels of inequality in these distributions and the proportion of the population ineligible for social services.

Judicial reform momentum picked up in the early 2000s as the Office of the High Representation took on a forceful role (Figure 2.20). With EU support, it began formally coordinating judicial reforms. The entities adopted laws on judicial and prosecutorial functions that represented the first major step toward the creation of a harmonized legal framework. In 2003, the Office of the High Representation introduced procedural laws that introduced harmonized country-wide civil and criminal procedures (HJPC 2017). Mid-decade reforms of the state-level judiciary also helped strengthen judicial independence. In 2004, the entities and the State agreed to establish the High Judicial and Prosecutorial Council, an independent body with the power to appoint and discipline judges and prosecutors. The State-level court and prosecutors became functional in 2005 (OSCE 2017). Early compliance problems with the ICTY were overcome in the early 2000s.

Figure 2.20.
Figure 2.20.

Bosnia and Herzegovina: Judicial Independence and Protection of Property Rights

(Index; 0 = worst, 10 = best)

Sources: World Economic Forum; and IMF staff calculations.

After 2006, judicial reform momentum weakened even as the country’s domestic revenue mobilization improved and external anchors shifted. The international community began to shift away from supporting the direct approach of the Office of the High Representative to the incentive-driven EU accession process. While the latter provided long-term incentives for institutional reforms, implementation over the short term was hampered by Bosnia and Herzegovina’s heavily decentralized structure and inter-entity tensions. Reforms stalled, and a constitutional reform package was defeated in the State Parliament in 2007. While discussions to reengage on judicial reform subsequently picked up, progress on the ground was not as strong as that indicated by the index shown in Figure 2.20, which is based on perceptions.

Despite episodic improvements, judicial performance in Bosnia and Herzegovina remains weak. The structure of governance is fragmented, contributing to judicial ineffectiveness. Entity laws are not harmonized horizontally, coordination among judicial institutions is lacking, and governments exercise undue influence on judicial budgets (OSCE 2017; CoE 2016). Persistent interethnic squabbles have prevented implementation of many Constitutional Court decisions (EC 2016c). Courts are slow to issue judgments, despite some improvement in the clearance rate and disposition time of cases. Because judgments remain unenforced (EBRD 2017), plaintiffs often reinitiate new lawsuits. Judges are perceived as subscribing to legal approaches seen as more favorable to political parties representing their ethnicity. The quality of judgments on economic and financial cases is often poor; many judges award disproportionate compensation without addressing the underlying problem. International indicators also reflect the weaknesses in Bosnia and Herzegovina’s judicial system: the overall state of judicial effectiveness in the country is poor compared with regional peers (European Commission for Efficiency of Justice 2016), and the public’s perception of the judiciary is also negative (GRECO 2015b). The enforcement of property rights is also weak.

Judicial reforms are back in focus, supported by the European Union, but the outcome is uncertain. In 2015, the authorities adopted the Reform Agenda, which lays out plans to improve the rule of law and is supported by Bosnia and Herzegovina’s international partners, with the European Union in the lead (meaningful progress on the agenda is a prerequisite for EU candidate status (Figure 2.21).) The IMF’s Extended Fund Facility, approved in 2016, contributes to this agenda by aiming to strengthen governance of state development banks and SOEs. Box 2.3 reviews reforms related to governance in IMF-supported programs in selected CESEE countries (Kosovo and Ukraine).

Figure 2.21.
Figure 2.21.

Bosnia and Herzegovina: EU Accession Timeline

Source: European Commission.Note: BiH = Bosnia and Herzegovina.

Evolution of the Effectiveness of CESEE Justice Systems and Property Rights Protection

This section reviews the evolution of judicial effectiveness in all the 20 CESEE countries covered. We include the rule of law indicator, for which data are available starting in the 1990s; indicators on the judiciary’s efficiency, independence, and impartiality; and protection of property rights, for which data start in the 2000s. The data show significant progress as well as setbacks over the past two decades, as seen in the case studies.10 The average standard deviation across indicators from different sources measuring judicial system effectiveness and protection of property rights provides an indication of whether different sources of information agree (Figure 2.22). For some countries, the differences are relatively small, suggesting that there is broad consensus, while for others, indicators from different sources vary significantly, suggesting greater uncertainty and hence the need for a more cautious assessment.

Figure 2.22.
Figure 2.22.

Consistency of Similar Indicators from Different Sources1

(Standard deviation)

Sources: Varieties of Democracy Institute (V-Dem); World Bank, Doing Business; World Economic Forum (WEF); and IMF staff calculations.Note: Data labels use International Organization for Standardization (ISO) country abbreviations.1 Standard deviations are calculated across different indicators, ranked by percentiles of the distribution and then averaged over time. For the judicial system, the following indices are used: judicial independence and impartiality of courts from the WEF and judicial accountability from the V-Dem. For the protection of property rights, indices used are protection of property rights from the WEF, protection of property rights from the Heritage Foundation, and enforcement of contracts from the World Bank’s Doing Business Indicators.

CEPEJ data indicate that CESEE EU countries perform well in terms of justice system efficiency compared with the EU15, but there is significant heterogeneity. CEPEJ hard data indicate that CESEE EU countries, on average, have slightly higher resolution rates compared with CESEE non-EU countries, or even the EU15 (Figure 2.23). For insolvency cases, however, the resolution rate in CESEE non-EU countries is significantly lower than in EU countries. Further, substantial variation exists, with the Czech Republic and Slovenia at the high end of the spectrum and Croatia and Romania at the low end. Disposition time data show comparable efficiency levels in CESEE-EU countries and the EU15, with similar variation within the two groups. Other efficiency indicators presented by the EU Justice Scoreboard also point to some CESEE EU countries having greater judicial efficiency than some of the EU15 countries (EC 2017). CESEE non-EU countries have longer disposition times and hence overall lower efficiency.

Figure 2.23.
Figure 2.23.

CESEE: Case Resolution Rate and Disposition Time, 20141

Source: European Commission for the Efficiency of Justice.Note: EU15 countries are listed in text footnote 1.1 For resolution rate: values higher than 100 indicate that more cases are resolved than received. For disposition time: higher values indicate higher theoretical duration for a court to solve the pending cases. Criminal cases are excluded.

Despite significant progress, the CESEE’s perceived judicial indicators on average still appear weaker than in the EU15. Comparing the four indicators presented in Figure 2.24, the perceived differences between the CESEE and the EU15 average are smallest for the rule of law and largest for judicial independence. The 2016 Eurobarometer Survey suggests that the perceived independence of courts and judges among the general public and companies is lower in CESEE-EU countries than in the EU15 (though with significant in-group variations), which is attributed to greater interference by governments or politicians (Figure 2.25). This is despite the fact that the EU Justice Scoreboard suggests that CESEE-EU countries do not significantly deviate in terms of de jure safeguards of judicial independence from the EU15.11 Typically, CESEE-EU countries perform better than CESEE non-EU countries.

Figure 2.24.
Figure 2.24.

Europe: The Rule of Law and Some of Its Components

(Lighter blue = better; darker blue = worse)1

Sources: World Bank, Worldwide Governance Indicators (rule of law); World Economic Forum (protection of property rights, judicial independence, impartiality of courts); and IMF staff calculations.Note: Data on judicial independence, impartiality of courts, and protection of property rights are not available for Kosovo.1 The percentiles are defined based on the worldwide rankings of available countries excluding low-income countries.
Figure 2.25.
Figure 2.25.

Perceived Independence of Courts, 20171

(Percent)

Source: Eurobarometer.Note: EU15 countries are listed in text footnote 1.1 Percentage of respondents that ranked independence of courts in their country as fairly or very good.

Cross-country variations are significant for all four indicators, with the best-performing CESEE countries perceived to have judicial indicators exceeding those of some EU15 countries. Importantly, while many CESEE countries are in the middle two quartiles of the global distribution for the rule of law indicator, 10 or 11 CESEE countries are in the lower quartile for the other three indicators, broadly in line with the case study findings and GRECO’s evaluations. There are also up to three EU15 countries in the lower quartile for judicial independence and impartiality, in line with GRECO reports that note concerns arising especially regarding judicial independence and impartiality in over a third of CoE member countries (CoE 2015, 2016).

Regulatory enforcement in CESEE countries seems weaker than de jure indicators suggest. On average, the CESEE countries in the study rank around the 57th percentile of the rule of law index global distribution. However, the region ranks lower, around the 48th percentile, on the regulatory enforcement index compiled by the World Justice Project. This suggests weaker performance in regulatory enforcement in CESEE countries than the performance in establishing the regulatory framework. GRECO (2017) finds that while solid legal and institutional foundations have been established on paper, in many CESEE countries effective implementation is lacking. The Global Integrity Report also estimates a large gap between the regulatory framework and its actual implementation in the region—on average about 30 percentage points—that is similar to the report’s estimates for emerging market economies.

Despite much progress, the pace of improvement appears to have slowed or even reversed since the global financial crisis.

  • In general, countries farther behind have recorded larger improvements in judicial indicators since 2001 (Figure 2.26).

  • While the perceived rule of law has continued to improve in several CESEE countries in recent years, in about half of them the pace of improvement has slowed or even reversed since 2007, as shown in the case studies (Figure 2.27). The evolution is worse for the other indicators, especially for judicial impartiality and independence.

  • These findings are consistent with those of other authors highlighting a slowdown or reversal of judicial reforms and anticorruption efforts after EU accession (Mungiu-Pippidi 2015; EBRD 2013, 2016). Aslund and Djankov (2014) maintain that several of Bulgaria’s and Hungary’s reforms have proved vulnerable,12 and the EC recently registered concern about Poland’s judicial independence.

Figure 2.26.
Figure 2.26.

CESEE: Evolution of the Elements of the Rule of Law

Sources: World Bank, Worldwide Governance Indicators; World Economic Forum; and IMF staff calculations.Note: EU15 countries are listed in text footnote 1.
Figure 2.27.
Figure 2.27.

CESEE: Evolution of Institutions before and after 2007

Sources: World Bank, Worldwide Governance Indicators; World Economic Forum; and IMF staff calculations.

Main Findings

This section presents the main findings from all the strands of analysis carried out in this chapter, including some econometric evidence. It draws from the case studies, the judicial indicators, and regressions covering all advanced and emerging market economies that explore the determinants of judicial independence and protection of property rights in a global setting. Panel regressions were estimated with five-year, nonoverlapping averages using model specifications based on the conceptual framework presented earlier in this chapter (Box 2.4).

This chapter finds empirical support for the importance of the distribution of resources and of opportunities for strengthening judicial systems and the protection of property rights.

  • From the case studies, countries that managed to prevent large increases in inequality and the emergence of oligarchic structures attained better institutions (see also Guriev 2017).13 Policies implemented as part of the transition, such as privatization, deregulation, restructuring of SOEs, and implementation of competition policies, had a considerable impact on income inequality and on preventing the emergence of oligarchic structures, a finding that Djankov (2014b) also highlights. In particular, the way privatization was conducted played a significant role in resource distribution, with implications for institutional quality. For example, most members of Romania’s elite used insider knowledge, political power, and control over state resources to solidify their control over the economy during privatization, resulting in a much higher Gini coefficient by the late 1990s and contributing to considerable resistance to judicial reforms (Gabanyi 2004). In contrast, Estonia’s privatization, which aimed to put assets into the hands of those with the incentives and skills to use them effectively, combined with wide participation across society, appears to have been vital for Estonia’s success in institution building. In Serbia, members of the business elite managed to increase their control over resources, undermining judicial independence. In Poland and Hungary, far-reaching policies to liberalize trade and commercial activities succeeded in demonopolizing the economy early in the transition, which may have aided judicial independence and control of corruption (Slay 1995).14 But setbacks also occurred in several countries, as documented in the case studies and in the indicators. EBRD (2016) links these to a perceived unfair distribution of earlier reform gains, and Aslund and Djankov (2014) attribute some of the deterioration to the influence of business groups with strong ties to the government. In some cases, the private sector may also influence the independence of the courts directly.

  • As in several previous empirical studies, the econometric work for this chapter finds that the Gini coefficient has a negative correlation with judicial institutions, but is not always statistically significant. However, a broader index of resource distribution—which besides income equality also includes equality of access to education and healthcare and the distribution of power among different socioeconomic groups—has a more robust association with higher independence of the judiciary and better protection of property rights.

The capacity of the public administration is critical to achieving judicial independence and overall effectiveness. In several countries, for example in Kosovo and Poland, rapid changes in the legal framework, an increasing number of court cases, and opportunities for better-paid jobs emerging in the private sector (especially for legal, finance, and economist professions) initially put pressure on the capacity of the judiciary. In almost all the cases studies, the creation of an independent, self-governing body responsible for recruiting and selecting magistrates helped limit political involvement in selecting and disciplining judges. While most countries in the case studies created, de jure, an independent self-governing body, de facto independence varied significantly across countries. Ensuring the independence of the self-governing body was easier in countries such as Estonia that early on managed to replace most of the communist-era political appointees in important judiciary positions. However, the case studies show that in countries where replacement of judges with integrity problems or political connections was not comprehensive, an antireform alliance formed among judges worried about losing their jobs and political parties that wanted to keep control over the justice system. This appears to have been the case in Romania and Serbia early in the transition, and it delayed the establishment of a de facto independent self-governing body. Where a qualified and professional bureaucracy was established, the effectiveness of the judiciary was fostered and de jure reforms appeared to be implemented more successfully. The variable capturing merit-based procedures to recruit and promote civil servants has a robust association with judicial independence and property rights protection in the regressions.

Transparency and accountability mechanisms feature prominently in the case studies, and they seem to play a particularly important role when the environment is unfavorable to robust institutions. Transparency took many forms. For example, Estonia’s publishing of formal coalition agreements contributed to the continuation of reforms despite frequent government changes. In Croatia, the publication of results of surveys on the judicial system enabled public scrutiny and helped catalyze reforms. Romania’s civil society organizations used the freedom of information legislation adopted during the EU accession process to expose politicians’ dishonest behavior, facilitating judicial reforms. In Ukraine, legal reforms requiring the identification of ultimate beneficiaries made bank owners liable for losses from related-party lending. Freedom of information gets some support in our econometric analysis in line with earlier results (IMF 2005; Borner, Bodmer, and Kobler 2004), and its marginal impact rises when resource distribution or public administration capacity are not conducive to robust institutions. These findings echo others’ findings that transparency, especially related to fiscal issues, including public procurement, increases the effectiveness of laws that otherwise exist only on paper (Mungiu-Pippidi and Dadasov 2017; OECD 2014). To improve the efficiency of the judiciary, GRECO recommends transparency in the recruitment, promotion, and case assignments of judges and in measures of judicial system performance.

In line with the literature, openness tends to be positively associated with judicial independence and protection of property rights. Estonia’s experience suggests that substantial reductions in trade tariffs and nontariff barriers, elimination of export restrictions, and guarantees for equal rights for both foreign and domestic investors during the privatization process facilitated institutional reforms by increasing competition and discouraging rent seeking. In Poland, the Balcerowicz Plan replaced import restrictions and foreign trade monopolies with tariffs (IMF 2014), thereby reducing opportunities for rent seeking. Foreign ownership of banks also fostered competitive credit allocation and limited connected lending, for example in Estonia and Poland, strengthening the constituency for more rules-based institutions (Poghosyan and Poghosyan 2010; Bonin, Hasan, and Wachtel 2005; Nikiel and Opiela 2002). In the regressions, lower barriers to trade and the institutional quality of trading partners have a significant positive correlation with judicial independence and the protection of property rights.

The case studies suggest that the European Union and the CoE played different roles as external anchors, depending on the dynamics of domestic factors affecting institutional quality. In countries like Estonia, with strong domestic fundamentals for effective institutions, institutional reforms were largely domestically driven and used EU and CoE standards as benchmarks. In countries where domestic fundamentals were not as conducive to effective institutions, such as, Croatia, Romania, and Serbia, the European Union and the CoE helped overcome political resistance to reforms. While EU-driven reforms initially were largely de jure, they did facilitate improvements in domestic fundamentals as well, and ultimately in the judiciary’s de facto effectiveness. In Croatia and Serbia, incentives from EU accession coupled with recommendations by CoE monitoring bodies helped establish magistrates’ self-governing bodies. However, when the incentives offered by the European Union were viewed as unattractive, as in Serbia in 2005–07, anti-EU political parties blocked reforms. For Croatia and Romania, EU conditionality was instrumental for the adoption of a judicial reform strategy aimed at separating the judiciary and the political branches of government. Also, the European Union and the CoE continue to encourage reforms via, for example, the Cooperation and Verification Mechanism for Bulgaria and Romania. Some previous studies also support the view that the EU “anchor” played a positive role for institutional improvement (IMF 2005; EBRD 2013; Mulas-Granados, Koranchelian, and Segura-Ubiergo 2008), though Mungiu-Pippidi (2015) warns that the EU impact is limited if reforms are implemented as bureaucratic requirements and do not engage civil society and change domestic agents’ incentives. In the regression, the EU impact is captured via trading partners’ institutional quality, which is found to be significant for judicial independence, but not for property rights protection.

Additional noneconomic factors that appear to matter for judicial effectiveness and property rights protection are

  • Societal fragmentation: In Bosnia and Herzegovina, Croatia, and Serbia, long wars delayed the transition, and societal fragmentation stifled judicial reforms. Also, fragmentation along rural and urban population lines may have complicated institutional reforms in Poland and contributed to reform reversals in other countries. These results are in line with the literature (Guriev 2017). The negative association of the old-age dependency ratio with institutional quality may reflect difficulties in solving collective action problems in societies with a large share of retirees who may favor the status quo and oppose reforms with long-term payoffs.15

  • The strength of civil society, which appears to help judicial reforms, as illustrated in Estonia, Poland, and Romania: Some authors (Bakolias 2000; Mungiu-Pippidi 2017; Rodríguez-Ferreira 2013) argue that civil society is critical to supporting effective justice systems, for example by fostering public debate, increasing awareness, and demanding transparency and accountability.

  • Favoritism in politics, which has a strong negative link to judicial independence and property rights protection in the regressions: Clientelism enables some groups to capture institutions, as found in the case studies. At times, state-owned banks were an important conduit of weak governance. Ukraine’s experience suggests that high levels of corruption and entrenched vested interests impede governance and judicial reforms. In Poland, instances of corruption among the judiciary and members of the political elite during 1998–2003 coincided with the perceived deterioration in judicial independence. The power struggles between different groups are deemed a cause for the ups and downs in judicial reforms in most of the case studies. A 2017 GRECO report attributes implementation gaps in many CESEE countries’ legal frameworks to remaining corruption and clientelism among those who wish to preserve their grip on power and the status quo. Surveys such as the 2017 EU Justice Scoreboard also point to political pressure as one of the main reasons for perceived lack of judicial independence.

Conclusion

CESEE countries significantly strengthened the effectiveness of judicial systems and property rights protection, though achievements varied across countries, and progress was not linear. Looking ahead, a number of countries aspire to join the European Union. For these countries, but also for others seeking to improve the effectiveness of their judiciary and institutions, the main policy insights from the case studies, indicators, and econometric analysis are

  • The importance of distributional factors in countries’ success in judicial reforms calls for careful examination of the distributional impact of policies. The way privatization was implemented, as well as the opening up of the economy, had a critical bearing on whether a few dominant players emerged or more balanced economic structures prevailed. This had attendant implications for judicial effectiveness, especially for independence and impartiality. This calls for careful consideration of the distributional implications of all policies and other drivers of inequality and argues for reforms that can help ensure a level playing field. Strong enforcement of competition rules and lower trade and entry barriers can reduce monopolistic power. Redistributive fiscal policies can be another policy lever, with attention also given to equality of opportunities.

  • Selecting and promoting public officials (judicial and otherwise) strictly on merit and strengthening the independence of the civil service can improve institutional quality.

  • Countries’ experiences suggest that better transparency and accountability can foster reforms. Besides freedom of information legislation, economic policies that can contribute to transparency include fiscal transparency, accountability on the use of public resources, e-government, financial disclosures of public officials, and transparency of ownership structures of financial and nonfinancial corporations. The impact of transparency and accountability seems stronger when other fundamentals were not conducive to high institutional quality, suggesting that this could be an area that presents several entry points for policymakers.

  • The European Union and the CoE played a key role as external anchors, though the sustainability of reforms rested more on domestic factors. In countries with domestically driven reforms, EU and CoE legal standards acted as a benchmark for high institutional quality. In countries with a limited domestic drive for institutional reforms, the incentive of EU membership helped overcome some political resistance to reforms, though setbacks were common. EU conditionality helped align domestic legal frameworks to those of the European Union. While this generated de jure changes, de facto improvements appear to have followed a less linear path. Yet in many cases, EU and CoE standards facilitated improvements in domestic factors conducive to institutional reforms. For example, the adoption of freedom of information laws enabled civil society to be more successful in exposing rent-seeking behavior of government officials. The European Union and the CoE continue to play a catalytic role through technical assistance and enforcement procedures, though their effectiveness after accession may be more limited.

  • IMF-supported program cases also indicated that operating on domestic levers can help nudge institutional reforms. The IMF can enhance its analysis of distributional impacts and promote policies that favor a more equal distribution of resources and opportunities. Its technical assistance can help strengthen state capacity in many ways, though other institutions are more active in overall civil service reform. The IMF can contribute to transparency in many ways—for example, via comparative analyses, standard setting, data, fiscal and financial transparency, and anti-money-laundering initiatives, as well as in increasing accountability mechanisms.

  • Many of these factors interacted with each other due to important feedback loops, suggesting that there can be several entry points for policy intervention. “The insight that ‘everything matters’ can be both paralyzing and empowering” (Taler and Sunstein 2009). Transparency presents many opportunities for nudges to start a virtuous cycle.

These findings are tentative, and more work is needed to understand institutional reforms. Judicial effectiveness and property rights protection, as well as a host of socioeconomic factors that may determine them, are inherently difficult to measure and assess. Complex political economy interactions affect reforms, making it hard to uncover how agreement was reached and maintained. More work is needed to understand factors and policies that affect the balance of power and increase the chances that institutional reforms are undertaken, make a difference in practice, and are sustained.

Institutions and Economic Outcomes

Effective institutions, which encompass an effective rule of law, play a key role in promoting more equitable and sustainable growth. A well-documented stylized fact is that societies with high institutional quality tend to be more prosperous. Several authors identify causal effects from institutions to per capita income and underscore that differences in institutional quality can explain cross-country variations in economic development. The World Bank’s 2017 World Development Report argues that peace, justice, and strong institutions (UN Sustainable Development Goal (SDG) 16) hold “important instrumental value because the attainment of the goal will aid in the attainment of all the other SDGs.” It highlights that “the achievement of all the SDGs will require a solid understanding of governance to enable more effective policies.”

Institutions foster equitable and sustainable growth through several channels. The main ones include

  • Ensuring more equal access to opportunities—a level playing field—and appropriate rewards to those who provide labor, capital, and ideas.

  • Providing checks and balances that discourage rent-seeking behavior and promote more efficient/fairer use of public resources and better government services. Checks and balances make decision making less dependent on individuals, thereby limiting policies that benefit only particular interest groups.

  • Securing a high level of responsiveness to citizens’ preferences and demands, which is key for building public trust in government and institutions, thus facilitating consensus around growth-enhancing reforms.

Institutions can affect growth by enhancing commitment and collective action (World Bank 2017). These factors are particularly relevant for investment and efficiency. The first factor, commitment, involves preparing an environment where firms and individuals feel secure to invest resources in productive activities. The second factor, trust and collective action, pertains to the ability to form partnerships and undertake specialization in production and correct potential market failures (World Bank 2017). Recent microeconomic studies provide evidence for these mechanisms and highlight how institutions affect factors of production. We focus on the following three direct channels, recognizing that they are also interrelated:

  • Labor: Empirical studies have found a strong effect of weak institutions and governance on the emigration of skilled workers (Cooray and Schneider 2016). Similarly, Atoyan and others (2016) argue that better institutions hold the promise of retaining and slowing emigration of skilled workers.

  • Investment: In the absence of effective protection of property rights, incentives for investment and innovation will be harmed. Micro studies find that firms that feel more secure from the threat of expropriation invest a larger share of their profits in their business (Johnson and others 2002). Institutions also affect foreign direct investment, which in turn affects productivity and technology adoption (Bénassy-Quéré, Coupet, and Mayer 2007; Bevan and Estrin 2004).

  • Efficiency (total factor productivity): The theory predicts that institutions affect innovation and productivity through enhanced trust, cooperation, commitment, and contract enforcement (World Bank 2017). The rule of law is critical, as weaknesses in contract enforcement prevent specialization and optimal allocation of labor and capital (North 1990), which stifles total factor productivity. Firms and workers are hesitant to specialize if they are not sure whether all parties will adhere to the agreed contract. As market size grows and products get more complicated, trust, specialization, coordination, and enforcement of contracts matter more (Dixit 2007; World Bank 2017). Better contract enforcement helps firms expand their pool of suppliers by enhancing trust between unknown parties (Johnson and others 2002).

Institutions also affect intermediate variables that matter for growth, including but not limited to

  • Government expenditure, revenue, and services: For a government to collect taxes needed to provide public goods, its citizens must be willing to comply and cooperate. Legitimacy and cooperation are maximized if the rule of law is applied consistently, trust is built, and decision-making processes are inclusive (World Bank 2017). Weak institutions and governance can lead to forgone tax revenue, larger unofficial economy size (IMF 2016a), and government’s inability to deliver quality public services (World Bank 2017). Studies show that better public investment management institutions—transparent procurement and project appraisal processes—are associated with more efficient public infrastructure and higher absorption of EU funds (IMF 2016a).

  • Access to credit: The strength of the legal system in credit protection and collateral execution affects how much financing creditors are willing to extend (Townsend 1979; Aghion and Bolton 1992; Hart and Moore 1994). Similarly, better contract enforcement is associated with higher lending and fewer defaults (Bianco and others 2005). In addition, weak debt enforcement and ineffective insolvency frameworks tend to lower recovery values of problem loans (IMF 2015).

  • Economic resilience: The ability to withstand negative shocks is affected by institutions because they govern the quality of policies and their implementation (OECD 2016). Better institutions are associated with greater fiscal policy countercyclicality (Frankel, Vegh, and Vuletin 2013) and with more effective monetary policy transmission (Mishra and others 2014). Countries with stronger protection of property rights are found to have lower probability of market crashes (Blau 2017). Better policies and institutions may enable countries to avoid or withstand episodes of debt distress (Kraay and Nehru 2006; IMF 2017a).

  • Some credit rating agencies and capital market participants acknowledge the importance of institutions and governance for macroeconomic stability and sovereign risk assessment (for example, Standard and Poor’s 2011, 2013; Moody’s 2016; Briegel and Bruinshoofd 2016, Bruinshoofd 2016).

Institutions have an important impact on inequality and inclusive growth. Corruption can undermine the state’s ability to deliver inclusive economic growth through its adverse effect on macro and financial stability, lower investment, and reduced human capital accumulation and social spending (IMF 2016a, 2017a). Effective institutions enhance cooperation and trust, making it easier to undertake reforms, collect taxes, and provide quality public services, thus helping achieve more sustainable growth (World Bank 2017).

Many cross-country studies suggest a causal relationship from institutions to growth. While it is likely that causality runs both ways (Barro 2015), or that some third factor (such as accumulated physical and human capital) affects both institutions and growth, several cross-country studies provide evidence that institutions matter for long-term growth (Mauro 1995; Hall and Jones 1999; Acemoğlu, Johnson, and Robinson 2001; and Banerjee and Iyer 2005). To overcome the challenge of endogeneity of institutions, these studies focus on differences in strength of certain institutions—for example, property rights that were driven by exogenous factors such as culture or historical events. Acemoğlu, Johnson, and Robinson (2001), for example, used European mortality rates during colonization as an instrument for current institutions and estimated large effects of institutions on income per capita. Nonetheless, disagreements remain. Several papers challenge the measurement of institutions (Hoyland, Moene, and Willumsen 2012; Donchev and Ujhelyi 2014) or argue that the instruments used to identify causal effects are not appropriate (Docquier 2014). A large body of social science literature deals with two-way linkages between economic and political institutions and the sequencing of reforms. Changes in state capacity or partial improvement in property rights could jump-start development and lead to citizens demanding better institutions (Fukuyama and Levy 2010; Fukuyama 2008).

Prepared by Faezeh Raei.

The Process of European Union Membership and the Rule of Law

Nineteen countries of Central, Eastern, and Southeastern Europe (CESSEE) are associated with the European Union (EU) in various forms. Eleven are EU members (Bulgaria, Croatia, Czech Republic, Estonia, Hungary, Latvia, Lithuania, Poland, Romania, Slovenia, Slovak Republic), five are candidates (Albania, Macedonia, Montenegro, Serbia, Turkey), and two are potential candidates (Bosnia and Herzegovina, Kosovo) (Figure 2.2.1). Potential candidates have the prospect of joining the European Union, but have not yet been granted candidate-country status, and their relationship with the European Union is governed by the Stabilization and Association Agreements.1 In 2017, Ukraine entered an association agreement with the European Union.

Figure 2.2.1.
Figure 2.2.1.

CESEE: Timeline of European Union Accession

Source: European Commision.1 Turkey signed an Association Agreement with the European Economic Community (predecessor of the EU) on September 12, 1963.2 Ukraine fully implemented an Association Agreement with the European Union on September 1, 2017. The Association Agreement was negotiated between 2007 and 2011 and signed in 2014. Substantial parts of the Association Agreement have been applied provisionally since November 1, 2014, and January 1, 2016, for the Deep and Comprehensive Free Trade Area.

The EU accession process entails aligning local laws and institutions with EU laws. The rule of law, together with other political, economic, and institutional criteria (the Copenhagen criteria) must be fulfilled by countries in order to join the European Union. The accession process follows a series of formal steps from a preaccession agreement to membership candidacy, the negotiation phase, ratification of the final accession treaty, and, finally, membership. The process requires the adoption of EU laws and preparations to be able to properly apply such laws, known as the Acquis Communautaire. The Acquis is divided into 35 chapters for negotiations between the European Union and candidate states. Each chapter covers a major aspect of EU policy, such as free movement of goods, capital, and workers; economic policy; energy; transportation; regional and foreign policy; fundamental rights; and the judicial system. Chapter 23 of the Acquis, Judiciary and Fundamental Rights, deals with the judicial system.

The Judiciary and Fundamental Rights chapter requires reforming the judicial system to ensure its independence and efficiency. It promotes the establishment of an independent, effective, and impartial judiciary to effectively safeguard the rule of law. In particular, it requires eliminating external influences over the judiciary, putting in place legal guarantees for fair trial procedures, and providing adequate financial resources and training. Relatedly, members are required to deter and fight corruption effectively, since corruption represents a threat to the rule of law.

Specific benchmarks guide transposing the chapter on Judiciary and Fundamental Rights into local law and the country’s institutional setup. For most chapters, the European Union sets what are called closing benchmarks, which need to be fulfilled by adopting laws and putting in place institutions. These benchmarks fall into two interlinked categories: (1) independence, accountability, and transparency of the judicial system and protection of property rights; and (2) fighting high-level corruption. Some recommended actions include establishing a judicial inspectorate to monitor the integrity of the judicial system and follow up on complaints; legal provisions for independent staffing of the inspectorate; random assignment of judicial cases to reduce political influence; and merit-based guidelines for the progression of judicial staff. Some recommended actions related to the prevention of high-level corruption include (1) establishing a specialized institution for the prosecution of high-level corruption; (2) independent staffing of such an institution; (3) creating legal provisions for whistle-blowers; (4) implementing a system to verify asset declarations of public officials; (5) investigating inexplicable wealth; and (6) publishing statistics on investigation and conviction cases.

The process of reforming the judiciary in line with the chapter on Judiciary and Fundamental Rights could extend well beyond EU accession. Creating and maintaining an independent and impartial judiciary and administration is a long-term process. For this reason, the European Commission allows some of the required actions to take place after accession by setting interim benchmarks and through continuous monitoring and progress reports. For example, a Cooperation and Verification Mechanism has been in place in Bulgaria and Romania to monitor and guide reforms of the judicial system and fight corruption after those countries joined the European Union in 2007. As European Commission reports indicate, despite progress, efforts are still needed to demonstrate a track record, finalize the adoption of legal codes, and ensure the implementation of court decisions in these countries.

The European Union also has a framework aimed at respecting and strengthening the rule of law in all its members. If the mechanisms established to secure the rule of law at the national level cease to operate effectively, there is a systemic threat to the rule of law and, hence, to the functioning of the European Union (EC 2010). In such situations, the European Commission can act to protect the rule of law by launching infringement procedures and activating Article 7 of the Treaty of the European Union. Given, however, the very high thresholds for activating Article 7, a new framework aimed at preventing the emergence of a systemic threat to the rule of law was enacted in 2014 (EC 2014).

Prepared by Faezeh Raei and Vizhdan Boranova.

1 The Stabilization and Association Agreements set out additional conditions for membership for the Western Balkan countries with the aim to (1) stabilize the countries politically and encourage their swift transition to a market economy, (2) promote regional cooperation, and (3) attain eventual membership in the European Union.

Specific Reforms to the Rule of Law in IMF-Supported Programs: Kosovo and Ukraine

This box focuses on specific reforms in Kosovo and Ukraine in the context of IMF-supported programs. The reforms have a narrower focus—control of corruption in Ukraine and clearing court backlogs in Kosovo. Their experiences highlight the difficulty in making progress in judicial reforms and the need to learn by doing and adapting to the local context. External actors have the strongest impact when they support domestic reform actors.

Ukraine

Corruption and oligarchic structures thwart improvements in the rule of law in Ukraine. Multiple data sources suggest that corruption is more prevalent in Ukraine than in other countries of Central, Eastern, and Southeastern Europe (CESSEE) or the European Union (EU) (IMF 2017b). Less-active civil society groups, flawed and minimal privatization, and weak initial reform strategies are often cited as reasons for the lack of progress (Yemelianova 2010; Valdai Discussion Club 2014). Vested interests continue to resist reform, and political fragmentation makes progress more challenging, but civil society is currently quite active and gathering support and is calling attention to corruption.

The IMF-supported program in Ukraine focuses on tackling corruption. Reforms have included (1) the independent National Anti-Corruption Bureau of Ukraine (NABU), (2) comprehensive asset declarations for high-level officials, and (3) a business ombudsman. Over 85 cases have been sent to court by the NABU, financial assets have been seized, and prominent figures have been arrested. However, there have been no major convictions yet. The program includes policies to reduce opportunities for corruption by streamlining business licenses, improving public procurement, bringing energy prices to import parity, overhauling tax administration, cleaning up the banking system, and putting in place an effective anti-money-laundering framework. But additional efforts are needed to address the perception of impunity.

Progress in the reform of state-owned enterprises has been limited, although progress has been made in the banking sector. Weak governance of state-owned enterprises has led to inefficiencies and corruption. Amendments to the privatization law were adopted in January 2016, but no large state-owned enterprises have been privatized. A new law on governance of these enterprises requires independent supervisory boards and adequate auditing principles. Ukraine has oligarch-owned banks, which use deposits to fund dubious related-party transactions (Baum and others 2008). Weaknesses in the rule of law and supervisory powers made it difficult to effectively control the banks, which allowed some owners to earn fictitious profits at the expense of taxpayers and depositors. A break came in 2014–15, when reform-oriented management was appointed at the National Bank of Ukraine (NBU), which saw its independence and powers strengthened (due in part to prior actions under the IMF Extended Fund Facility). Legal reforms required the identification of ultimate beneficiary owners, made bank owners liable for related-party lending losses, and shifted the burden of proof from the NBU to the banks. The NBU has closed nearly 90 of 180 banks since 2014, and the largest private bank was recently nationalized, but firmer efforts to collect related-party loans are needed.

Kosovo

Although Kosovo has a short history with institution-building, some progress has been made in improving the court system. The most recent IMF-supported program emphasized Kosovo’s inefficient court system as a major impediment to bank lending and growth. Kosovo’s courts had large case backlogs due to low institutional capacity, weak management, and poor incentives. Creditors could not efficiently obtain and enforce judgments and hence required more collateral and higher lending rates.

The authorities decided to confront the backlog of open cases (Figure 2.3.1). With help from the US Agency for International Development, the authorities (1) introduced a system of private enforcement agents that helped creditors enforce court judgments and recover assets and reduced the burden on courts; (2) established a centralized registry of bank account holders at the Central Bank of Kosovo, which enables the private enforcement agents to garnish accounts; and (3) improved court case resolution procedures. A large reduction in court cases was achieved. In parallel, private enforcement agents resolved numerous cases and recovered millions of dollars in assets. The progress in contract enforcement likely contributed to the sharp recent decline in lending rates. However, there are remaining gaps in judicial effectiveness, as debtors can sometimes sidestep enforcement actions.

Figure 2.3.1.
Figure 2.3.1.

Kosovo: Court Backlog Clearance under USAID Program

(Cumulative, thousands of court cases)

Source: US Agency for International Development (USAID) Contract Enforcement Program.
Prepared by Ricardo Llaudes, Brett Rayner, Pamela Madrid Angers, and Jason Weiss.

Econometric Analysis

We estimate panel regressions with five-year nonoverlapping averages with time dummies and random effects, conduct robustness checks, and attempt to mitigate endogeneity.

Dependent Variables

The main variables are judicial independence and protection of property rights indices from the World Economic Forum (WEF). For robustness, we also use the protection of property rights index from the Heritage Foundation and an indicator of court impartiality based on WEF data.

Explanatory Variables

To capture power asymmetries owing to the unequal distribution of resources and opportunities, we employ a composite indicator of resource distribution encompassing socioeconomic groups, education, health, and gender, with some of these aspects regressed separately as well. Also, we use indicators of market dominance, natural resource availability, and corruption in politics—the latter reflecting the prevalence of favoritism in politics. For the ability to solve collective action problems, we use the press freedom index, several measures of transparency and accountability, the old-age dependency ratio, and the urbanization rate. State capacity is represented by the variable covering the extent of established rules and procedures to hire and train government employees. We include trade barriers and trading partners’ institutional quality to analyze the role of external factors. We control for GDP per capita. The sample includes 26 advanced and 53 emerging market economies from 1990 to 2014.

The baseline econometric analysis provides support for some variables capturing power asymmetries, transparency, state capacity, and openness, as well as noneconomic factors (Table 2.4.1). We identify a positive association between institutional quality and more equal distribution of resources, higher information freedom, state capacity, lower trade barriers, trading partners’ institutional quality, and less corruption in politics. Another relatively new factor that seems to matter is the old-age dependency ratio, which is negatively associated with institutional quality.1 Perhaps this captures the higher demand for checks and balances in societies with a larger share of working-age population. Gorodnichenko and Roland (2011) emphasize that attitudes in societies change slowly due to culture. These findings are broadly in line with the more recent literature, which finds that many factors contribute to institutional quality (see EBRD 2013; Ganiou Mijiyawa 2013).

Table 2.4.1

Factors Affecting Institutional Quality

article image
Source: IMF staff estimates. Note: Robust standard errors in parentheses. *** p < 0.01; ** p < 0.05; * p < 0.1.

Some interaction terms between the explanatory variables matter. The positive impact of information freedom is larger when the quality of public administration is low, resources are more concentrated, or the level of GDP per capita is lower. This suggests that when resource distribution or public administration capacity is not conducive to strengthening institutions, the marginal impact of checks and balances imposed by information freedom on politicians and government officials rises.

The baseline results are fairly robust to various model specifications and alternative measures (see Annex 2.3). Market dominance indicators are strongly associated with both judicial independence and property rights protection, but their presence eliminates the significance of trade barriers. This is possibly because market power indicators and openness operate through the common channel of competition.

Alternative measures for property rights protection, resource distribution, trade openness, and transparency and accountability do not alter the results materially. Some measures of transparency and accountability, while having the expected sign, are not statistically significant. We could not identify a statistically significant correlation with the urbanization rate and educational attainment (though education opportunities are included in the composite indicator of resources and opportunities distribution). Dropping variables that might be considered as institutions themselves—corruption in politics, state capacity, and transparency and accountability—maintains the significance of variables capturing power asymmetries and openness.

Caveats abound, given difficulties in assessing the effectiveness of judicial systems and protection of property rights and the feedback loops between these institutions and their potential determinants. While we have used the instrumental variable approach by including lagged variables to mitigate the potential reverse causality between institutional quality and economic performance, some residual endogeneity bias is likely to remain. Cross-sectional regressions, however, broadly confirm the panel results. Controlling for GDP per capita addresses concerns that some of the identified associations might reflect the impact of better institutions on the explanatory variables through high income. However, other factors not included in our regressions may drive both the dependent and explanatory variables.

Prepared by Raju Huidrom, Mariusz Jarmuzek, and Ara Stepanyan. 1 Straub (2000) used life expectancy in a panel regression and identified a statistically significant positive association with institutional quality.

Annex 2.1. Institutions: Literature Review

Annex Table 2.1.1.

Summary of the Theoretical Literature on Institutions

article image
Annex Table 2.1.2.

Summary of the Empirical Literature on Institutions

article image
Annex Table 2.1.3.

Institutions and Economic Outcomes

article image

Annex 2.2. Indicators and Sources

In line with the IMF Board paper on the “Use of Third-Party Indicators (TPIs) in Fund Reports” (IMF 2017c), this annex describes the indicators used and their sources. Specific descriptions of indicators used are described in Annex Table 2.2.1.

Annex Table 2.2.1.

Description of Third-party Indicators

article image
article image

The World Bank’s Worldwide Governance Indicators

The Worldwide Governance Indicators draw on four different types of source data: surveys of households and firms, including the Afrobarometer surveys, the Gallup World Poll, and Global Competitiveness Report surveys; commercial business information providers, including the Economist Intelligence Unit, Global Insight, and Political Risk Services; nongovernmental organizations, including Global Integrity, Freedom House, and Reporters Without Borders; and public sector organizations, including the Country Policy and Institutional Assessments of the World Bank and regional development banks, the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development Transition Reports, and the French Ministry of Finance Institutional Profiles Database.

World Economic Forum Global Competitiveness Index

The Global Competitiveness Index is a composite index based on data largely obtained from an opinion survey asking business executives to evaluate aspects of their economy. The survey is conducted with the help of a network of 160 partner institutes that follow detailed sampling guidelines to ensure that the sample of respondents is the most representative possible and comparable. To improve comparability, 4 of 10 questionnaires are filled out by executives who have previously taken part in the survey. Official statistics are also used.

World Bank Doing Business Index

The Doing Business Index looks at domestic small and medium companies and measures the regulations applying to them through their life cycle. To provide different perspectives on the data, the index presents data both for individual indicators and for two aggregate measures: the distance to frontier score and the ease of doing business ranking. Doing Business uses a simple averaging approach for weighting component indicators, calculating rankings, and determining the distance to frontier score.

European Commission for the Efficiency of Justice (Commission européenne pour l’efficacité de la justice—CEPEJ)

The CEPEJ maintains a comprehensive database with data on judicial systems of Council of Europe member states for 2010, 2012, and 2014. The data are based on reports submitted by country authorities. Since 2008, the CEPEJ has implemented a peer evaluation process for the systems for judicial data collection and reporting in Council of Europe members. The CEPEJ data cover topics such as the budget of judicial systems and legal aid, professionals, courts and users, and the efficiency of the justice system.

Group of States Against Corruption (GRECO)

GRECO’s objective is to improve the capacity of its 49 member states to fight corruption by monitoring their compliance with the Council of Europe’s anticorruption standards and their effective implementation. GRECO uses a dynamic process of mutual evaluation and peer pressure. Its country-by-country evaluations identify deficiencies in national anti-corruption frameworks and make recommendations on addressing shortcomings, thus prompting the necessary legislative, institutional, and practical reforms. GRECO also produces evaluation reports that cover justice systems.

Varieties of Democracy Institute (V-Dem)

The V-Dem Project is a collaborative international effort that unites thousands of social scientists working in the sphere of democracy and governance. It is coordinated by the University of Gothenburg’s V-Dem Institute and the University of Notre Dame’s Kellogg Institute. Approximately half of the indicators in the V-Dem data set are based on factual information obtainable from official documents such as constitutions and government records. The other half consists of more subjective assessments on topics like political practices and compliance with de jure rules. On such issues, typically, five experts per country provide ratings. These experts are generally academics or professionals working in government, media, or public affairs. They are also generally nationals of and/or residents in the country and have documented knowledge of both that country and a specific substantive area.

International Country Risk Guide (ICRG)

The ICRG provides ratings based on indicators for countries that forecast political, financial, and economic risk. A separate index is created for each of the subcategories. This data set is produced by the PRS Group of Syracuse, New York. Political risk assessments are based on a compiler’s judgement, while financial and economic ratings are based on macro-financial data. Weights assigned to each variable and subcategory are predetermined and identical for every country.

Annex 2.3. Econometric Analysis: Additional Results

This annex presents three sets of robustness checks. First, some of the explanatory variables that could be considered measures of institutional quality themselves are removed from the regressions. Second, we examine additional variables, such as market dominance. Finally, we attempt to address endogeneity issues.

Following Acemoğlu and others (2003), who argue that historically determined components of institutions are slow-moving and can be considered exogenous, we do not include individual effects. The Breusch-Pagan test is employed to determine whether random effects should be included, with results broadly in favor of random effects. This serves as a benchmark for robustness checks.

Some of the explanatory variables in the baseline regressions—freedom of the press, impartiality of public administration, and corruption in politics—could also be considered as measures of institutional quality themselves. To address this concern, we remove each of these, one by one and all of them at the same time, from the set of explanatory variables, and reestimate the model. Variables capturing power asymmetries and openness remain significant (Annex Table 2.3.1). We also continue to find a statistically significant association with institutional quality of trading partners, old-age dependency, and per capita income.

Annex Table 2.3.1

Factors Affecting Institutional Quality: Dropping Variables

article image
Source: IMF staff estimates. Note: Robust standard errors in parentheses. *** p < 0.01; ** p < 0.05; * p < 0.1.

We tried adding corporate market dominance, as it could be a source of power asymmetries. Hence, excluding this measure could result in an omitted variable bias. We find a positive and significant association between market dominance and judicial independence and property rights protection (Annex Table 2.3.2). However, when openness and corporate market dominance are jointly included, openness is not always statistically significant, though the signs are as expected. This likely reflects the fact that openness affects competition, as does market dominance.

Annex Table 2.3.2.

Factors Affecting Institutional Quality: Adding Market Dominance

article image
Source: IMF staff estimates. Note: Robust standard errors in parentheses. *** p < 0.01; ** p < 0.05; * p < 0.1.

Finally, we try to mitigate endogeneity concerns by using lags of variables as instruments in a generalized methods of moments (GMM) framework. Since including lags of variables as instruments may not satisfactorily address endogeneity, we also try cross-sectional regressions, and regress the most recent five-year period for the dependent variables on longer lags (average over 1990–2000) of explanatory variables. We find that measures of resource distribution, openness, and the old-age dependency ratio remain associated with the expected sign with judicial independence and protection of property rights, even though they are not always statistically significant (Annex Table 2.3.3). Other explanatory variables (for example, impartiality of public administration and transparency) have the expected sign as in the baseline in most alternative specifications, but lose significance.

Annex Table 2.3.3.

Factors Affecting Institutional Quality: Endogeneity

article image
Source: IMF staff estimates. Note: Robust standard errors in parentheses. *** p < 0.01; ** p < 0.05; * p < 0.1.

References

  • Acemoğlu, Daron. 2005. “Constitutions, Politics, and Economics: A Review Essay on Persson and Tabellini’s the Economic Effects of Constitutions.” Journal of Economic Literature 43: 1025048.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Acemoğlu, Daron. 2006. “Modeling Inefficient Institutions.” NBER Working Paper No. 11940. National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Acemoğlu, Daron, and James Robinson. 2012. Why Nations Fail. Boston: Massachusetts Institute of Technology.

  • Acemoğlu, Daron, Simon Johnson, and James A. Robinson. 2001. “The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Empirical Investigation.” American Economic Review 91 (5): 1369401.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Acemoğlu, Daron, Simon Johnson, and James A. Robinson. 2002. “Reversal of Fortune: Geography and Institutions in the Making of the Modern World Income Distribution.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 117: 1231294.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Acemoğlu, Daron, Simon Johnson, and James A. Robinson. 2005. “Institutions as a Fundamental Cause of Long-run Growth.” In Handbook of Economic Growth Volume 1, Part A, edited by Philippe Aghion and Steven N. Durlaufn. Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Acemoğlu, Daron, Simon Johnson, James A. Robinson, and Yunyong Taicharoen. 2003. “Institutional Causes, Macroeconomic Symptoms: Volatility, Crises and Growth.” Journal of Monetary Economics 50: 49123.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Agh, Attila. 2004. Post-accession in East Central Europe. Budapest: Hungarian Centre for Democracy Studies Press.

  • Aghion, Philippe, and Patrick Bolton. 1992. “An Incomplete Contracts Approach to Financial Contracting.” The Review of Economic Studies 59 (3): 47394.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Alonso, José Antonio, and Carlos Garcimartín. 2013. “The Determinants of Institutional Quality. More on the Debate.” Journal of International Development 25 (2): 20626.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Andrews, Matt, Lant Pritchett, and Michael Woolcock. 2012. “Escaping Capability Traps through Problem-Driven Iterative Adaptation.” CGD Working Paper No. 299, Center for Global Development, Washington, DC.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Aslund, Anders and Simeon Djankov. 2014. “The Great Rebirth.” Washington, DC: Peterson Institute for International Economics.

  • Atoyan, Ruben, Lone Christiansen, Allan Dizioli, Christian Ebeke, Nadeem Ilahi, Anna Ilyina, Gil Mehrez, Haonan Qu, Faezeh Raei, Alaina Rhee, and Daria Zakharova. 2016. “Emigration and Its Economic Impact on Eastern Europe.” IMF Staff Discussion Note 16/07, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bacon, Wally. 2004. “Economic Reform.” In Romania since 1989: Politics, Economics, and Society, edited by Henry F. Carey. Lanham, MD: Lexington Books.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bakolias, Maria. 2000. “Legal and Judicial Development: The Role of Civil Society in the Reform Process.” Fordham International Law Journal 24 (6): 2655.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Banerjee, Abhijit, and Lakshmi Iyer. 2005. “History, Institutions, and Economic Performance: The Legacy of Colonial Land Tenure Systems in India.” American Economic Review 95 (4): 1190213.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Banfield, Edward. 1958. “The Moral Basis of a Backward Society.” Research Center in Economic Development and Cultural Change, University of Chicago.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Barro, Robert J. 2015. “Convergence and Modernization.” The Economic Journal 125: 91142.

  • Bartlett, William. 2007. The Western Balkans. Varieties of Capitalism in the Post-communist Countries. London: Palgrave.

  • Bartlett, William, Frank Bönker, and Zdravko Petak. 2014. “Sustainable Governance Indicators: 2014 Croatia Report.” Gütersloh: Bertelsmann Stiftung.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Baum, Christopher, Mustafa Caglayan, Dorothea Schäfer, and Oleksandr Talaveraet. 2008. “Political Patronage in Ukrainian Banking.” Boston College Working Paper in Economics No. 67, Boston.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Begović, Boris. 2013. “European Integrations and Serbian Economic Growth: Economic Integration as an Alternative to the EU Membership.” Anali Pravnog Fakulteta u Beogradu 61 (1): 5372.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Begović, Boris, and Dragor Hiber. 2006. “EU Democratic Rule of Law Promotion: The Case of Serbia.” Center on Democracy, Development and the Rule of Law, Stanford University, Palo Alto, CA.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bénassy-Quéré, Agnès, Maylis Coupet, and Tierry Mayer. 2007. “Institutional Determinants of Foreign Direct Investment.” The World Economy 30 (5): 76482.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Besley, Timothy, and Torsten Persson. 2009. “The Origins of State Capacity: Property Rights, Taxation, and Politics.” American Economic Review 99 (4): 1218244.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bevan, Alan A., and Saul Estrin. 2004. “The Determinants of Foreign Direct Investment into European Transition Economies.” Journal of Comparative Economics 32 (4): 77587.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bianco, Magda, Tullio Jappelli, and Marco Pagano. 2005. “Courts and Banks: Effects of Judicial Enforcement on Credit Markets.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 37 (2): 22344.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Blau, Benjamin M. 2017. “Economic Freedom and Crashes in Financial Markets.” Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions and Money 47 (March): 3346.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Blitz, Brat K. 2003. “Refugee Returns in Croatia: Contradictions and Reform.” SAGE Journals: Politics 23 (93): 18191.

  • Blokker, Paul. 2013. New Democracies in Crisis? A Comparative Constitutional Study of the Czech Republic, Hungary, Poland, Slovakia and Romania. London: Routledge.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bokros, Lajos. 2014. “Regression. Reform Reversal in Hungary After a Promising Start.” In The Great Rebirth, edited by Anders Aslund and Simeon Djankov. Washington, DC: Peterson Institute for International Economics.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bonin, John P., Iftekhar Hasan, and Paul Wachtel. 2005. “Privatization Matters: Bank Efficiency in Transition Countries.” Journal of Banking & Finance 29: 215578.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Borner, Silvio, Frank Bodmer, and Markus Kobler. 2004. “Institutional Efficiency and Its Determinants: The Role of Political Factors in Economic Growth.” OECD Development Centre, Paris.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Briegel, Fabian, and Allard Bruinshoofd. 2016. “Institutional Quality in Europe: Diverging Trends in Challenging Economic Times.” Rabobank Research Economic Report, Utrecht.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bruinshoofd, Allard. 2016. “Institutional Quality and Economic Performance.” Rabobank Research Economic Report, Utrecht.

  • Bruszt, László, Nauro F. Campos, Jan Fidrmuc, and Gérard Roland. 2009. “Civil Society, Institutional Change, and the Politics of Reform: The Great Transition.” In Economies in Transition. Studies in Development Economics and Policy, edited by G. Roland. London: Palgrave Macmillan.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Carnevali, Davide. 2013. “La Nuova Geografa Giudiziaria.” In Argomenti di Ordinamento Giudiziario, edited by D. Cavallini. Bologna: Bononia University Press.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Carp, Radu. 2007. “A Constitutional Principle under Scrutiny: The Immovability of Judges – Romanian Regulations in a Comparative Law Perspective.” In Judicial Reforms in Central and Eastern European Countries, edited by R. Coman and J.-M. De Waele. Brugge: Vanden Broele.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Chong, Alberto, and Luisa Zanforlin. 2000. “Law Tradition and Institutional Quality: Some Empirical Evidence.” Journal of International Development 12: 1057068.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Clague, Cristopher, Philip Keefer, Stephen Knack, and Mancur Olson. 1996. “Property and Contract Rights under Democracy and Dictatorship.” Journal of Economic Growth 1: 24376.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Coase, Ronald H. 1960. “The Problem of Social Cost.” Journal of Law and Economics 3 (October): 144.

  • Coman, Ramona. 2007. “Media, Justice and Politics or How the Independence of the Judiciary Became an Issue on the Romanian Political Agenda.” In Judicial Reforms in Central and Eastern European Countries, edited by R. Coman and J. M. De Wade. Brugge: Vanden Braele.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Coman, Ramona. 2009. “Reformer la Justice Dans un Pays Post-Communiste. Le Cas de la Roumanie.” University of Brussels, Brussels.

  • Cooray, Arusha, and Friedrich Schneider. 2016. “Does Corruption Promote Emigration? An Empirical Examination.” Journal of Population Economics 29 (1): 293310.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Council of Europe (CoE). 2015. “State of Democracy, Human Rights and the Rule of Law in Europe.” Report by the Secretary General of the Council of Europe, Strasbourg.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Council of Europe (CoE). 2016. “Challenges for Judicial Independence and Impartiality in the Member States of the Council of Europe.” Information Document, Council of Europe, Strasbourg.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dăianu, Daniel. 2004. “Fiscal and Monetary Policies.” In Romania since 1989: Politics, Economics, and Society, edited by Henry F. Carey. Lanham, MD: Lexington Books.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dallara, Cristina. 2007. “Judicial Reforms in Transition: Legacies of the Past and Dominant Political Actors in Post-Communist Countries.” IRSIG-CNR Working Paper, The Institute for Research on Judicial Systems, Bologna.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dallara, Cristina. 2010. “External and Internal Factors of Democratization in the Western Balkans.” Transitions 50 (1).

  • Dallara, Cristina. 2014. Democracy and Judicial Reforms in South-East Europe between the EU and the Legacies of the Past. New York: Springer International Publishing.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dell, Melissa. 2010. “The Persistent Effects of Peru’s Mining Mita.” Econometrica 78(6): 1863903.

  • Demsetz, Harold. 1967. “Toward a Theory of Property Rights.” The American Economic Review 57 (2): 34759.

  • Demsorean, Ana, Sorana Parvulescu, and Bogdan Vetrici-Soimu. 2009. “Romania: Vetoed Reforms, Skewed Results.” In International Actors, Democratization and the Rule of Law, edited by A. Magen and L. Morline. Routledge/UACES Contemporary European Studies.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dicosola, Maria. 2012. “Judicial Independence and Impartiality in Serbia: Between Law and Culture.” Diritti Comparati.

  • Dixit, Avinash K. 2007. Lawlessness and Economics: Alternative Modes of Governance. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

  • Djankov, Simeon. 2014a. “Bulgaria: The Greatest Vacillations.” In The Great Rebirth, edited by Anders Aslund and Simeon Djankov. Washington, DC: Peterson Institute for International Economics.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Djankov, Simeon. 2014b. “The Microeconomics of Postcommunist Transformation.” In The Great Rebirth, edited by Anders Aslund and Simeon Djankov. Washington, DC: Peterson Institute for International Economics.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Djankov, Simeon, Oliver Hart, Caralee McLiesh, and Andrei Shleifer. 2008. “Debt Enforcement around the World.” Journal of Political Economy 116 (December): 1105149.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Djankov, Simeon, Rafael La Porta, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, and Andrei Shleifer. 2002. “The Regulation of Entry.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 117: 137.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Djankov, Simeon, Rafael La Porta, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, and Andrei Shleifer. 2003. “Courts.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 118: 453517.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Docquier, Frédéric. 2014. “Identifying the Effect of Institutions on Economic Growth.” In Institutional Competition between Common Law and Civil Law: Theory and Policy, edited by H. Schmiegelow and M. Schmiegelow. New York: Springer.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Donchev, Dilyan, and Gergely Ujhelyi. 2014. “What do Corruption Indices Measure?Economics & Politics 26 (2): 30931.

  • Ekiert, Grzegorz, and George Soroka. 2013. “Pathways to Freedom. Poland: Political and Economic Lessons from Democratic Transitions.” Civil Society, Markets, and Democracy Initiative, Council on Foreign Relations, New York.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Esposito, Gianluca, Sergi Lanau, and Sebastian Pompe. 2014. “Judicial System Reform in Italy: A Key to Growth.” IMF Working Paper 14/32. International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD). 2013. “Transition Report 2013.” London.

  • European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD). 2014. “Commercial Laws of Bosnia and Herzegovina: An Assessment by the EBRD.” London.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD). 2016. “Transition Report 2016-17.” London.

  • European Commission (EC). 1997. “Regular Report from the Commission on Poland’s Progress Towards Accession.” Brussels.

  • European Commission (EC). 2002. “Regular Report from the Commission on Poland’s Progress Towards Accession.” Brussels.

  • European Commission (EC). 2005. “Regular Report from the Commission on Croatia’s Progress Towards Accession.” Brussels.

  • European Commission (EC). 2007. “Report from the Commission to the European Council and Parliament on Romania’s Progress on Accompanying Measures Following Accession.” Brussels.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • European Commission (EC). 2009. “Report from the Commission to the European Council and Parliament on Progress in Romania under the Co-operation and Verification Mechanism.” Brussels.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • European Commission (EC). 2016a. “Country Report Romania 2016: Including an In-Depth Review on the Prevention and Correction of Macroeconomic Imbalances.” Brussels.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • European Commission (EC). 2016b. “Serbia 2016 Report.” Brussels.

  • European Commission (EC). 2016c. “Bosnia and Herzegovina 2016 Report.” Brussels.

  • European Commission (EC). 2017a. “European Commission Launches Infringement Against Poland over Measures Affecting the Judiciary.” Press Release, Brussels.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • European Commission (EC). 2017b. “The 2017 EU Justice Scoreboard.” Publications Office of the European Union, Luxembourg.

  • European Commission for Efficiency of Justice (CEPEJ). 2016. “European Judicial Systems Efficiency and Quality of Justice 2016.” CEPEJ Study No. 23, Strasbourg.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • European Commission on Racism and Intolerance (ECRI). 1999. “European Commission Against Racism and Intolerance, Country Report on Estonia.” Strasbourg.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • European Commission on Racism and Intolerance (ECRI). 2015. “European Commission Against Racism and Intolerance, Country Report on Estonia.” Strasbourg.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Field, Lars P., and Stefan Voigt. 2003. “Economic Growth and Judicial Independence: Cross-country Evidence Using a New Set of Indicators.” European Journal of Political Economy 19 (3): 497527.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Field, Lars P., and Stefan Voigt. 2005. “How Does Judicial Independence Affect the Investment Climate?” In Investment Climate, Growth, and Poverty, edited by G. Kochendorfer-Lucius and B. Pleskovic. Washington, DC: World Bank.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Finer, Samuel E. 1997. The History of Government. Volumes I–III. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

  • Frankel, Jeffrey, Carlos Vegh, and Guillermo Vuletin. 2013. “On Graduation from Fiscal Procyclicality.” Journal of Development Economics 100 (1): 3247.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Freedom House. 2003. “Nations in Transit 2003 Report.” Washington, DC.

  • Fukuyama, Francis. 2008. “What Do We Know About the Relationship between the Political and Economic Dimensions of Development?” In Governance, Growth, and Development Decision-Making, edited by Daron Acemoğlu, Francis Fukuyama, and Dani Rodrik. Washington, DC: World Bank.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fukuyama, Francis. 2011. The Origins of Political Order: From Prehuman Times to the French Revolution. New York: Farrar, Straus and Giroux.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fukuyama, Francis, and Brian Levy. 2010. “Development Strategies: Integrating Governance and Growth.” Policy Research Working Paper No. 5196, World Bank, Washington, DC.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gabanyi, Anneli Ute. 2004. “The New Business Elite: From Nomenklature to Oligarchy.” In Romania since 1989: Politics, Economics, and Society, edited by Henry F. Carey. Lanham, MD: Lexington Books.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ganiou Mijiyawa, Abdoul. 2013. “Determinants of Property Rights Institutions: Survey of Literature and New Evidence.” Economics of Governance 14 (2): 12783.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gherasimov, Cristina. 2015. “Estonia and Poland: Setting Up Regional Examples in Anti-Corruption Performance Trough Independent Judiciaries.” Presentation at ECPR Joint Sessions of Workshops, Warsaw, March 29–April 2.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Glaeser, Edward L., and Andrei Shleifer. 2002. “Legal Origins.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 117 (November): 1193230.

  • Gorodnichenko, Yuriy, and Gerard Roland. 2010. “Culture, Institutions and the Wealth of Nations.” NBER Working Paper No. 16368. National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Grossman, Sanford J., and Oliver D. Hart. 1986. “The Costs and Benefits of Ownership: A Theory of Vertical and Lateral Integration.” Journal of Political Economy 94(4): 691719.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Group of States Against Corruption (GRECO). 2013. “Corruption Prevention in Respect of Members of Parliament, Judges and Prosecutors, Evaluation Report Estonia.” European Commission, Brussels.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Group of States Against Corruption (GRECO). 2014. “Corruption Prevention in Respect of Members of Parliament, Judges and Prosecutors, Evaluation Report Croatia.” European Commission, Brussels.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Group of States Against Corruption (GRECO). 2015a. “Corruption Prevention in Respect of Members of Parliament, Judges and Prosecutors, Evaluation Report Serbia.” European Commission, Brussels.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Group of States Against Corruption (GRECO). 2015b. “16th General Activity Report.” European Commission, Brussels.

  • Group of States Against Corruption (GRECO). 2016. “Corruption Prevention in Respect of Members of Parliament, Judges and Prosecutors, Evaluation Report Romania.” European Commission, Brussels

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Group of States Against Corruption (GRECO). 2017. “Fourth Evaluation Round Report: Conclusions and Trends.” European Commission, Brussels.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Guriev, Sergei. 2017. “Political Economy and Reforms. Do Reforms Have to be Popular to be Successful?Presentation at the 2017 Conference on Reaccelerating Convergence in Central, Eastern and Southeastern Europe: The Role of Governance and Institutions, Dubrovnik, Croatia. July 11.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gutmann, Jerg, and Stefan Voigt. 2017. “Judicial Independence in the EU–A Puzzle.” ILE Working Paper Series, No. 4. University of Hamburg Institute of Law and Economics, Hamburg.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hall, Robert, and Charles Jones. 1999. “Why Do Some Countries Produce So Much More Output per Worker than Others?Quarterly Journal of Economics 114: 83116.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hart, Oliver, and John Moore. 1994. “A Theory of Debt Based on the Inalienability of Human Capital.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 109 (4): 84179.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hiber, Dragor. 2005. “The Reform of the Judiciary and the Judicial Legislation.” In Serbia Four Year of Transition, edited by B. Begović and B. Mijatović. Center for Liberal Democratic Studies.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • High Judicial and Prosecutorial Council of Bosnia and Herzegovina (HJPC). 2017. “History of Judicial Reform and HJPC.” Sarajevo.

  • Hoyland, Bjorn, Karl Moene, and Fredrik Willumsen. 2012. “The Tyranny of International Index Rankings.” Journal of Development Economics 97: 114.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund (IMF). 1997. “Good Governance. The IMF’s Role.” Washington, DC.

  • International Monetary Fund (IMF). 2005. World Economic Outlook. Washington DC. September.

  • International Monetary Fund (IMF). 2014. “25 Years of Transition Post-Communist Europe and the IMF.” Regional Economic Issues. Special Report. Washington DC. October.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund (IMF). 2015. “A Strategy for Resolving Europe’s Problem Loans.” IMF Staff Discussion Note 15/19, Washington, DC.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund (IMF). 2016a. “Corruption: Costs and Mitigating Strategies.” IMF Staff Discussion Note 16/05, Washington, DC.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund (IMF). 2016b. Regional Economic Issues: Central, Eastern, and Southeastern Europe. Washington, DC. November.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund (IMF). 2017a. “The Role of the Fund in Governance Issues— Review of the Guidance Note—Preliminary Considerations.” Washington, DC.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund (IMF). 2017b. “Ukraine: Selected Issues.” Country Report No. 17/84. European Department, Washington, DC. April.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund (IMF). 2017c. “Use of Third-party Indicators in Fund Reports.” Washington, DC. April.

  • Iwanek, Maciej, and Stanislaw Wellisz. 1993. “The Privatization of the Polish Economy.” Eastern Economic Journal 19 (3).

  • Johnsøn, Jesper, Nils Taxell, and Dominik Zaum. 2012. “Mapping Evidence Gaps in Anti-corruption: Assessing the State of the Operationally Relevant Evidence on Donors’ Actions and Approaches to Reducing Corruption.” U4 Issue Paper No. 7/2012, Christian Michelsen Institute, Bergen.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Johnson, Simon, John McMillan, and Christopher Woodruff. 2002. “Property Rights and Finance.” American Economic Review 92 (5): 1335356.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Jovic´, Dejan. 2006. “Croatia and the European Union: A Long-Delayed Journey.” Journal of Southern Europe and the Balkans 8(1): 85103.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kalniņš, Valts. 2015. “Process-tracing Study Report on Estonia.” Centre for Public Policy, PROVIDUS, Riga Latvia.

  • Kaufmann, Daniel, and Aart Kraay. 2002. “Growth Without Governance.” Economía (Winter): 169215.

  • Kraay, Aart, and Vikram Nehru. 2006. “When Is External Debt Sustainable?.” The World Bank Economic Review 20 (3): 341365.

  • Kubicek, Paul. 2004. Organized Labor in Postcommunist States: From Solidarity to Infirmity. Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press.

  • Kucharczyk, Jacek, and Jarosław Zbieranek. 2010. “Democracy in Poland 1989–2009. Challenges for the Future.” Institute of Public Affairs, Warsaw.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Laar, Mart. 2007. “The Estonian Economic Miracle.” Center for International Trade and Economics, The Heritage Foundation, Washington, DC.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Laeven, Luc, and Giovanni Majnoni. 2005. “Does Judicial Efficiency Lower the Cost of Credit?Journal of Banking & Finance 29 (July): 1791812.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lagarde, Christine. 2016. “Mending the Trust Divide.” Speech at the International Bar Association Conference, Washington, DC, September 18.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lagarde, Christine. 2017. “Addressing Corruption with Clarity.” Speech at the Brookings Institution, Washington, DC, September 18.

  • Landes, David S. 1998. The Wealth and Poverty of Nations: Why Some Are So Rich and Some So Poor? New York: W.W. Norton.

  • La Porta, Rafael, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, and Andrei Shleifer. 2008. “The Economic Consequences of Legal Origins.” Journal of Economic Literature 46 (2): 285332.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • La Porta, Rafael, Florencio Lopez-De-Silanes, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W. Vishny. 1997. “Trust in Large Organizations.” American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings 87: 33338.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • La Porta, Rafael, Florencio Lopez-De-Silanes, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W. Vishny. 1998. “Law and Finance.” Journal of Political Economy 106: 1113155.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • La Porta, Rafael, Florencio Lopez-De-Silanes, Andrei Shleifer, and Robert W. Vishny. 1999. “The Quality of Government.” Journal of Law, Economics and Organization 15: 22279.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Leutloff-Grandits, Carolin. 2006. “Claiming Ownership in Postwar Croatia: The Dynamics of Property Relations and Ethnic Conflict in the Knin Region.” Social Anthropology 17 (1): 13435.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Licht, Amir, Chanan Goldschmidt, and Shalom H. Schwartz. 2007. “Culture Rules: The Foundations of the Rule of Law and Other Norms of Governance.” Journal of Comparative Economics 35 (4): 65988.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lumiste, Rünno, Robert Pefferly, and Alari Purju. 2008. “Estonia’s Economic Development: Trends, Practices, and Sources: A Case Study.” Commission on Growth and Development Working Paper No. 25, World Bank, Washington, DC.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Madir, Jelena. 2011. “Recent Developments in Judicial Reform in Croatia.” Law in Transition 6: 5259.

  • Magen, Amichai, and Leonardo Morlino. 2009. “International Actors, Democratization and the Rule of Law: Anchoring Democracy?” Routledge/UACES Contemporary European Studies. London.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mahoney, Paul G. 2001. “The Common Law and Economic Growth: Hayek Might Be Right.” Journal of Legal Studies 30 (2): 50325.

  • Marčeta, Irena. 2010. “The International Anchoring of Serbia’s Democracy: The Seeds of a Crisis Embedded.” Italian Political Science Review 2: 195218.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mauro, Paolo. 1995. “Corruption and Growth.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 110: 681712.

  • Mendelski, Martin. 2012. “EU-driven Judicial Reforms in Romania: A Success Story?East European Politics 28 (1): 2342.

  • Menz, Christian. 2013. Explaining Croatia’s (non)compliance with EU Conditionality on ICTY Cooperation: Do External Incentives Make the Difference? Anchor Academic Publishing.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mishra, Prachi, Peter Moniel, Peter Pedroni, and Antonio Spilimbergo. 2014. “Monetary Policy and Bank Lending Rates in Low-Income Countries: Heterogeneous Panel Estimates.” Journal of Development Economics 111: 11731.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Moody’s Investor Service. 2016. “Rating Methodology: Sovereign Bond Ratings.” December 22.

  • Moore, B., Jr. 1966. Social Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy: Lord and Peasant in the Making of the Modern World. Boston: Beacon Press.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mulas-Granados, Carlos, Taline Koranchelian, and Alex Segura-Ubiergo. 2008. “Reforming Government Subsidies in the New Member States of the European Union.” IMF Working Paper 08/165, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mungiu-Pippidi, Alina. 2015. The Quest for Good Governance: How Societies Develop Control of Corruption? Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mungiu-Pippidi, Alina. 2017. “Inclusive Institutions and Prosperity: CESEE Countries’ Path So Far, How They are Likely to Evolve, and Possible Lessons.” Presentation at the 2017 Conference on Reaccelerating Convergence in Central, Eastern and Southeastern Europe: The Role of Governance and Institutions, Dubrovnik, Croatia. July 11.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mungiu-Pippidi, Alina, and Ramin Dadasov. 2017. “When Do Anticorruption Laws Matter? The Evidence on Public Integrity Enabling Contexts.” Crime, Law and Social Change: 116.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Murret, Eugene. 2010. “Judicial Reform in Serbia.” Judicature 94 (1): 2830.

  • Nellis, John R. 1996. “Finding Real Owners – Lessons from Estonia’s Privatization Program.” Note No. 66. Private Sector Development Department, World Bank, Washington, D.C.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Nikiel, Ewa M., and Timothy P. Opiela. 2002. “Customer Type and Bank Efficiency in Poland: Implications for Emerging Market Banking.” Contemporary Economic Policy 20: 5571.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • North, Douglass C. 1981. Structure and Change in Economic History. New York: W.W. Norton & Co.

  • North, Douglass C. 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

  • Noutcheva, Gergana. 2006. “EU Conditionality and Balkan Compliance: Does Sovereignty Matter?Doctoral Dissertation, University of Pittsburgh.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Open Society Institute (OSI). 2001. “Monitoring the EU Accession Process: Judicial Independence.” EU Accession Monitoring Program, Central European University Press, Budapest.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD). 2014. “Building More Effective, Accountable, and Inclusive Institutions for All.” Element 6, Paper 1, Paris.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD). 2016. “OECD G-20 Policy Paper on Economic Resilience and Structural Policies.” OECD, Paris. November 14.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Organization for Security and Co-operation in Europe (OSCE). 2011. “Judicial Institutions in Serbia.” Vienna.

  • Organization for Security and Co-operation in Europe (OSCE). 2014. “Baltic States: Citizenship and Language Rights of Russian-speaking Minorities.” Presentation at the Human Rights Without Frontiers International OSCE Human Dimension Implementation Meeting, Warsaw, September 29.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Organization for Security and Co-operation in Europe (OSCE). 2017. “Strengthening the Justice Sector.” Factsheet, January 1. http://www.oscebih.org.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Panizza, Ugo. 2001. “Electoral Rules, Political Systems, and Institutional Quality.” Economics and Politics 13 (3): 31142.

  • Paramio, Ludolfo. 2002. “Romania: An Excessively Long Transition.” In Democratic Transition in Romania. Madrid: FRIDE.

  • Pärna, Priidu. 2005. “Legal Reform in Estonia.” International Journal of Legal Information 33 (2).

  • Patena, Wiktor. 2015. “Post-Privatization Corporate Perfomance in Poland in 2008–2011.” SSRN Electronic Journal (February 9).

  • Pavlovic, L. 2003. “Comment on the Serbian Judiciary.” Speech published on the online forum Justice in the Balkans.

  • Pesic, Vesna. 2007. “State Capture and Widespread Corruption in Serbia.” Center for European Policy Studies (CEPS) Working Document 262, Brussels.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Piana, Daniela. 2009. “The Power Knock at the Courts’ Back Door: Two Waves of Postcommunist Judicial Reforms.” Comparative Political Studies 42 (6).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Piana, Daniela, Philip Langbroek, Tomas Berkmanas, Ole Hammerslev, and Otilia Pacurari. 2013. “Legal Education and Judicial Training in Europe: The Menu for Justice Project Report.” Eleven International Publishing.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Piketty, Tomas. 1995. “Social Mobility and Redistributive Politics.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 100: 55184.

  • Poghosyan, Arsen, and Tigran Poghosyan. 2010. “Foreign Bank Entry, Bank Efficiency and Market Power in Central and Eastern European Countries.” Economics of Transition 18 (3): 57198.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Polish Justice Ministry. 2017, Press release, July 12.

  • Pralong, Sandra. 2004. “NGOs and the Development of Civil Society.” In Romania since 1989: Politics, Economics, and Society, edited by Henry Carey. Lanham: Lexington Books.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Putnam, Robert. 1993. Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions in Modern Italy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

  • Radulović, Branko, and Stefan Dragutinović. 2014. “Case Studies of Privatization in Serbia.” National Alliance for Local Economic Development, Belgrade. November.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Rajkovic, Nikolas Milan. 2012. The Politics of International Law and Compliance. Serbia, Croatia and The Hague Tribunal. Abingdon, NY: Routledge.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ristic, Marija. 2016. “EU Insists on Serbian Cooperation Over War Crimes.” Balkan Transitional Justice.

  • Rodríguez-Ferreira, Octavio. 2013. “Civic Engagement and the Judicial Reform.” The Wilson Center, Washington, DC.

  • Roland, Gérard. 2004. “Understanding Institutional Change: Fast-moving and Slow-moving Institutions.” Studies of Comparative International Development 38: 10932.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Roland, Gérard. 2014. Development Economics. The Pearson Series in Economics. London: Routledge.

  • Roman, Petre. 2002. “Peculiarities of the Transition in Romania.” In Democratic Transition in Romania. Madrid: FRIDE.

  • Romer, David. 2003. “Misconceptions and Political Outcomes.” Economic Journal 113: 120.

  • Rossi, Federico M. 2012. “From the Coup to the Escalation of Violence: The Transition to Democracy in Romania.” COSMOS Working Paper 2012/13, Center on Social Movement Studies, Florence.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Sarapuu, Külli. 2012. “Administrative Structure in Times of Changes: The Development of Estonian Ministries and Government Agencies 1990–2010.” International Journal of Public Administration 35 (12): 80819.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Schwartz, Shalom H. 1994. “Beyond Individualism/Collectivism: New Cultural Dimensions of Values.” In Individualism and Collectivism: Theory, Method, and Applications, edited by Kim Uichol, Harry C. Triandis, Cigdem Kagitcibasi, Sang-Chin Choi, and Gene Yoon. Thousand Oaks, CA: SAGE Publications.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Schwartz, Shalom H. 1999. “Cultural Value Differences: Some Implications for Work.” Applied Psychology International Review 48: 2347.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Siani-Davies, Peter. 2005. The Romanian Revolution of December 1989. Ithaca and London: Cornell University Press.

  • Slay, Ben. 1995. “Industrial Demonopolization and Competition Policy in Poland and Hungary.” Economics of Transition 3 (4): 479504.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Spasić, Ivana. 2008. “Serbia 2000–2008: A Changing Political Culture?.” Balkanologie 11(1–2).

  • Standard and Poor’s. 2011. “Sovereign Government Rating Methodology and Assumptions.” Ratings Direct. June 30.

  • Standard and Poor’s. 2013. “How We Rate Sovereigns.” Ratings Direct. November 12.

  • State Audit Office of Hungary. 2016. “Summary of the Results of the 2015 Integrity Survey.” Budapest.

  • Straub, Stéphane. 2000. “Empirical Determinants of Good Institutions: Do We Know Anything?IDB Working Papers No. 6085, Inter-American Development Bank, Washington, DC.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Stulz, Rene M., and Rohan Williamson. 2003. “Culture, Openness, and Finance.” Journal of Financial Economics 70 (3): 31349.

  • Taube, Günther, and Rene Weber. 1999. “On the Fast Track to EU Accession: Macroeconomic Effects and Policy Challenges for Estonia.” IMF Working Paper No. 99/156, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Taler, Richard H., and Cass R. Sunstein. 2009. Nudge. London: Penguin Books.

  • Tomas, Vinod, Yan Wang, and Xibo Fan. 2000. “Measuring Educational Inequality: Education Gini Index from 1960 to 1990.” Washington, DC: World Bank.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Thomsen, Poul. 2017a. “The Role of Governance and Institutions.” Speech at the 2017 Conference on Reaccelerating Convergence in Central, Eastern and Southeastern Europe: The Role of Governance and Institutions, Dubrovnik, Croatia. July 11.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Thomsen, Poul. 2017b. “Central, Eastern, and Southeastern Europe: Harnessing the Power of Good Governance.” IMFBlog, July 27.

  • Tõnnisson, Kristina, and Tiina Randma-Liiv. 2008. “Public Management Reforms: Estonia.” In Public Management Reforms in Central and Eastern Europe, edited by Geert Bouckaert, Juaj Nemec, Vitalis Nacrosis, Gyorgy Hajnal, and Kristina Tonnisson. NISPAcee.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Townsend, Robert. 1979. “Optimal Contracts and Competitive Markets with Costly State Verification.” Journal of Economic Theory 21: 26593.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Trumbull, Gunnar. 2012. Strength in Numbers: The Political Power of Weak Interests. Cambridge MA: Harvard University Press.

  • Uzelac, Alan. 2003. “Reform of the Judiciary in Croatia and its Limitations (Appointing Presidents of the Courts in the Republic of Croatia and the Outcomes).” In Institutional Framework, Vol. I: Between Authoritarianism and Democracy: Serbia, Montenegro, Croatia. Belgrade: CEDET.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Vachudova, Milada Anna. 2006. “Democratization in Post-communist Europe: Illiberal Regimes and the Leverage of International Actors.” Center for European Studies Working Paper No. 139. Center for European Studies, Cambridge, MA.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Valdai Discussion Club. 2014. “The Crisis in Ukraine: Root Causes and Scenarios for the Future.” September.

  • Vihalemm, Triin, and Anu Masso. 2003. “Identity Dynamics of Russian-speakers of Estonia in the Transition Period.” Journal of Baltic Studies 34(1): 92116.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Weber, Max. 1930. The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism. London: Allen and Unwin.

  • Weber, Max. 1958. The Religion of India. Glencoe: Free Press.

  • Weber, Max. 1968. Economy and Society: An Outline of Interpretive Sociology. Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press.

  • Williamson, Oliver E. 1985. The Economic Institutions of Capitalism: Firms, Markets, Relational Contracting. New York: Free Press.

  • Williamson, Oliver E. 2000. “The New Institutional Economics: Taking Stock Looking Ahead.” Journal of Economic Literature 38: 595613.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • World Bank. 2017. World Development Report: Governance and the Law. Washington, DC: World Bank.

  • World Economic Forum (WEF). 2016. Global Competitiveness Report, 2015–16. WEF.

  • Yemelianova, Anna. 2010. “A Diagnosis of Corruption in Ukraine.” European Research Centre for Anti-Corruption and State-Building. Berlin.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Zingales, Luigi. 2017. “Toward a Political Theory of the Firm.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 31 (3): 11330.

This chapter was prepared by a staff team consisting of Vizhdan Boranova, Raju Huidrom, Mariusz Jarmuzek, Martin Petri, Faezeh Raei, Tiberiu Scutaru, Ara Stepanyan, and Svetlana Vtyurina, with input from Nadeem Ilahi, Ricardo Llaudes, Pamela Madrid Angers, Francisco Parodi, Brett Rayner, Jason Weiss, and Ruifeng Zhang, as well as from country teams. The team was led by Laura Papi, under the general guidance of Jörg Decressin. Gilda Ordoñez-Baric provided skillful administrative support.

1

The EU15 are Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg, the Netherlands, Portugal, Spain, Sweden, and the United Kingdom.

2

The CESEE countries are Albania, Bosnia and Herzegovina, Bulgaria, Croatia, the Czech Republic, Estonia, Hungary, Kosovo, Latvia, Lithuania, Macedonia, FYR, Moldova, Montenegro, Poland, Romania, Serbia, the Slovak Republic, Slovenia, Turkey, and Ukraine.

3

In addition to an effective judiciary, property rights protection requires effective enforcement and foreclosure regimes, enforcement agents, bailiffs, notaries, and credit and land registries—aspects not covered in this chapter.

4

Many other economic institutions, such as fiscal and financial institutions, are important, but have been the subject of other studies. For example, the November 2016 Regional Economic Issues: Central, Eastern, and Southeastern Europe focused on government efficiency.

5

Acemoğlu, Johnson, and Robinson (2005) refer to effective institutions as “inclusive institutions” and contrast them with “extractive institutions,” Fukuyama (2011) speaks of “accountable government” versus “patrimonialism,” and Mungiu-Pippidi (2015) refers to “ethical universalism” versus “particularism.”

6

In this context, the collective action problem is the inability to take actions that maximize the well-being of society as a whole.

7

Initial conditions are taken as 1993 because the early 1990s denote the beginning of the CESEE transition, and due to data availability.

8

However, some point to limited integration of the Russian-speaking minority as a cost of the otherwise inclusive reform strategy (OSCE 2014; ECRI 1999, 2015).

9

Control of corruption declined between 2001 and 2011, but has improved again in the past few years and is now comparable to the EU15 average.

10

The rule of law is a broader indicator, while the judiciary’s effectiveness (including efficiency, independence, and impartiality) and the protection of property rights are components of the rule of law.

11

The EU Justice Scoreboard provides information on safeguards related to the status of judges regarding their appointment, evaluation, possible transfer without consent, and potential dismissal (EC 2017b).

12

The State Audit Office of Hungary (2016) reports an improvement in survey-based corruption risk indicators between 2013 and 2015, but indicates that “the ratio of institutions applying anti-corruption procedures still remains low.”

13

The transition from a centrally planned to a market-based economy generally entailed higher measured inequality. The region’s posttax Gini coefficient, on average, increased by 4 percentage points during the 1990s, though it started at very low levels. Nevertheless, this may overestimate the increase, as the income distribution in command economies likely underestimated the degree of inequality due to price controls and shortages.

14

OECD (2014) notes that more competition results in less corruption.

15

Atoyan and others (2016) find that the exit of young and skilled people from the region over the past 20 years (the largest economic emigration in modern history as a share of home population) removed a voice that could have been critical for improving institutions.

  • Collapse
  • Expand
  • Figure 2.1.

    CESEE: Estimated Efficiency Gains from Institutional Reforms

    (Percent; potential improvement in total factor productivity)

  • Figure 2.2.

    Factors Shaping Institutional Quality1

  • Figure 2.3.

    CESEE: Initial Level of Fundamentals and Aspects of the Rule of Law1

    (Index; 0 = worst, 10 = best)

  • Figure 2.4.

    Estonia: Judicial Independence and Protection of Property Rights

    (Index; 0 = worst, 10 = best)

  • Figure 2.5.

    Estonia: Factors Affecting Institutional Quality1

    (Index; 0 = worst, 10 = best)

  • Figure 2.6.

    Estonia: EU Accession Timeline

  • Figure 2.7.

    Poland: Factors Affecting Institutional Quality1

    (Index; 0 = worst, 10 = best)

  • Figure 2.8.

    Poland: Judicial Independence and Protection of Property Rights1

    (Index; 0 = worst, 10 = best)

  • Figure 2.9.

    Poland: EU Accession Timeline

  • Figure 2.10.

    Romania: Factors Affecting Institutional Quality1

    (Index; 0 = worst, 10 = best)

  • Figure 2.11.

    Romania: Judicial Independence and Protection of Property Rights

    (Index; 0 = worst, 10 = best)

  • Figure 2.12.

    Romania: EU Accession Timeline

  • Figure 2.13.

    Croatia: Factors Affecting Institutional Quality1

    (Index; 0 = worst, 10 = best)

  • Figure 2.14.

    Croatia: EU Accession Timeline

  • Figure 2.15.

    Croatia: Judicial Independence and Protection of Property Rights

    (Index; 0 = worst, 10 = best)

  • Figure 2.16.

    Serbia: Factors Affecting Institutional Quality1

    (Index; 0 = worst, 10 = best)

  • Figure 2.17.

    Serbia: Judicial Independence and Protection of Property Rights

    (Index; 0 = worst, 10 = best)

  • Figure 2.18.

    Serbia: EU Accession Timeline

  • Figure 2.19.

    Bosnia and Herzegovina: Factors Affecting Institutional Quality1

    (Index; 0 = worst, 10 = best)

  • Figure 2.20.

    Bosnia and Herzegovina: Judicial Independence and Protection of Property Rights

    (Index; 0 = worst, 10 = best)

  • Figure 2.21.

    Bosnia and Herzegovina: EU Accession Timeline

  • Figure 2.22.

    Consistency of Similar Indicators from Different Sources1

    (Standard deviation)

  • Figure 2.23.

    CESEE: Case Resolution Rate and Disposition Time, 20141

  • Figure 2.24.

    Europe: The Rule of Law and Some of Its Components

    (Lighter blue = better; darker blue = worse)1

  • Figure 2.25.

    Perceived Independence of Courts, 20171

    (Percent)

  • Figure 2.26.

    CESEE: Evolution of the Elements of the Rule of Law

  • Figure 2.27.

    CESEE: Evolution of Institutions before and after 2007

  • Figure 2.2.1.

    CESEE: Timeline of European Union Accession

  • Figure 2.3.1.

    Kosovo: Court Backlog Clearance under USAID Program

    (Cumulative, thousands of court cases)