CHAPTER 7 Surveillance, Growth, and Crisis
Author:
Mr. Harold James
Search for other papers by Mr. Harold James in
Current site
Google Scholar
Close

Abstract

Two parallel problems arose in the course of the 1960s. One, the fear of an emerging shortage of reserves and the consequent debate over the desirability of an international reserve currency, was the subject of the last chapter. The second, concerning the response by national policymakers to the need for balance of payments adjustment, provides the theme of this chapter. Countries found submission to the discipline required for the operation of the system increasingly hard. In particular, the system required the imposition of fiscal restraint or deflation for balance of payments purposes in circumstances that might be difficult politically. For the largest economy and the major “key currency,” the United States and the dollar, such discipline could not be imposed from the outside: it had to be self-generated. During the fiscally conservative 1950s, this aspect of self-discipline (which represented a prerequisite for confidence in the whole international monetary order) constituted no difficulty. Increasingly in the 1960s, a belief in the availability of macroeconomic management and then, after 1965, growing defense expenditures weakened the American commitment to discipline. The resultant problems of the dollar are described in Chapter 8. This chapter is concerned with analogous debates about discipline in other countries and its imposition from outside, even in the mild form of surveillance: exposure to a mixture of peer pressure, public exhortation, and dependence on the possibility of borrowing on conditions from an outside institution. In the 1960s, surveillance became an increasingly important theme in the development of the world economy.

Two parallel problems arose in the course of the 1960s. One, the fear of an emerging shortage of reserves and the consequent debate over the desirability of an international reserve currency, was the subject of the last chapter. The second, concerning the response by national policymakers to the need for balance of payments adjustment, provides the theme of this chapter. Countries found submission to the discipline required for the operation of the system increasingly hard. In particular, the system required the imposition of fiscal restraint or deflation for balance of payments purposes in circumstances that might be difficult politically. For the largest economy and the major “key currency,” the United States and the dollar, such discipline could not be imposed from the outside: it had to be self-generated. During the fiscally conservative 1950s, this aspect of self-discipline (which represented a prerequisite for confidence in the whole international monetary order) constituted no difficulty. Increasingly in the 1960s, a belief in the availability of macroeconomic management and then, after 1965, growing defense expenditures weakened the American commitment to discipline. The resultant problems of the dollar are described in Chapter 8. This chapter is concerned with analogous debates about discipline in other countries and its imposition from outside, even in the mild form of surveillance: exposure to a mixture of peer pressure, public exhortation, and dependence on the possibility of borrowing on conditions from an outside institution. In the 1960s, surveillance became an increasingly important theme in the development of the world economy.

International surveillance takes place in a growing variety of different institutional settings, in particular within the IMF, the G-10, the Bank for International Settlements (BIS), and the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD). Because the task of adjustment grew harder, it invited renewed thinking about institutional arrangements.

uch07fig01
“We can’t make it tonight, Maggie. It’s John’s night to explain ‘paper gold’ to me.”

Surveillance became, on the one hand, more necessary in the 1960s as a system developed. Ever since the very early history of the IMF, no one had seriously contemplated a completely automatic operation. The Fund would be required to make judgments about the use of its resources by members and the appropriateness of members’ policies when they requested and used them; and to supervise the elimination of exchange restrictions. It did not take much further development for countries to see that the system, and the imbalances within it, required analysis as much as did the policies of members. Countries’ balance of payments began to reflect the consequence of a partial financial liberalization and increased movements of capital. On the other hand, applying surveillance became more difficult for two reasons. First, as a result of the new importance—in national political discussions—of the regulation and control of growth and employment, the political sensitivity of governments to economic issues increased. In consequence, their willingness to undertake adjustment as a response to international pressure diminished. Second, in many cases the governments concerned lacked the conceptual apparatus that was a prerequisite for effective surveillance. In particular, many officials and most ministers did not understand the importance of monetary policy for their country’s external position.

Growth had become for most countries a fact of political life. The successes of the world economy stemmed in part from the spectacular growth effects of an economic catch-up, as well as from the trade liberalization and better policy that allowed the realization of the potential to make good previous losses. Higher growth in the 1950s and 1960s seemed a compensation for the poor performance of the interwar economy and the disruptions caused by the Second World War.1 But some began to take for granted the rapid gains and apparently permanently high growth rates of the postwar miracle. The question began to arise of whether, if and when the miracle came to an end, societies would blame the international system, blame themselves, or blame the force of circumstance. What would happen when growth fell away? Would states begin to look for domestic ways of preserving growth? Or would states use the international system to generate a new stimulus and would that in turn make other states fear that their stability was under threat? In either case, the system would be dragged into the fierce domestic debates caused by growth and its problems. Signs of the growing tension can be found in the systemic debates—for instance over the SDR—as well as in the increasingly problematic field of policy coordination. The G-10 ministerial meeting of 1968 in Bonn came to be seen as a nadir of cooperation, and a sign of the intolerable strains under which the international system was now operating.

The decade of the 1960s was the heyday of “growthmanship.” Japan launched an income doubling plan in 1960; and in 1965 it abandoned the balanced budget strategy that had been pursued throughout the postwar era. John F. Kennedy’s campaign in 1960 ran on a pledge of 5 percent growth, and his first question to every economist was how that target might be achieved. In the general election in Britain two years later, both the major opposing parties promised voters 4 percent growth. In Germany, the architect of the postwar miracle, Ludwig Erhard, failed as Federal Chancellor to deal with the recession of 1966–67; and in the coalition government that followed his, a Law on Stability and Growth (1967) gave a legislative form to the new political priority of economic expansion (in its original form, as prepared by the Erhard government, the law had been intended as a “Law on Stability”). Planning growth, or a “white hot technological revolution” required new instruments of management: global steering, target projections, in Germany a Mifrifi (midterm financial planning) and a Mamiflex (economic policy of moderation and flexibility), in Britain a Neddy (NEDC: National Economic Development Council), in Japan a commitment to income doubling and continued “administrative guidance” through the Ministry of International Trade and Industry, and in France the planiste legacy of Jean Monnet.2 The results of growth seemed evident as Western Europe and Japan began to catch up economically with the United States, and as the productivity gap of the 1950s disappeared—thanks in large part to the flow of American investments.

The priority attached to growth and to running economies at the limits of their capacities brought gradually rising inflation rates, and also balance of payments difficulties. When these occurred in the United Kingdom, one of the reserve centers of the Bretton Woods system, they led to a more general destabilization. The United Kingdom’s problems came as a consequence of misguided economic ideas, and wrong policies, but also of a fundamentally flawed position resulting from the overseas holdings of sterling balances. No multilateral institution or institutionalized surveillance could hope to correct the resulting instability. The foundation of the political consensus established by both the major parties in the postwar era had lain in a simplified and rather distorted version of Keynesianism. The major consequence for policy lay in the use of fiscal policy as a way of providing demand management and a propensity to look for too much expansion. The Keynesian consensus attached little importance to monetary policy and for a long time more or less neglected the effect of monetary behavior on the external account. As a consequence, the concept of international surveillance became highly problematical.

The Euromarkets

A major element in the increasingly intense European crises of the late 1960s was the greatly increased volatility of capital movements. Capital movements had already begun to play a much larger role in the late 1950s than had been anticipated at Bretton Woods. Even with tight controls on capital movements (the establishment of convertibility applied only to current account transactions), money movements responded to market signals. In addition, a pool of unregulated and uncontrolled capital emerged and grew rapidly over the course of the 1960s: the “Euromarket,” first in dollars, and then later also in other currencies used for financial operations outside their national areas.

Already in the interwar years, deposits and loans in “third” or nonnational currencies had provided an element of competition between currencies. There had been British, Dutch, and Swiss dollar loans to Central Europe. The postwar Eurodollar market began in the late 1940s, when the new Chinese communist government placed its dollar earnings with a Soviet bank in Paris (the Banque Commerciale pour l’Europe du Nord). In the early 1950s, after Yugoslav gold in New York was sequestered by the U.S. government, the U.S.S.R. and China made a consistent practice of not depositing dollars derived from export earnings with American banks, but rather using an extraterritorial (often called an offshore) market. The Federal Reserve Board’s Regulation Q, limiting interest payments on U.S. domestic bank deposits added an American incentive to hold dollars abroad. U.S. capital exports and military spending resulted in additional accumulations: because the dollars spent in this way were not used to buy American goods and services, some Europeans began to argue that Americans were buying companies abroad and maintaining their soldiers for free.

In the early 1960s, the majority of Eurodollars were held by central banks. After exchange controls on current transactions were lifted in 1958, Swiss and British commercial banks were free to accept foreign currency deposits and could offer more favorable rates than those on the U.S. domestic market. A much larger and more active private market developed after 1966 as U.S. money market interest rates rose above the levels permitted on bank deposits under Regulation Q. Once the market had reached a certain size, it generated transactions no longer necessarily limited to outflows from the United States. By 1971, one observer believed that “perhaps more than one half of all Eurodollars now in existence have been ‘made in Europe.’”3 In 1967, private banks began a practice of rolling over short-term deposits into what were effectively long-term loans. In 1963 the first postwar dollar bond issues outside the United States were concluded. As a result of these developments, during the course of the 1960s, the Eurodollar market grew to a very substantial size: from $1,500 million in 1959 to $46,000 million at the end of 1970. Since there were by then other currencies than the dollar used for extraterritorial transactions, the total “Euromarket” was larger: $57,000 million for 1970 and $71,000 million for 1971.4 One U.S. banker described the new markets as “a marvelous platform from which it is easy to rebound, in any direction, to any country, into any currency—and with anonymity.” The British Chancellor of the Exchequer of the mid-1970s referred to “the faceless men who managed the growing atomic cloud of footloose funds, which had accumulated in the Euro-markets to evade control by national governments.”5

Banking in Eurodollars increased the international money supply, in an analogous way to the operation of banks as a domestic money multiplier. The development of the Eurocurrency markets meant a definitive end of the Bretton Woods attempt to create an internationally controlled money supply. It challenged as a result both national monetary authorities and the IMF. By increasing the options available for the transfer of money, it also inevitably made for greater instability on currency markets.6

Central bankers were puzzled as how to deal with the potential disturbances caused by the new flows. Intervention in the markets, even if immediately successful, might in the longer run be counterproductive. One former Executive Director of the Bank of England argued at the end of the 1960s that “if central banks lend their names permanently to forward-exchange operations in any of the leading currencies using the largest domestic banks as agents, they will vastly increase the scope of these markets and, incidentally, will make much easier than need be the path of the speculator and the hedging of fixed assets in countries with a weak currency.”7 As the Euromarkets made exchange rate management much harder, they also acted, perhaps paradoxically, as a disincentive to authorities to contemplate rate changes. Such problems are inherent in any system relying on adjustable pegs. Any parity change would be interpreted as a signal, not that the right rate had been arrived at, but that further changes might be undertaken. It would destroy part of the credibility associated with a fixed rate system, and set off yet more intense speculative onslaughts on exchange parities. This consideration had moved Per Jacobsson to oppose the German revaluation of 1961 so vigorously. Such calculations applied even more forcefully in the case of currencies that served as international reserves—the dollar and sterling—and ensured that the problems of the Bretton Woods order appeared in these cases as peculiarly intractable.

Institutional Mechanisms

The IMF concerned itself with systemic reform as well as with the discussion of specific balance of payments problems. In particular, the debate over liquidity and reserve creation that eventually led to the innovation of the SDR involved the question of who would bear the main responsibility for adjustment. France and the United States tussled over how a new reserve system might reduce the potential strain on the dollar (the U.S. objective) and prevent the continuance of the U.S. “exorbitant privilege” (the French objective). At the same time elsewhere, in a different forum, surveillance of country policies and an attempt to provide solutions to balance of payments problems represented attempts at improving the operation of the existing system. These discussions were carried out by the G-10 deputies (who became involved in the SDR debate through the structural connection of the G-10 and the IMF), and also within the OECD, the successor to the Organization for European Economic Cooperation (OEEC) when the United States, Canada, and later Japan joined as full members.

In April 1961 the OEEC Economic Policy Committee had created Working Party 3, with the intention that it should “analyze the effect on international payments of monetary, fiscal and other policy measures, and will consult together on policy measures, both national and international, as they relate to international payments equilibrium.” WP-3 was composed of senior officials from Belgium, Canada, France, Germany, Italy, the Netherlands, Switzerland, the United Kingdom, the United States, and a Scandinavian country (in practice, Sweden), with the later addition of Japan. Intentionally it then replicated the composition of the G-10. Members of the Working Party were required to consult with other members of the OEEC, as well as with “the Board of Management of the European Monetary Authority and with other international organizations.”.

WP-3’s essential function lay in multilateral surveillance of balance of payments issues. In order to accomplish this, it needed to analyze broader macroeconomic developments. Meetings began characteristically with a tour d’horizon of crucial economic indicators in a number of the large industrial countries. But in the increasingly serious currency crises of the late 1960s, the WP-3 played an ever more peripheral role. This was not for lack of foresight. There was an urgent awareness of the gravity of the problem by the mid-1960s, but also, already then, an increasing sense of impotence and ineffectiveness.

In August 1966 WP-3 produced a report entitled “The Balance of Payments Adjustment Process.” Its major recommendation concerned the creation of an “early warning system”: “to try and ensure that as soon as evidence of an actual or potential imbalance begins to accumulate, it is the subject of a collective evaluation of the situation of the country or countries concerned, with a view to facilitating the adoption of appropriate policies.” The key objective, spelled out in Paragraph 70, was to entice countries to begin the process of domestic adjustment earlier: before the outbreak of a major crisis. The report largely ignored exchange rate adjustment and gave the subject only two brief references.

Within WP-3, the German central banker Otmar Emminger (who at the time was also the chairman of the G-10 deputies) devoted himself to the development of a mechanism for such an early warning system. Instead of looking indiscriminately at a large collection of data, policymakers should pay attention to a number of key indicators (money supply, bank lending, bank liquidity, short-term interest rates, and use of central bank credit). The function of the surveillance exercise was to focus attention on macroeconomic data that should initiate a policy change or policy response. Emminger concluded that “due emphasis should be placed on the interrelationship between the developments in the field of money, credit and public finance on the one hand, and the balance of payments, on the other.”8

The problem that made surveillance less than effective did not simply lie in the political task of prompting countries to take earlier, and less dramatic response, to potential balance of payments difficulties. There was also the almost insuperable intellectual challenge of convincing some monetary authorities that there existed such a link between money and the balance of payments.

The parallel institution that occupied itself with multilateral surveillance fared Little better. The G-10 had an intrinsically strong position thanks to the purse power established through its connection with the General Arrangements to Borrow (GAB). But a combination of political and intellectual resistance blocked its evolution as an effective provider of surveillance. In the mid-1960s, U.S. officials were referring to the G-10 as “more mouse than elephant.”9 They resented the leverage that its composition inevitably gave to the Europeans who regularly caucused before meetings, and, as a consequence, the United States tried to make that body as much of a mouse as it could by restricting the policies that could be considered. The influence of the United States, and the American wish not to have the dollar discussed, led to a refusal to consider parity alterations as a solution to balance of payments issues. In 1964, the deputies’ report included the following list of “appropriate … instruments of economic policy”: budgetary and fiscal policies, incomes policies, monetary policies, measures relating to international capital transactions, commercial policies, selective measures on housing or hire purchases. The document added that “such instruments must be employed with proper regard for obligations in the field of international trade and for the IMF obligation to maintain stable exchange parities which are subject to change only in cases of fundamental disequilibrium.”10 In other words, exchange rate changes were not to be considered as a usable instrument of policy.

Even the IMF was only willing to present the option of altering exchange rates in the most cautious of terms. When discussing balance of payments adjustment, the Annual Report of 1964 stated: “Adjustments in exchange rates are of course not precluded by the par value system, and are indeed foreseen by the Articles in the event that a country has fallen into fundamental disequilibrium; but such situations should arise less frequently to the extent that the policies described above are followed.”11 Subsequent reports, however, fell entirely silent on the issue of parity changes.

The United Kingdom and the Sterling Issue

Dealing with the United Kingdom in the 1960s exemplified the problems inherent in the concept of surveillance. The regular British balance of payments traumas occurring between 1961 and 1967 might have been held to justify nonstop “early warnings” of the kind envisioned by OECD’s WP-3. Long before the belated devaluation of 1967, it became abundantly clear that the pound was significantly overvalued. But no one wished to speak about parity changes in the context of international discussions between officials. Devaluation or revaluation involved such a degree of political sensitivity (and market sensitivity) that these options simply could not be debated as part of a surveillance exercise. Parity discussions were impossible for reasons of national prestige; the British rejected the use of monetary policy or a discussion of it; and their policies were constrained by domestic priorities (full employment) and international commitments (the sterling balances). As a result, there was not much to talk about usefully at an international level.

The failure of Britain to adjust before 1967 also gave an indication of the extent to which the practice of surveillance was handicapped by the absence of a common intellectual framework to guide responses to major economic problems or an agreement on policy choices. In the critical months of 1967 and 1968 participants complained that WP-3 meetings were both “ineffectual” and “rather dull.”12 Without a shared understanding of the functioning of the economy, surveillance can easily degenerate into a rehearsal of cases based solely on perceptions of national interest. WP-3 members regularly expressed their disappointment with the inadequacy of British attempts at adjustment, and pressed the IMF to urge Britain to act more effectively.

In the British case, the locus classicus on monetary policy was the Radcliffe Commission report of 1959. Again and again this document insisted on the unimportance of monetary policy. “Monetary action works upon total demand by altering the liquidity position of financial institutions and of firms and people desiring to spend on real resources; the supply of money itself is not the critical factor.… When all has been said on the possibility of monetary action and of its likely efficacy, our conclusion is that monetary measures cannot alone be relied upon to keep in nice balance an economy subject to major strains from both without and within.… The importance attached to the use of fiscal measures, particularly the Budget balance, has been one of the fundamental innovations of the post-war period.”13

The reason the Radcliffe view appealed to so many practical men was that it seemed perfectly to justify the Bank of England’s traditional concern with supporting the gilt market (that is, the market for government bonds) by holding interest rates low, at the expense of other policy objectives. A strategy of this kind clearly prevented the formulation of any sort of independent monetary policy. But its pursuit was crucial to maintaining the relationship between the financial authorities, the City of London, and the world of politics.14 As a result, money was consigned to an unimportant place in policy discussions.15 Here existed a fundamental difference with the Dutch or German view of appropriate instruments and objectives of economic management.

A further source of British resistance to international surveillance of its economic policy lay in the strength of the political commitment to hold unemployment at historically very low rates. In this regard, the United Kingdom represented only an extreme version of a generally shared approach in the 1960s. In the 1950s, British unemployment had fluctuated around 1.5 percent, and in the 1960s governments tried to keep this sensitive figure at even lower levels. The major constraint on expansive fiscal policy lay in the effect on the balance of payments. After brief expansions, the appearance of deficits required fiscal restraint. The resulting policy was usually characterized as “stop-go.”

Finally, the British position was intrinsically weak because of the overhang of sterling balances. In explaining the British opposition to the use of monetary measurements in policymaking, the Bank of England constantly used as its major argument the role of sterling as a reserve currency, which made it impossible to forecast the level of foreign-owned balances in London.16 In fact, holdings by central banks of sterling balances, which could be converted at any time into other currencies or gold, appeared to remain relatively constant in the first half of the 1960s. They amounted to £2,642 million at the end of 1958, £3,048 million at the end of 1964, and £2,982 million at the end of 1967.17 But a liquidation remained a constant threat. Fear of this eventuality led the United Kingdom to press many newly independent African states to accept a currency board that would issue local currency against sterling reserves rather than set up independent central banks (though for the new states, currency boards might also have an attraction as a relatively cheap way of obtaining liquidity and stabilizing the currency). The largest holders of sterling balances in the mid-1960s were involved in some mixture of political and economic dependence on the United Kingdom. Malaysia required military support in the conduct of a civil war. Hong Kong was incapable of surviving without British protection. Australia was the beneficiary of major British investment flows, as well as retaining a few of the constitutional characteristics of a member of some loose British imperial system. The Republic of Ireland was dependent on Britain for three fourths of its trade and in practice had little choice except to remain inside the sterling area. Kuwait was in part tied through its reliance on British military support, but above all wanted to build up an external source of savings as a way of dealing with its powerful neighbors and compensating through monetary strength for its military weakness.

There was always an uncertainty about how long the balances would be maintained: whether there would not be a powerful temptation to follow the postwar route of an India or an Argentina and liquidate sterling assets. It appeared inevitable that a devaluation, or even the possibility of devaluation, would prompt the liquidation of balances. Devaluation, it was usually argued, would provide no help in balance of payments adjustment because it would be inevitably followed by increased nervousness and thus a further and possibly complete liquidation. The constant threat of balance of payments problems, and the associated risks to sterling balances, required constant alteration of the fine-tuning fiscal pedal. The commentator Fred Hirsch rightly wrote of: “British financial officials who for ten years from 1955 had in effect compromised most of their own power to run the economy other than by pressing down on domestic expansion whenever the pound sterling had come under pressure.”18 He thought that the only solution lay in the transfer of the burden of sterling’s reserve function to an international institution such as the IMF.

The instability caused by the sterling balance overhang and the danger of liquidation in fact lay behind each of the major British crises of the second half of the 1960s. The year 1964 had been an election year, with a rapid growth of bank credit and an economic expansion engineered by the Conservative government in the hope of increasing its popularity. Balance of payments pressure required the negotiation in June and July of a $1 billion IMF stand-by arrangement. The outcome of the election was a narrow victory for the Labour Party, but it became clear that a new election would be desirable in order to obtain a working parliamentary majority.

For the next three years, Britain continued to avoid devaluation because of the willingness of the United States to support sterling: partly because of a feeling of solidarity between reserve currencies and partly because of the United Kingdom’s importance to the U.S. conception of its foreign policy. At the highest level of government to government dealings, foreign policy, troop stationing, and reserve currencies all entered into a complex calculation of national interest. An appreciation of the similarity between the international roles of the dollar and sterling led to the argument that the British currency represented the outer perimeter defense of the dollar. The escalation of war in Viet Nam after 1965 made the United States more desperate for European allies and eager to work the “special relationship.” After April 1966, when France withdrew from the military organization of the North Atlantic Treaty Organization (NATO), the American search for European support became more pressing.

In the second half of 1964, the balance on the British current account became highly negative. Nevertheless, one day after the election results were announced, the new government made a firm decision not to devalue, and after this the topic of devaluation was only referred to by politicians as “the unmentionable.” The belief was that socialism would come to be associated in the popular mind with depreciation of the currency. “The Conservatives,” the new Labour Chancellor of the Exchequer later said, “would have crucified us.” And, in addition, one of Prime Minister Harold Wilson’s economic advisers had persuaded him that “‘socialist’ policies could cure the balance of payments problem in quite a short time.”19 The logic imposed by the vulnerability of sterling balances had prevailed, dressed up as socialist policy.

Instead, the government tried to deal with the trade balance by the imposition of an import surcharge and to impose monetary restraint by a sharp increase in November 1964 in central bank interest (bank rate). An IMF team in London, joined on the new government’s budget day (November 11) by the Managing Director and prepared to accept the news of a British devaluation, was surprised when the government ruled out the possibility. The fundamental goal of the November bank rate operation was to accompany a major foreign borrowing operation. The Bank of England raised a $3,000 million credit from foreign central banks. As Hirsch commented: “In twenty-four hours the central bankers created more international liquidity with fewer questions asked than the most expansionist Triffinite would ever suggest for the IMF.”20 In addition, in December a new stand-by arrangement with the IMF was approved so that an emergency facility would be at hand before the calling of new elections.

The domestic strain was dealt with partially by moving into a rather gentle “stop” phase of the fiscal stop-go cycle, and partly by the introduction of an incomes policy, which was endorsed by both the OECD and the IMF. In July 1965, after a new burst of heavy losses of reserves, British local authority and central government investment were cut back. In September, the United Kingdom concluded an additional rescue package with the G-10.

The new elections in March 1966, which gave the Labour Party a solid parliamentary majority, had been preceded by a freeze of advances by the commercial (“clearing”) banks. In July, when statistics showing a renewed large current account deficit were released, another sterling crisis broke out with a $1.1 billion drain on British reserves, and the Bank of England required further support from the Federal Reserve.21 The British government pressed for a wage freeze negotiated with the labor unions as a sign that the British government was serious in its effort to correct the balance of payments. But, in practice, by the beginning of 1967, Britain had started a new expansion phase with a rapid reduction of the bank rate—an operation apparently conducted in the belief that since 1968 was an election year in the United States, there would be a substantial American reflation and an easing of rates.

In January 1967, the IMF’s Managing Director, Pierre-Paul Schweitzer, again visited London, offered Fund assistance, and once more cautiously discussed the problem of devaluation. If a devaluation were carried out and the amount of devaluation were either insufficient of excessive, he said, the result would be to trigger large capital movements.22 For the present the situation did not seem acute; and international early warnings fell on deaf British ears.

In the late summer of 1967 as a renewed drain set in, Wilson blamed the unfavorable British payments development on chance and unforeseen circumstances: the disruption to international trade caused by the closure of the Suez Canal in June as a result of the Arab-Israeli war, and dock strikes that began to strangle British overseas trade in September, and which had allegedly affected imports more than exports.23 On November 3, 1967, the Governor of the Bank of England told the IMF that the British authorities could no longer tie themselves to the six-month nondevaluation pledge that they had given earlier in the summer. On the same day, Wilson told one minister, “Of course my mind is open on that … It’s Jim [Callaghan, the Chancellor of the Exchequer] who has a closed mind on devaluation.”24 The next day, Callaghan called Wilson to say that there was a threat to the sterling parity;25 but a major new international package might still prevent the realization of the “unmentionable.” On November 7, U.S. Treasury Secretary Henry Fowler, who was completely committed to supporting the sterling parity, still sounded relatively optimistic about the British position. For the Americans, the attack on one reserve center appeared to be a dangerous anticipation of the vulnerability of the other. “The sterling situation was not hopeless and was worth another effort to provide support in the prospect that the factors which in recent months have reversed the sterling position would yield to more favorable forces.”26 France was also worried about the implications of a sterling crisis for the stability of the French franc. Callaghan still thought that a more thoroughgoing domestic adjustment coupled with some form of international assistance would be enough. He scandalized Labour Members of Parliament on November 7 by stating in the House of Commons that the postwar policy of keeping very low levels of unemployment had been misguided. “We must have a somewhat larger margin of unused capacity than we used to try to keep. That is the truth of the matter.” On the next day, he told Wilson that he still wanted to keep to the old sterling parity, but that there was a serious chance that Britain might be forced off.27

On November 11, 1967 the IMF talked with U.S. officials about arranging a $1.4 billion stand-by arrangement (200 percent of the U.K. quota) if it was requested by the United Kingdom. Britain believed that a total assistance of $3 billion, including a stand-by arrangement of 266 percent of quota, would be required for the defense of sterling to be successful. The American Deputy Managing Director of the IMF supported a last ditch stand to maintain the parity. But the IMF’s Managing Director and staff came to the conclusion that the Fund should not provide the substantial sum required, and that they should encourage Britain to use the opportunity provided by the immediate crisis to achieve the long-overdue parity change. On November 13, at a meeting at the BIS in Basle the Governor of the Bank of England told other central bankers of the IMF’s decision. The IMF now began to fear that the United Kingdom was still opposed to devaluation, and that the United States and European members might force the Fund into a stand-by arrangement without an adequate program because they believed that a U.K. devaluation might be followed in France. Schweitzer on November 15 insisted that “a fully adequate program would be needed. He realized that just adding more deflation was not the answer.” He made it clear that there existed little alternative to a sterling devaluation.

In fact, while these debates were taking place in Basle and Washington, the politicians in London had already reached a decision. On November 15, 1967 British ministers agreed to a devaluation of 14.3 percent, to $2.40, to be announced over the weekend, on November 18. This was formally agreed the next day in the cabinet, and the British Executive Director in the IMF told the Managing Director that while no decision had yet been taken, he wanted to inquire about a $1.4 billion stand-by arrangement to accompany and support a sterling devaluation. On November 17, 1967 the IMF received an official British request for a stand-by arrangement, and on Saturday, November 18, the devaluation decision was announced.

In the wake of the devaluation, the G-10, the OECD, the BIS, and the IMF were all involved in discussing the terms for assistance to the United Kingdom. In the negotiations with the IMF on November 21 and 22, Britain refused any notion of overall credit ceilings and said that the idea of a standby arrangement might even have to be abandoned. The British government was only prepared to accept an annual test on its fiscal position (it promised to hold the borrowing requirement to £1,000 million) and the British balance of payments (it believed the new measures would lead to an annual improvement of £500 million).28 In announcing the program in the House of Commons, Callaghan’s successor as Chancellor, Roy Jenkins, stated rather misleadingly: “In spite of misleading reports to the contrary, the Fund has not attached conditions to this credit.”29 But the statement did reflect the mildness of the conditionality, a lenience that infuriated other countries (particularly low-income countries) that had needed to draw from the Fund. The subsequent debate within the Fund Executive Board eventually led to a formulation of a more systematic and evenhanded approach to conditionality.

The British position remained precarious for some time after the November 1967 devaluation and the IMF stand-by arrangement. The immediate effect was to damage the trade balance as devaluation increased the costs of imports even though the volume might be expected to fall as a result of the price effects (an effect described as the J-curve: the adjustment of trade patterns to the new relative cost structure would take some time). In addition to the J-curve deterioration, to everyone’s surprise, the volume of British imports actually increased in the year after devaluation, despite a slowdown of economic growth. In the second half of 1968, as the trade gap widened further, Britain took additional action to restrict imports. Sterling area members again tried to run down their balances. A panic in the gold market in March 1968 also affected the pound. The year after devaluation appeared to vindicate the old argument of the antidevaluers, that a parity alteration would only increase the nervousness of central bank holders of sterling, who would have been humiliated by the loss of value of their reserves. But this time the problem was solved through international action. In September 1968 the United Kingdom reached agreement with the BIS and a group of industrial countries for a $2 billion credit agreement. It enabled the U.K. government to provide a dollar guarantee for sterling holdings above 10 percent of a country’s total reserves. Since sterling as a reserve asset became in consequence equivalent to the dollar, but offered interest rate advantages, sterling balances increased in the five-year period of the so-called Basle agreement.30

The longer-run effect of the 1967 crisis included a significant improvement in the British balance of payments (estimated at an annual £1,000 million), largely because of a rise of exports.31 The 1967 experience also had an effect on perceptions of the role of monetary policy in U.K. economic decision making, and in creating a common understanding of external linkages, which provided the only possible lasting basis for effective surveillance. It marked the beginning of the undoing of the Radcliffe doctrine. In October 1968, the IMF’s Economic Counsellor, J.J. Polak, conducted a seminar in London with officials from the Bank of England and the Treasury. The major concept deloyed was domestic credit expansion—DCE (see pages 141–42): a way of presenting the notion that monetary targets affected both the external balance and inflation to a group of nonbelievers raised on the doctrines of the Radcliffe report. It was a rather acrimonious meeting, in which the Bank’s analysts appeared to reject the IMF’s view of monetary policy. But DCE began to appear in British policy discussions. In April 1969 in the budget presentation, the Chancellor spoke of monetary policy as providing essential support to fiscal policy.32 At a follow-up monetary seminar in Washington in April 1970, there was a wide measure of consensus and the DCE target appeared as relatively uncontentious.

It was the beginning of an intellectual conversion, but not yet of a political turning. The adoption of a more serious approach to monetary policy had been a consequence of discussions with multilateral institutions, whose views had a great impact because of the need for external assistance in light of the United Kingdom’s balance of payments situation. Once, however, the pressure of circumstances eased, there was less need to take seriously advice coming from the outside—until the dramatic burst of inflation in the 1970s. That generated a greater political consensus, which could not depend on technical advice alone, that monetary policy should play an important part in the struggle against inflation.

The Problems of the Surplus Countries

One of the reasons why the United States had been prepared to make such a sustained effort to support British sterling lay in security considerations, as well as in the feeling of solidarity that linked the fortunes of two reserve centers. The relationship between the United States and Germany took on the air of a similarly symbiotic rapport in which defense and economic calculations entered on both sides. U.S. military spending in Germany constituted the major source of dollar outflows on military account to Europe. Germany realized the extent of its dependence on the American presence and was willing to make concessions when it came to the discussion of reserve holdings. The Bundesbank’s holding of dollars appeared to be an easy and innocuous way of paying for U.S. protection.

Germany tried to reduce the pace of reserve accumulation by promoting capital outflows and making inflows more difficult. In the first half of the 1960s, the gold share of German reserves rose, largely as a consequence of British gold sales to Germany during periods of strain on sterling: from $2,971 million at the end of 1960 to $4,410 million at the end of 1965. But after this, the gold reserves were deliberately reduced, while total German reserves grew: from $7,165 million at the end of 1961 to $8,153 million at the end of 1967 and $9,948 million in 1968.33

As the German surpluses expanded in 1967, Germany needed to reassure the United States about its policy. On March 30, 1967, the President of the Bundesbank, Karl Blessing, wrote to the Chairman of the Federal Reserve Board to give a German commitment (which subsequently became known as the “Blessing letter”): “By refraining from dollar conversions into gold from the United States Treasury the Bundesbank has intended to contribute to international monetary cooperation and to avoid any disturbing effects on the foreign exchange and gold markets. You may be assured that also in the future the Bundesbank intends to continue this policy and to play its full part in contributing to international monetary cooperation.” At the same time, the Bundesbank agreed to purchase with reserve funds $500 million medium-term U.S. government securities.34

At the same time as the Bundesbank was giving its pledges on reserves, WP-3 urged action to stimulate the German economy out of the recession of 1966–67 and in consequence to reduce the current account surplus. The recommendations of WP-3 in 1967 read like an endorsement of the policies of Karl Schiller, the new Economics Minister in the Great Coalition of Christian Democrats and Social Democrats, and of the pursuit of growthmanship. Germany should correct its balance of payments by means of monetary expansion, the reduction of long-term interest rates, and “fiscal flexibility.” A “normal rate of expansion” with 4 percent per annum increase in real output should be restored.35

Japan had abandoned budget balancing as a primary objective several years earlier, in 1965, but nevertheless built up very large trade surpluses in the late 1960s. Adjustment appeared to be futile, and Japan openly went over to a policy of reserve accumulation a few months after the Blessing letter. In August 1967, the Japanese representative “caused a stir” in the WP-3 when he announced that Japan intended to increase its reserves “gradually” from $2,000 million to $5,000 million over the next ten years.36 In fact, Japanese reserves rose from a steady figure just above $2,000 million during 1962–67 to $2,906 million at the end of 1968, $3,654 million at the end of 1969, then $4,840 million in 1970, and $15,360 million by the end of the crisis year 1971.37

The international discussion of Japanese reserves became more intense after the Bank of Japan applied a restrictive monetary policy in September 1969 in order to slow down the Japanese inflation.38 The result was to attract substantial inflows of short-term capital from the United States, and Japan’s reserves accumulated at an even quicker rate.

The Battle of the Franc

Japanese and German strength was the counterpart of problems elsewhere in the international monetary system. The issue of a possible French devaluation had already been one of the complicating factors in the 1967 U.K. crisis. In May 1968, student unrest followed by widespread industrial strikes threatened to bring down the French government. The President of the Republic, General de Gaulle, visited French troops stationed in Germany in what appeared to be a preparation for civil war. In the event, the labor strikes were settled by large wage rises rather than by tanks. The pressure of increased industrial costs again raised the issue of a parity change for the French franc or for the deutsche mark. In the summer of 1968, the position of the IMF was that a revaluation of the deutsche mark would not deal with the underlying problems and would only increase pressure against the weak links in the international system, the pound and the franc.39

Then in August 1968 capital flight began out of France in anticipation of a devaluation. The French government responded by restricting credit in order to restrain domestic growth and abolishing exchange controls in an attempt to win the confidence of markets.

Attempts to coordinate policy internationally only promoted a new level of politicization of currency crises. In November 1968, at the insistence of the U.S. President, and on very short notice, the ministers and central bank governors of the G-10 met in Bonn. It was a meeting poorly prepared in every sense and provides an unpromising prologue to the subsequent story of international summitry as it developed from the mid-1970s. It took place in the bleak building of the Economics Ministry in Bonn, with endless champagne, beer, and canapés on offer but nothing else to eat, and in the corridors an entourage of bored officials expelled from the high-level political meetings.40 Demonstrators outside the building held up placards with the slogan “Save the Mark.” Inside, the German hosts presented a package that had been the subject of intense political discussion within the German coalition government, with the Economics Minister, Karl Schiller, advocating an alteration of the parity but finding himself in a minority (despite the fact that exchange rate policy formally lay within his sphere of competence). As a result of the domestic political complexities, it became clear that the German negotiating position could not be modified through any international debate and that the meeting was thus fundamentally redundant.

The Finance Minister, Franz Josef Strauss, passionately opposed a revaluation of the deutsche mark as harmful to German export interests and the Federal Chancellor, Kurt Kiesinger, had pledged himself over and over again not to surrender the parity of the mark.41 Instead the Germans proposed a “substitute revaluation”: the introduction of a border tax of 4 percent on exports, which would have some of the effects on external trade of a revaluation. The argument was that the fall crisis of 1968 had resulted from “speculative movements” and that the politicians should ignore the temporary nervousness of the markers. Economics Minister Schiller, the nominal host of the G-10 ministers’ meeting, opened with a statement that there would be no change in the parity of the deutsche mark.42 Strauss was particularly unrestrained and uncooperative. He is reported to have said during the Bonn discussions: “Whether there was a majority at this conference of 7 to 3 or 9 to 1 did not impress him. Other countries would not determine what was Germany’s business. Revaluation of the deutsche mark would not resolve the problems of other countries. It was tried in 1961 and produced very little.” He also took a “French” line in vigorously attacking what he described as U.S. economic imperialism and spoke of the “political problem” represented by “the wholesale takeover of key German industries … How can the United States have such deficits in its balance of payments and yet pay such prices for European companies?”43

The foreigners, on the other hand, pressed for a more systematic approach by Germany. They were frustrated at the obvious but unproductive disagreements among German cabinet ministers. U.S. Treasury Secretary Fowler claimed that the position of the deutsche mark demonstrated a “fundamental disequilibrium” in the sense of the Bretton Woods agreements, requiring a parity realignment.44 He thought a revaluation of the deutsche mark more appropriate than a devaluation of other currencies, since he did not want to endanger the sensitive position of the United Kingdom once again. Schiller replied by asking why Fowler “preferred revaluation to devaluation,” and hinting that the answer depended on the dollar’s weakness: “supplementary international (and not national) measures will be needed in order to affect the balance of payments of certain countries.”45 The British Chancellor of the Exchequer, Roy Jenkins, stated that “the pound should not suffer from inadequate German action … The parity for sterling was right and any change in it would be wrong”: a German revaluation of 7.5 percent would be appropriate.46 Earlier, the British Prime Minister had told Germany’s Ambassador in London that the inflexible German stance was “irresponsible” and “intolerable.” As part of the exercise of putting pressure on Germany, the United Kingdom threatened the withdrawal of British troops from Germany if there was no action on the exchange rate.47

All this pressure failed to shift the paralyzed domestic German political situation. When it became clear that the Germans did not want to act, the international pressure turned on France. The figure provided by the technical economists suggested that France should devalue by 15 percent, though the Americans thought a lower figure would suffice. The French position became further confused when de Gaulle phoned the French Finance Minister François-Xavier Ortoli to say that “if we need to, we shall devalue, but make them fear that we could devalue a great deal” (and thus put pressure on the United Kingdom to devalue yet again, and via the United Kingdom also influence the United States).48 Eventually, Ortoli agreed to an isolated French devaluation of 11.1 percent, a figure suggested by Pierre-Paul Schweitzer, who was genuinely trying to make exchange rates function as an instrument of adjustment instead of as an instrument for carrying out political conflicts between the Great Powers. Ortoli added a peculiar note to his statement to the effect that since France had not been allowed to devalue by 15 percent, it might well devalue by less than the 11.1 percent, or indeed not devalue at all.49

At the Bonn G-10 ministerial meeting (which at the time was sometimes called a summit), an international package was assembled to support the French devaluation, and details of the deal appeared in the newspapers. Only one day after the summit, however, on November 23, 1968, de Gaulle announced that France would maintain the parity of the franc.50 Instead of devaluing, France would go through a period of austerity. The proposed deficit for 1969 would be cut by half, and it was estimated that the French current account deficit for 1969 would fall from an estimated $1.5 billion to $0.4 billion. France’s President had demonstrated the futility of the Bonn meeting. The aftermath of Bonn left politicians terrified of high-level international meetings for a substantial while. In fact, some observers recognized how unsuitable the summit process was for the task in hand. During the summit, Roy Jenkins had commented that meetings of this kind could not possibly decide a general currency realignment, a position that was endorsed by the IMF. Jenkins added that “the purpose of the present Conference would be completely defeated if it became known that a future Conference were planned in which all currencies would be open for reconsideration.”51

The seesaw between France and Germany over who should bear the responsibility of stabilizing markets continued for a year. Greater German growth or more French austerity? At the December 1968 meeting of WP-3, Emminger announced that the existence of the border taxes meant that the Bundesbank no longer had to maintain a tight monetary policy in order to check inflation. There was an “inconclusive” discussion, but no one urged Germany to do more than to stay with the rather high real growth target of 4–4.5 percent announced for 1969.52

On April 27, 1969, de Gaulle was defeated in a referendum that he almost certainly knew he would lose and had called as an act of political suicide. In May 1969, new flows of money from France to Germany started. Already in March, German Economics Minister Karl Schiller indicated that he might be willing to take “possible further steps”: an indication that he, unlike Strauss, was prepared to consider a German revaluation.53 Such hints only increased the speculative inflows. In all, between the beginning of the troubles in May 1968 and the German elections of September 1969, the German inflow amounted to $5.8 billion.54

For the whole of the summer, Germany did not act, paralyzed by the internal cabinet conflict between revaluers, led by Schiller, and opponents, led by Strauss, as well as by the prospect of new elections that would end a period of unstable coalition rule. Schiller derived substantial intellectual support from the reports of the independent Council of Economic Experts, which had from its beginning in 1964 pleaded for flexible exchange rates. The Bundesbank leadership, on the other hand, remained committed to fixed rates. For the moment the division of opinion could not he resolved, and the politically easiest solution appeared to be to retain the status quo. At a meeting of central bankers in Basle, Bundesbank President Karl Blessing read a message from the German Chancellor once again excluding the possibility of altering the deutsche mark rate. France had to take further deflationary measures. In July 1969 the new government froze all public investment. This did not help to calm the markets, and on August 9, 1969 France asked the IMF for its agreement to an 11 percent devaluation, which was accompanied by an IMF program and a new credit squeeze. The devaluation was also followed, as in the United Kingdom after 1967, by a “monetary seminar,” in which monetary targeting on the basis of domestic credit expansion was explained and advocated to French officials. Like their British counterparts, they began in a very skeptical mood and became convinced only after very lengthy discussions.

A few weeks after the long battle of the franc had ended, the German elections took place (September 28, 1969). On the day after the failure of the Christian Democrats to gain an overall majority, and the formation of a social democratic and liberal coalition government in which Schiller played the key role, the deutsche mark was floated. On October 24, 1969 a new parity was adopted: DM 3.66 to the dollar, an appreciation of 9.3 percent. The new government believed that the revaluation would cut the inflation that had resulted from the monetary laxity of the previous year, and that price rises for the next 12 months would be 2.5–3.5 percent rather than the 5–6 percent that would have followed from a failure to change the deutsche mark parity.55 To more and more Germans, the fixed parity system seemed to involve the international imposition of inflation on Germany, whose historical experience had produced a profound horror of its consequences. In their view, the IMF had been ineffective in suggesting any way out of their dilemma—or even in securing French adjustment or devaluation. Many began to view the Bretton Woods construct with increasing unease.

Inflation as an International Phenomenon

The higher levels of inflation that characterized the late 1960s were explained at the time in two, rival and apparently contradictory, ways. The first explanation, which was widely believed in France and Germany (its leading theoretical exponents were Jacques Rueff and Egon Sohmen), might be labeled “international monetarism.”56 Increased reserve creation as a result of U.S. payments deficits, which produced larger claims on the United States, provided the basis for an expansion of credit and money in other countries. However, it is hard to accept this development as a full explanation of rising worldwide inflation rates in the second half of the 1960s.

First, the U.S. deficits were initially only meeting an urgent need in other countries. Far from threatening the system, they actually allowed it to work. Moreover, the price behavior of the surplus countries, which was always used as the most striking evidence in support of the theory of international inflation, can be explained in a quite different way. A major part of the explanation of why Germany and Japan saw the international monetary system of the 1960s as more inflationary than did the Americans is to be found simply in the nature of the growth process of Europe and Japan. Japan and Germany experienced in the 1960s a development of prices quite comparable with that of the United States. The increased price of nontradables relative to tradables that was an intrinsic part of the process of catching up in an initially much poorer and less developed economy led to overall higher consumer prices.57 The consequence of their productivity growth meant that their costs grew less quickly than U.S. costs, while their consumer price behavior seemed to reflect the impact of international inflation. Thus, they both accumulated big surplus balances in the second half of the 1960s, the counterpart of very high saving rates. The surplus countries sometimes concluded that their high rates of inflation were a consequence of external monetary developments. Only in a limited sense was this diagnosis correct, since, for the surpluses to have been avoided, Germany and Japan would have had to maintain substantially higher rates of inflation than the United States, and they were not willing to do this.

This analysis remained essentially valid until the end of the decade. In 1968 and 1969 consumer price increases were higher in France (4.6 percent and 6.1 percent, respectively), the United Kingdom (4.7 and 5.5 percent), and Japan (5.4 and 5.2 percent) than in the United States (3.9 and 4.7 percent), although the rates were lower in Italy and Germany (see Figure 7-1). Monetary authorities in these expansive states were responding to new domestic situations—the intensive labor unrest and heightened political instability—as much as they were accommodating the monetary consequences of the action of the U.S. government or of the Federal Reserve System (see Figure 7-2).

Figure 7-1.
Figure 7-1.

Consumer Price Inflation in United States, Japan, and Germany

(In percent)

Source: International Monetary Fund, International Financial Statistics.
Figure 7-2.
Figure 7-2.

Money Growth in United States, Japan, and Germany

(Annual change in percent)

Source: International Monetary Fund, International Financial Statistics.

The alternative explanation for gathering inflation therefore looks at domestic developments. By the end of the decade, there were strong internal reasons for Europeans to adopt a more expansive policy, and the U.S. dollar inflows merely provided them with an adequate reserve base on which to build expansion. The pattern of European development was changing. The results of the “golden age,” full employment and labor scarcities, began to erode the relative price stability that had also been a component of that “golden age.”

The long postwar boom in the large continental European states had been sustained by the movement of labor from low productivity agriculture into much higher productivity occupations in manufacturing and services. By the mid-1960s, the rural source of labor supply had been largely exhausted, and the continental economies reached the position the United Kingdom had been in since the beginning of the century. There were no more domestic supplies of cheap labor. The pace of productivity growth and income growth as a result slowed. At the same time, sustained full employment increased the bargaining position of labor, led to an increase in wage demands and then to an accommodating monetary policy. Given the labor bargaining environment, any other option would have produced higher levels of unemployment and would have challenged the social compromise on which the “golden age” was founded. The situation on the labor market allowed a new wave of militancy in putting forward labor’s demands.58 Unions became much more powerful. In 1968, two thirds of the labor force in France was involved in strikes; in Germany one million workers were on strike, in Italy four million. The number of work days lost through strikes in the United Kingdom increased every year from 1965 to 1970. At this time, all European countries introduced legislation making redundancy harder, and thus further strengthening the position of labor,59 and encouraged the inflationary wage-push momentum. Some countries, especially those with strong trade performances, saw the achievement of current account surpluses as a way of achieving high employment levels, or of exporting unemployment. If many countries had followed this line, there would have been a danger of a 1930s-style development, in which a competition between nations for current account surpluses would have forced deflation on the whole system.

In practice it did not produce this result, because of the development of international capital markets. The temptation posed by “growthmanship” for the management of the current account was exactly the opposite to that outlined above. In this case, the belief that the stimulation of demand for the sake of maintaining full employment was held to justify running a current account deficit. It many countries had adopted this view, there would have been a risk of a competition for current account deficits, which would have unsettled the then very inexperienced international capital markets. At the outset of the postwar era, in the absence of large capital movements, countries needed to maintain approximately a current account balance. However, in most countries, there was little correlation in the 1960s between private savings and investment, so that any adjustment needed to be made through fiscal policy.60 If the economy overheated as investment moved ahead of savings, the government would (as a result of the balance of payments constraint) impose fiscal austerity. Public sector saving would thus make up for the shortfall in private saving. Limitations on capital movements therefore limited government policy in a way governments found uncomfortable (especially if elections were imminent). In the late 1960s, as increased capital movements became available, governments saw a way out of these constraints, and inflation became the order of the day.

Conflicts between different ways of understanding a problem always reflect different understandings on how it should be tackled. If the domestic and structural, labor market-related, explanation of inflation was accepted, little could be done. If, on the other hand, the monetary explanation was thought to be correct, a solution was easier. It required a barrier to the international transmission of monetary expansion.

The prevalence of inflation at accelerating rates, in combination with national differences in inflation rates as a consequence, provided a stimulus to new thoughts about the attractions of floating currencies. Might this course not offer a way of uncoupling an economy from the international inflationary dynamic? It certainly looked easier than renegotiating the pattern of industrial relations that lay at the heart of the social compromise. Currency arrangements can be quicker to fix than domestic institutional structures.

In June 1969 the German central banker Otmar Emminger had stated in a public speech:

I fear that the Federal Republic is pretty well alone with this insistence of public opinion on price stability. It seems that most other countries ate prepared to tolerate annual price increases of 3 % or even more, be it as a seemingly inevitable price for higher growth, or be it as a facile way out of social pressures in a “mass democracy.” … it may be useful to examine whether individual countries, whose price developments get out of line for an extended period in relation to the general international average … could adjust their exchange rate in an easier and more gradual way.61

There might even be a way of preserving an important element of currency stability. The most immediately attractive answer to American instability and the problem of the American reserve role lay in the building of a greater stability in Europe—the resurrection of the regionalism that had proved so successful in the case of the European Payments Union (EPU). The idea had been advocated in the mid-1960s by one of the original architects of the EPU. After de Gaulle‗s explosive February 1965 press conference, the economist Robert Triffin had written to the President in an attempt to turn the Frenchman’s remarks to positive effect. Triffin made clear his agreement with the diagnosis of the dollar’s “exorbitant privilege,” but argued that the French reform proposals could realistically be realized only in a European, and not a global context. One of the aims of the Europeans should be to construct a system of liquidity that would remove the IMF from “any necessity, or any power, of intervening in measures that affect the balance of payments between members of the European Economic Community.”62

There existed in particular a specific technical problem, which might be solved through a European initiative. The Bretton Woods par value system contained a mechanism that encouraged the use of the dollar as a reserve currency. Par values were fixed relative to gold or to the dollar (Article IV, Section 1(a)), and spot exchange transactions were not to deviate more than 1 percent from parity. The signatories of the 1958 European Monetary Agreement had agreed to let their currencies vary only 0.75 percent either side of the dollar parity. Two nondollar currencies could therefore move 1.5 percent against each other (if the one were at its ceiling relative to the dollar, and the other at its floor). As a result, the permitted fluctuation margins of two European currencies were twice that of either with the dollar; and since the exchange risk of holding dollars was thus half, the dollar was a more satisfactory store of liquidity. Triffin saw this as a major inducement for foreign central banks to continue the (undesirable) financing of the U.S. payments deficit. This problem could only be tackled if European currencies agreed to narrower bands among themselves than those permitted under Bretton Woods.

The Hague summit of the European Community in December 1969, called to “relaunch Europe” once again, produced a declaration that political union was the major goal of the next stage of European unification. In order to implement economic union, which entailed monetary union, a study group of experts under the Prime Minister of Luxembourg, Pierre Werner, in October 1970 recommended the progressive adoption of a common monetary policy, with the adoption of a narrower band for Community currencies.63 Creation of a monetary mechanism alone, however, was not enough. Countries should adopt policies promoting economic convergence (as provided for in Articles 104 and 105 of the Treaty of Rome). The Europeans should be obliged to engage in a closer coordination of fiscal policy. Werner provided a quite ambitious program for simultaneous monetary and fiscal adjustment.

In reality the dollar glut and its effects on international money creation did not constitute the only difficulty confronting the international monetary system. National responses to the ending of the favorable economic conditions of the “golden age” differed very widely, even in Europe. The Werner Report could be interpreted in two conflicting ways: some, mostly in Germany, believed that its implementation required increased economic convergence preceding monetary integration. Others, especially in France, saw prior monetary developments as the most effective mechanism for forcing a greater economic convergence. An objection to the French line of reasoning went as follows: had the failure of the Bretton Woods system to produce convergence simply and purely been the result of the American irresponsibility that General de Gaulle regarded as the fundamental cause of world economic instability? Or was this not too simple an explanation, and was not the American case only one example of the proclivity of states to go their own way, and for currency markets to react to national policy differences?

In practice, the recommendations of the Werner committee were submerged by the tide of international currency instability that emanated in 1970 and 1971 not from the European currencies but from the U.S. dollar. Even the regional alternative to a global reordering fell a victim of the systemic inability to solve simultaneously the double international problem of the 1960s: the international liquidity situation and the nature of domestic adjustment processes. Some blamed the international system. Some blamed the speculators. But both were doing nothing more than transmitting responses to differences in national performance: differences that were a product both of policy choices as well as deeper structural reasons.

The United States now lay at the center of the international instability, as a result of its own surge of monetary growth in 1970 and later. It had treated the prolonged sterling crisis so seriously not just because of the sentimentality of the “special relationship” with the United Kingdom, or out of common strategic interests, but for the immediately practical reason that the United Kingdom demonstrated the problems faced by a reserve country once individuals, investors, or other countries decided to liquidate part or all of their reserves. In this way the British currency came to be regarded as part of the “outer perimeter defenses” of the dollar itself. The United Kingdom had merely gone further down the road and showed the United States what might lie ahead. As a result, U.S. policymakers, if they valued economic power (which they did), and if they did not want to be held to ransom by the system, would gradually move to the conclusion that it might be better to attack the system than to work within it.

The powers given to international institutions under the Bretton Woods agreements were clearly not sufficient to prevent this type of disruption. All the IMF could do was attempt to persuade and convince. In conflicts with the interests of the system, national interests always win unless there is an argument (and someone to articulate it forcefully) that national well-being depends on the well-functioning of the system. The principle of surveillance involved the identification of systemic problems and the demonstration of the concurrence of national and systemic benefits. It was concerned with the balance of payments within the world system as a whole; and it should have given greater attention to exchange rates and their role in adjustment, and to the whole question of the appropriate structure of exchange rates.

The fudged compromise of the late 1940s formed the backdrop to the crisis of the late 1960s. With the adoption of what was in practice a key currency system, the operators of the reserve currencies (the United States and the United Kingdom) became unwilling to accept the principle of surveillance and able for long stretches to ignore its implications. When the result of ignoring persistent payments imbalances became evident, it would, as a consequence, inevitably take the form of a sudden swing in confidence and the outbreak of a crisis. Yet the system as it existed actually needed U.S. deficits in order to provide liquidity. This was one of the reasons why the reformers who drew up the SDR as the intended central reserve unit of the system had the right concept. At least in a fixed exchange system, effective surveillance is difficult to reconcile with key currencies. In a flexible system, the market would be making judgments all the time, and not just in crises, about the dollar and the pound, and the room for “exorbitant privilege” would be correspondingly greatly reduced. A move either to gold or to an artificial reserve unit would be the only way of tackling this issue in a system of stable exchange rates.

As a consequence, the surveillance of the 1960s was necessarily incomplete and imperfect. In order to have been faithful to the objectives and vision of Bretton Woods, it would have had to include a more adequate surveillance of the growth of financial markets and its implications. It would have needed to limit the international inflation resulting from the position of the dollar and from the U.S. policy mix. The latter, however, had become a tabu subject. Such imperfections could have no remedies within the existing system. Their existence undermined the fixed rate monetary regime.

  • Collapse
  • Expand
  • Adams, Patricia, “The World Bank and the IMF in Sub-Saharan Africa: Undermining Development and Environmental Sustainability,” Journal of International Affairs, Vol. 46, No. 1 (1992).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • African Development Bank, Report by the Board of Directors, various issues.

  • Alexander, Sidney S., “Effects of a Devaluation on a Trade Balance,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 2 (April 1952).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Andrew, Christopher, and Oleg Gordievsky, KGB: The Inside Story of Its Foreign Operations from Lenin to Gorbachev (New York: HarperCollins, 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Angell, Norman, The Great Illusion: A Study of the Relation of Military Power in Nations to Their Economic and Social Advantage (New York: G.P. Putnam’s Sons, 1911).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Antowska-Bartosiewicz, Iwona, and Witold Małecki, Poland’s External Debt Problem by the End of 1991 (Warsaw: Friedrich Ebert Foundation for Poland, 1992).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Argy, Victor, “Monetary Variables and the Balance of Payments,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 16 (July 1969).

  • Artis, Michael J., “How Accurate Is the World Economic Outlook? A Post Mortem on Short-Term Forecasting at the International Monetary Fund,” Staff Studies for the World Economic Outlook, World Economic and Financial Surveys (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1988).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Artus, Jacques R., “The 1967 Devaluation of the Pound Sterling,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 22 (November 1975).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Artus, Jacques R., and Rudolf R. Rhomberg, “A Multilateral Exchange Rate Model,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 20 (November 1973).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Aschinger, F.E., “The Future of Convertibility,” Swiss Review of World Affairs, Vol. 4, No. 8 (November 1954).

  • Ash, Timothy Garton, The Polish Revolution: Solidarity 1980–1982 (London: Jonathan Cape, 1983).

  • Ash, Timothy Garton, The Magic Lantern: The Revolution of’89 Witnessed in Warsaw, Budapest, Berlin and Prague (New York: Random House, 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Aspe Armella, Pedro, “The Renegotiation of Mexico’s External Debt,” Institute of Development Studies, IDS Bulletin, Vol. 21, No. 2 (1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Aspe Armella, Pedro, Economic Transformation: The Mexican Way (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press, 1993).

  • Attali, Jacques, Verbatim, Vol. 1, Chronique des années 1981–1986 (Paris: Fayard, 1993).

  • Auboin, Roger, The Bank for International Settlements, 1930–1955, Essays in International Finance No. 22 (Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press, 1955).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bacha, Edmar Lisboa, and Carlos F. Díaz-Alejandro, “Tropical Reflections on the History and Theory of International Financial Markets,” in For Good or Evil: Economic Theory and North-South Negotiations, ed. by Gerald K. Helleiner (Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 1982).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Balassa, Bela, “The Purchasing-Power Parity Doctrine: A Reappraisal,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 72 (December 1964).

  • Balassa, Bela, and John Williamson, Adjusting to Success: Balance of Payments Policy in the East Asian NICs (Washington: Institute for International Economics, 1987).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Balcerowicz, Leszek, 800 Dni: Szok Kontrolowany (Warsaw: Polska Oficyna Wydawnicza BGW, 1992).

  • Balcerowicz, Leszek, Eastern Europe: Economic, Social and Political Dynamics: A Lecture (London: School of Slavonic and East European Studies, University of London, 1993).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Balcerowicz, Leszek, “Poland,” in The Political Economy of Policy Reform, ed. by John Williamson (Washington: Institute for International Economics, 1994).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Balogh, Thomas, The Dollar Crisis: Causes and Cure, A Report to the Fabian Society (Oxford: Basil Blackwell, 1949).

  • Bangura, Yusuf, “IMF/World Bank Conditionality and Nigeria’s Structural Adjustment Programme,” in The IMF and the World Bank in Africa: Conditionality, Impact and Alternatives, ed. by Kjell J. Havnevik (Uppsala: Scandinavian Institute of African Studies, 1987).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bangura, Yusuf, “Crisis and Adjustment: The Experience of Nigerian Workers,” in The IMF, the World Bank and the African Debt, Vol. 2, The Social and Political Impact, ed. by Bade Onimode (London: Institute for African Alternatives and Zed Books, 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bank for International Settlements, Annual Report, various issues.

  • Bank for International Settlements, Committee on Banking Regulations and Supervisory Practices, Management of Banks’ International Lending: Country Risk Analysis and Country Exposure Measurement and Control (Basle: Bank for International Settlements, March 1982).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Baring, Arnulf, Machtwechsel: Die Ära Brandt-Scheel (Stuttgart: Deutsche Verlags-Anstalt, 1982).

  • Barrionuevo, José M., “Annex III: The Accuracy of World Economic Outlook Projections for Industrial and Developing Countries,” in International Monetary Fund, World Economic Outlook, October 1992: A Survey by the Staff of the International Monetary Fund, World Economic and Financial Surveys (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1992).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bates, Robert H., Markets and States in Tropical Africa: The Political Basis of Agricultural Policies (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1981).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bayoumi, Tamim, “Saving-Investment Correlations: Immobile Capital, Government Policy, or Endogenous Behavior?” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 37 (June 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bazdresch, Carlos, and Santiago Levy, “Populism and Economic Policy in Mexico 1970–1982,” in The Macroeconomics of Populism in Latin America, ed. by Rudiger Dornbusch and Sebastian Edwards (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bell, Michael W., Hoe Ee Khor, and Kalpana Kochhar, China at the Threshold of a Market Economy, IMF Occasional Paper No. 107 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1993).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Benn, Tony, Against the Tide: Diaries 1973–76 (London: Hutchinson, 1989).

  • Berend, Iván T., and Györgi Ránki, Economic Development in East-Central Europe in the 19th and 20th Centuries (New York: Columbia University Press, 1974).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bergsten, C. Fred, “Economic Imbalances and World Politics,” Foreign Affairs, Vol. 65, No. 4 (Spring 1987).

  • Bermeo, Nancy, and José García-Duran, “Spain: Dual Transition Implemented by Two Parties,” in Voting for Reform: Democracy, Political Liberalization, and Economic Adjustment, ed. by Stephan Haggard and Steven B. Webb (New York: Oxford University Press, 1994).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bernanke, Ben, and Harold James, “The Gold Standard, Deflation, and Financial Crisis in the Great Depression: An International Comparison,” in Financial Markets and Financial Crises, ed. by R. Glenn Hubbard (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bhagwati, Jagdish N., “Export Market Disruption, Compensation and GATT Reform,” in Bhagwati, ed., The New International Economic Order: The North-South Debate (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press, 1977).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bhagwati, Jagdish N., Anatomy and Consequences of Exchange Control Regimes (New York: Ballinger for National Bureau of Economic Research, 1978).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bhatia, Rattan J., The West African Monetary Union: An Analytic Review, IMF Occasional Paper No. 35 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1985).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Black, Stanley W., A Levite Among the Priests: Edward M. Bernstein and the Origins of the Bretton Woods System (Boulder, Colorado: Westview Press, 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Blum, John Morton, From the Morgenthau Diaries, Vol. 3, Years of War 1941–1945 (Boston: Houghton Mifflin, 1967).

  • Boltho, Andrea, The European Economy: Growth and Crisis (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1982).

  • Bolton, Sir George, “Background and Emergence of the Eurodollar Market,” in The Eurodollar, ed. by Herbert V. Prochnow (Chicago: Rand McNally, 1970).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Boorman, Jack, “A View from the IMF,” in Policies for African Development: From the 1980s to the 1990s, ed. by I.G. Patel (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1992).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Borchardt, Knut, “Can Societies Learn from Economic Crisis?” German Yearbook on Business History 1984 (Berlin: Springer Verlag, 1985).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Borchardt, Knut, “Trend, Cycles, Structural Breaks, Chance: What Determines Twentieth Century German Economic History,” in Borchardt, Perspectives on Modern German Economic History, translated by Peter Lambert (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Borden, William S., “Defending Hegemony: American Foreign Economic Policy,” in Kennedy’s Quest for Victory: American Foreign Policy 1961–1963, ed. by Thomas G. Paterson (New York: Oxford University Press, 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bordo, Michael D., “The Bretton Woods System: A Historical Overview,” in A Retrospective on the Bretton Woods System: Lessons for International Monetary Reform, ed. by Michael D. Bordo and Barry Eichengreen (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1993).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bordo, Michael D., Dominique Simard, and Eugene White, “France and the Bretton Woods International Monetary System, 1960 to 1968,” NBER Working Paper No. 4642 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1994).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bordo, Michael D., and Barry Eichengreen, eds., A Retrospective on the Bretton Woods System: Lessons for International Monetary Reform (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1993).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Borromée, M. Christian, “Le général de Gaulle et le problème monétaire international,” Espoir, Vol. 4 (1973).

  • Bossuat, Gérard, La France, l’aide américaine et la construction européenne 1944–1954 (Paris: Comité pour l’histoire économique et financière, 1992).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bouchet, Michel H., and Jonathan Hay, “The Rise of the Market-Based ‘Menu’ Approach and Its Limitations,” in Dealing with the Debt Crisis, ed. by Ishrat Husain and Ishac Diwan (Washington: World Bank, 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Boughton, James M., The CFA Franc Zone: Currency Union and Monetary Standard, IMF Working Paper No. 91/133 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Boughton, James M., “France and the IMF in the Floating-Rate Era: What Role for Surveillance?” paper prepared for a conference on France and the Bretton Woods Institutions 1944–1994, Paris, 1994; forthcoming under the title “La France, le FMI et le régime des taux de change flottants: Quel rôle donner à la surveillance?” in La France et les Institutions de Bretton Woods, 1944–94 (Paris: CEPII, 1995).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Boughton, James M., “The IMF and the Latin American Debt Crisis: Seven Common Criticisms,” IMF Paper on Policy Analysis and Assessment No. 94/23 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, October 1994).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bourguignon, François, and Christian Morrisson, Adjustment and Equity in Developing Countries: A New Approach (Paris: Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, 1992).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Branger, J. (intr.), Les Banques de développement dans le monde (Paris: Dunod, 1964).

  • Brau, Eduard H., “External Debt Management in the African Context,” in Africa and the International Monetary Fund, ed. by Gerald K. Helleiner (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1986).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Brau, Eduard H., R.C. Williams, P.M. Keller, and M. Nowak, Recent Multilateral Debt Restructurings with Official and Bank Creditors, IMF Occasional Paper No. 25 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1983).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bretton Woods Commission, “Commission Report,” in Bretton Woods: Looking to the Future (Washington: Bretton Woods Committee, 1994).

  • Brittan, Samuel, A Restatement of Economic Liberalism (London: Macmillan, 1988).

  • Brown, J.F., Eastern Europe and Communist Rule (Durham, North Carolina: Duke University Press, 1988).

  • Brown, Richard P.C., Public Debt and Private Wealth: Debt, Capital Flight and the IMF in Sudan (London: Macmillan, 1992).

  • Brown, William Adams, Jr., The International Gold Standard Reinterpreted 1914–1934 (New York: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1940).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Brown, William Adams, Jr., and Redvers Opie, American Foreign Assistance (Washington: Brookings Institution, 1953).

  • Bruno, Michael, “Stabilization and the Macroeconomics of Transition—How Different Is Eastern Europe?” Economics of Transition, Vol. 1 (1993).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bruno, Michael, “Inflation and Growth in Recent History and Policy: Applications of an Integrated Approach,” in Understanding Interdependence: The Macroeconomics of the Open Economy, ed. by Peter B. Kenen (Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press, 1995).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bruton, Henry J., Inflation in a Growing Economy, Series in Monetary and International Economics, No. 2 (Bombay: Bombay University Press, 1961).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Bryant, Ralph C., International Financial Intermediation (Washington: Brookings Institution, 1987).

  • Buchheim, Christoph, “Das Londoner Schuldenabkommen,” in Westdeutschland 1945–1955: Unterwerfung, Kontrolle, Integration, ed. by Ludolf Herbst (Munich: Oldenbourg, 1986).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Buchheim, Christoph, Die Wiedereingliederung Westdeutschlands in die Weltwirtschaft 1945–1958 (Munich: Oldenbourg, 1990).

  • Bullock, Alan, Hitler and Stalin: Parallel Lives (New York: A.A. Knopf, 1992).

  • Bulow, Jeremy, and Kenneth Rogoff, “The Buyback Boondoggle,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1988(2).

  • Burk, Kathleen, “Witness Seminar on the Origins and Early Development of the Eurobond Market,” Contemporary European History, Vol. 1 (1992).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Burk, Kathleen, and Alec Cairncross, ‘Goodbye Great Britain’: The 1976 IMF Crisis (New Haven, Connecticut: Yale University Press, 1992).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cairncross, Alec, and Barry Eichengreen, Sterling in Decline: The Devaluations of 1931, 1949 and 1967 (Oxford: Basil Blackwell, 1983).

  • Cairncross, Alec, and Nita Watts, The Economic Section 1939–1961: A Study in Economic Advising (London: Routledge, 1989).

  • Callaghan, James, Time and Chance (London: Collins, 1987).

  • Callaghy, Thomas M., “Lost Between State and Market: The Politics of Economic Adjustment in Ghana, Zambia, and Nigeria,” in Economic Crisis and Policy Choice: The Politics of Adjustment in the Third World, ed. by Joan Nelson (Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press, 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Campos, Roberto de Oliveiro, “Inflation and Balanced Growth,” in Economic Development in Latin America: Proceedings of a Conference Held by the International Economic Association, ed. by Howard S. Ellis (New York: St. Martin’s Press, 1961).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cassel, Gustav, The Downfall of the Gold Standard (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1936).

  • Cassis, Youssef, Les Banquiers de la City à l’époque Edouardienne (Geneva: Librairie Droz, 1984).

  • Catte, Pietro, Giampaulo Galli, and Salvatore Rebecchini, “Concerted Interventions and the Dollar: An Analysis of Daily Data,” in The International Monetary System, ed. by Peter B. Kenen (Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press, 1994).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Chenery, H.B., and A.M. Strout, “Foreign Assistance and Economic Development,” American Economic Review, Vol. 56 (September 1966).

  • Chen, Edward K.Y., Hyper-growth in Asian Economies: A Comparative Study of Hong Kong, Japan, Korea, Singapore and Taiwan (London: Macmillan, 1979).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cheru, Fantu, “The Role of the IMF and the World Bank in the Agrarian Crisis of Sudan and Tanzania: Sovereignty vs. Control,” in The IMF, the World Bank and the African Debt, Vol. 2, The Social and Political Impact, ed. by Bade Onimode (London: Institute for African Alternatives and Zed Books, 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Choi, Ying-Pik, Hwa Soo Chung, and Nicolas Marian, The Multi-Fibre Arrangement in Theory and Practice (London: Frances Pinter, 1985).

  • Claessens, Stijn, and Sudarshan Gooptu, “Can Developing Countries Keep Foreign Capital Flowing In?” Finance & Development, Vol. 31 (September 1994).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Clarke, Stephen V.O., The Reconstruction of the International Monetary System: The Attempts of 1922 and 1933, Princeton Studies in International Finance No. 33 (Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press, 1973).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Clarke, Stephen V.O., Exchange-Rate Stabilization in the Mid-1930s: Negotiating the Tripartite Agreement, Princeton Studies in International Finance No. 41 (Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press, 1977).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Clavin, Patricia, “The World Economic Conference 1933: The Failure of British Internationalism,” Journal of European Economic History, Vol. 20, No. 3 (Winter 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Clément, Jean A.P., “Rationale for the CFA Franc Realignment,” IMF Survey, International Monetary Fund, February 7, 1994.

  • Cline, William R., International Monetary Reform and the Developing Countries (Washington: Brookings Institution, 1976).

  • Cline, William R., “International Debt: Analysis, Experience and Prospects,” Journal of Development Planning, No. 16 (1985).

  • Cline, William R., “The Baker Plan and Brady Reformulation: An Evaluation,” in Dealing with the Debt Crisis, ed. by Ishrat Husain and Ishac Diwan (Washington: World Bank, 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cline, William R., The Future of World Trade in Textiles and Apparel (Washington: Institute for International Economics, 1987, rev. ed., 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cline, William R., “Comment,” in Latin American Adjustment: How Much Has Happened? ed. by John Williamson (Washington: Institute for International Economics, 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cohen, Benjamin J., “The Revolution in Atlantic Economic Relations: A Bargain Comes Unstuck,” in The United States and Western Europe: Political, Economic and Strategic Perspectives, ed. by Wolfram F. Hanrieder (Cambridge, Massachusetts: Winthrop Publishers, 1974).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cohen, Benjamin J., In Whose Interest? International Banking and American Foreign Policy (New Haven, Connecticut: Yale University Press, 1986).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Commission of the European Communities, Documents: Annual Economic Report 1984–85 (Communication from the Commission to the Council), COM(84) 587 final (Luxembourg: Office for Official Publications of the European Council, October 29, 1985).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Committee for the Study of Economic and Monetary Union, Report on Economic and Monetary Union in the European Community (Delors Report) (Luxembourg: Office for Official Publications of the European Community, 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Committee of Twenty, “Report of the Technical Group on Disequilibrating Capital Flows, May 17, 1973,” in International Monetary Reform: Documents of the Committee of Twenty (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1975).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Committee on the Working of the Monetary System (Radcliffe Committee), Report, Cmnd. 827 (London: H.M. Stationary Office, August 1959).

  • Congdon, Tim, The Debt Threat: The Dangers of High Real Interest Rates for the World Economy (Oxford: Basil Blackwell, 1988).

  • Coombs, Charles A., The Arena of International Finance (New York: John Wiley & Sons, 1976).

  • Cooper, Richard N., The Economics of Interdependence: Economic Policy in the Atlantic Community (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1968).

  • Cooper, Richard N., “A Monetary System for the Future,” Foreign Affairs, Vol. 63, No. 1 (Fall 1984).

  • Cooper, Richard N., “The Evolution of the International Monetary Fund Toward a World Central Bank,” in Cooper, The International Monetary System: Essays in World Economics (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press, 1987; originally published 1983).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cooper, Richard N., “What Future for the International Monetary System?” in International Financial Policy: Essays in Honor of Jacques J. Polak, ed. by Jacob A. Frenkel and Morris Goldstein (Washington: International Monetary Fund and De Nederlandsche Bank, 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Corrigan, E. Gerald, “Challenges Facing the International Community of Bank Supervisers,” Quarterly Review, Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Vol. 17, No. 3 (1992).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cortés Conde, Roberto, “Growth and Stagnation in Argentina,” in Towards a Development Strategy for Latin America: Pathways from Hirschman’s Thought, ed. by Simón Teitel (Washington: Inter-American Development Bank, 1992).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Costigliola, Frank, “The Other Side of Isolationism: The Establishment of the First World Bank 1929–1930,” Journal of American History, Vol. 59 (December 1972).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Crockett, Andrew, International Money: Issues and Analysis (New York: Academic Press, 1977).

  • Crockett, Andrew, “Strengthening International Economic Cooperation: The Role of Indicators in Multilateral Surveillance,” in The Quest for National and Global Economic Stability, ed. by Wietze Eizenga, E. Frans Limburg, and Jacques J. Polak (Dordrecht: Kluwer, 1988).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Crockett, Andrew, “The International Monetary Fund in the 1990s,” Government and Opposition, Vol. 27, No. 3 (1992).

  • Crockett, Andrew, “Monetary Policy Implications of Increased Capital Flows,” Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin, Vol. 33, No. 4 (November 1993).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Crosland, Susan, Tony Crosland (London: Jonathan Cape, 1982).

  • Cumby, Robert, and Richard Levich, “Definitions and Magnitudes: On the Definition and Magnitude of Recent Capital Flight,” in Capital Flight and Third World Debt, ed. by Donald R. Lessard and John Williamson (Washington: Institute for International Economics, 1987).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Cumings, Bruce, “The Origins and Development of the Northeast Asian Political Economy: Industrial Sectors, Product Cycles, and Political Consequences,” International Organization, Vol. 38, No. 1 (Winter 1984).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dam, Kenneth W., The Rules of the Game: Reform and Evolution in the International Monetary System (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1982).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dasgupta, Partha, An Inquiry into Well-Being and Destitution (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1993).

  • De Cecco, Marcello, The International Gold Standard: Money and Empire (New York: St. Martin’s Press, 1984).

  • de Grauwe, Paul, International Money: Post-War Trends and Theories (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1989).

  • de Grauwe, Paul, Hans Dewachter, and Marc Embrechts, Exchange Rate Theory: Chaotic Models of Foreign Exchange Markets (Oxford: Basil Blackwell, 1993).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dell, Edmund, A Hard Pounding: Politics and Economic Crisis 1974–1976 (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1991).

  • Dell, Edmund, “Britain and the Origins of the European Monetary System,” Contemporary European History, Vol. 3 (1994).

  • Dell, Sidney, On Being Grandmotherly: The Evolution of IMF Conditionality, Essays in International Finance No. 144 (Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press, 1981).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Deshormes, Etienne, “Camille Gutt—Premier Directeur Général du Fond Monétaire International 1946–1951,” Revue de la Banque, Vol. 50, Supplément historique (July 1986).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Despres, Emile, Charles P. Kindleberger and Walter S. Salant, “The Dollar and World Liquidity: A Minority View,” Economist, February 11, 1966.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Destler, I.M., and C. Randall Henning, Dollar Politics: Exchange Rate Policymaking in the United States (Washington: Institute for International Economics, 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Deutsche Bundesbank, Deutsches Geld- und Bankwesen in Zahlen 1876–1975 (Frankfurt: Fritz Knapp, 1976).

  • de Vries, Margaret Garritsen, The International Monetary Fund 1966–1971: The System Under Stress, Vols. 1–2 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1976).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • de Vries, Margaret Garritsen, The International Monetary Fund 1972–1978: Cooperation on Trial, Vols. 1–3 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1985).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • de Vries, Margaret Garritsen, Balance of Payments Adjustment 1945 to 1986: The IMF Experience (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1987).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • de Vries, Rimmer, “The Limited Role of the IMF,” World Financial Markets, Morgan Guaranty Trust Company, April 1982.

  • Díaz-Alejandro, Carlos F., Exchange-Rate Devaluation in a Semi-Industrialized Country: The Experience of Argentina 1955–1961 (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press, 1965).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Díaz-Alejandro, Carlos F., “Some Economic Lessons of the Early 1980s,” in Power, Passions, and Purpose: Prospects for North-South Negotiations, ed. by Jagdish N. Bhagwati and John Ruggie (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press, 1984).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Diebold, William, Jr., Trade and Payments in Western Europe: A Study in Economic Cooperation, 1947–51 (New York: Harper, 1952).

  • Dillon, K. Burke, C. Maxwell Watson, G. Russell Kincaid, and Chanpen Puckahtikom, Recent Developments in External Debt Restructuring, IMF Occasional Paper No. 40 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1985).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dirks, Frederick C., “Monetary Policy in the U.S., Canada, and the U.K.,” in The Revival of Monetary Policy: Texts and Charts of an Informal Discussion at the Eighth Annual Meeting of the Board of Governors, International Monetary Fund, September 11, 1953 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1953).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dobson, Wendy, Economic Policy Coordination: Requiem or Prologue? (Washington: Institute for International Economics, 1991).

  • Dominguez, Kathryn, and Jeffrey A. Frankel, Does Foreign Exchange Intervention Work? (Washington: Institute for International Economics, 1993).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Donner, Richard F., “Approaches to the Politics of Economic Growth in Southeast Asia,” Journal of Asian Studies, Vol. 50 (November 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dooley, Michael P., “An Analysis of the Debt Crisis,” IMF Working Paper No. 86/14 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, December 1986).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dornbusch, Rudiger, “Discussion,” in Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, Key Issues in International Banking (Boston: Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, 1977).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dornbusch, Rudiger, “Overborrowing: Three Case Studies,” in Dornbusch, Dollars, Debts and Deficits (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press, 1986; and Leuven, Belgium: Leuven University Press, 1986).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dornbusch, Rudiger, “The World Debt Problem: 1980–84 and Beyond,” in Dornbusch, Dollars, Debts and Deficits (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press, 1986, and Leuven, Belgium: Leuven University Press, 1986).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dornbusch, Rudiger, “Secretary Baker Hits the Campaign Trail,” New York Times, October 7, 1987.

  • Dornbusch, Rudiger, “Mexico: Stabilization, Debt and Growth,” Economic Policy, No. 7 (October 1988).

  • Dornbusch, Rudiger, “Debt Problems and the World Macroeconomy,” in Developing Country Debt and Economic Performance, Vol. 1, The International Financial System, ed. by Jeffrey D. Sachs (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dornbusch, Rudiger, Structural Adjustment in Latin America (Washington: Woodrow Wilson Center, 1991).

  • Dornbusch, Rudiger, and Yung Chul Park, “Korean Growth Policy,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Brookings Institution, 1987(2).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dornbusch, Rudiger, and Sebastian Edwards, “The Macroeconomics of Populism,” in The Macroeconomics of Populism in Latin America, ed. by Rudiger Dornbusch and Sebastian Edwards (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Dorrance, Graeme S., “The Effect of Inflation on Economic Development,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 10 (March 1963).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Drummond, Ian M., London, Washington, and the Management of the Franc, 1936–1939, Princeton Studies in International Finance No. 45 (Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press, 1979).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Economic Report of the President, Transmitted to the Congress (Washington: U.S. Government Printing Office), various issues.

  • Eichengreen, Barry, Golden Fetters: The Gold Standard and the Great Depression, 1919–1939 (New York: Oxford University Press, 1992).

  • Eichengreen, Barry, “A Payments Mechanism for the Former Soviet Union: Is the EPU a Relevant Precedent?” Economic Policy, Vol. 17 (October 1993).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Eichengreen, Barry, and Jeffrey Sachs, “Exchange Rates and Economic Recovery in the 1930s,” Journal of Economic History, Vol. 45 (1985).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Eisner, Robert, “The Twin Deficits,” in Profits, Deficits and Instability, ed. by Dimitri B. Papadimitriou (New York: St. Martin’s Press, 1992).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Elliott, William Y., The Political Economy of American Foreign Policy: Its Concepts, Strategy, and Limits (New York: Henry Holt, 1955).

  • Ellis, Howard S., Exchange Control in Central Europe (Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press, 1941).

  • Emminger, Otmar, “Internationaler Währungsfond und Wechselkurspolitik,” Zeitschrift für das Gesamte Kreditwesen, Vol. 10 (September 1957).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Emminger, Otmar, “Deutsche Geld- und Währungspolitik im Spannungsfeld zwischen innerem und äusserem Gleichgewicht (1948–1975),” in Emminger, Deutsche Bundesbank, Währung und Wirtschaft in Deutschland 1876–1975 (Frankfurt: Fritz Knapp, 1976).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Emminger, Otmar, D-Mark, Dollar, Währungskrisen: Erinnerungen eines ehemaligen Bundesbankpräsidenten (Stuttgart: Deutsche Verlags-Anstalt, 1986).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Favier, Pierre, and Michel Martin-Roland, La Deécennie Mitterrand, Vol. 1, Les ruptures (1981–1984) (Paris: Editions Seuil, 1990).

  • Feavearyear, Sir Albert, The Pound Sterling: A History of English Money (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2nd ed., 1963).

  • Fei, John C.H., Gustav Ranis, and Shirley W.Y. Kuo, Growth with Equity: The Taiwan Case (New York: Oxford University Press, 1979).

  • Fekete, János, “Reform of the International Monetary System is Imminent,” in Fekete, Back to the Realities: Reflections of a Hungarian Banker (Budapest: Akadémiai Kiadó, 1982).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Feldman, Gerald D., The Great Disorder: Politics, Economics, and Society in the German Inflation 1914–1924 (New York: Oxford University Press, 1993).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Feldstein, Martin, “American Economic Policy and the World Economy,” Foreign Affairs, Vol. 63, No. 5 (Summer 1985).

  • Feldstein, Martin, “Correcting the Trade Deficit,” Foreign Affairs, Vol. 65, No. 4 (1987).

  • Feldstein, Martin, and Charles Horioka, “Domestic Saving and International Capital Flows,” Economic Journal, Vol. 90 (June 1980).

  • Ferenczi, Imre, and Walter F. Willcox, International Migrations, Vol. 1 (New York: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1929).

  • Fernández, Roque B., “What Have Populists Learned from Hyperinflation,” in The Macroeconomics of Populism in Latin America, ed. by Rudiger Dornbusch and Sebastian Edwards (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fforde, John, The Bank of England and Public Policy 1941–1958 (Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press, 1992).

  • Finch, David, “Let the IMF be the IMF,” The International Economy, January/February 1988.

  • Finger, J.M., “Trade Liberalization: A Public Choice Perspective,” in Challenges to a Liberal International Economic Order, ed. by Ryan C. Amacher, Gottfried Haberler, and Thomas D. Willett (Washington: American Enterprise Institute, 1979).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Flanagan, Robert J., David W. Soskice, and Lloyd Ulman, Unionism, Economic Stabilization, and Incomes Policies: European Experience (Washington: Brookings Institution, 1983).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fleming, J. Marcus, “Domestic Financial Policies Under Fixed and Under Floating Exchange Rates,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 9 (November 1962).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fontana, Josep, and Jordi Nadal, “Spain 1914–1970,” in The Fontana Economic History of Europe: Contemporary Economies, Vol. 2, ed. by Carlo M. Cipolla (Glasgow: Collins, 1976).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Foreign Relations of the United States, Diplomatic Papers 1941, Vols. 1 and 3 (Washington: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1959).

  • Frankel, Jeffrey A., and Katharine C. Rockett, “International Macroeconomic Policy Coordination When Policymakers Do Not Agree on the True Model,” American Economic Review, Vol. 78 (June 1988).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Frenkel, Jacob A., Morris Goldstein, and Paul R. Masson, “International Coordination of Economic Policies: Scope, Methods, and Effects,” in Economic Policy Coordination, ed. by Wilfried Guth (Washington: International Monetary Fund and HWWA-Institut für Wirtschaftsforschung-Hamburg, 1988).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Fried, Edward R., and Charles L. Shultze, Higher Oil Prices and the World Economy: The Adjustment Problem (Washington: Brookings Institution, 1975).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Frieden, Jeffry A., Banking on the World: The Politics of American International Finance (New York: Harper & Row, 1987).

  • Friedman, Irving S., “Evaluation of Risk in International Lending: A Lender’s Perspective,” in Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, Key Issues in International Banking (Boston: Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, 1977).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Friedman, Milton, Essays in Positive Economics (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1953).

  • Friedman, Milton, “Monetary Policy: Theory and Practice,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 14 (February 1982).

  • Friedman, Milton, “Bimetallism Revisited,” in Friedman, Money Mischief: Episodes in Monetary History (New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, 1992).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Friedman, Milton, and Rose Friedman, Free to Choose: A Personal Statement (New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, 1980).

  • Funabashi, Yoichi, Managing the Dollar: From the Plaza to the Louvre (Washington: Institute for International Economics, 2nd ed., 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Funk, Walther, The Economic Future of Europe (Berlin: Terramare Office, 1940).

  • Furtado, Celso, The Economic Growth of Brazil: A Survey from Colonial to Modern Times, translated by Ricardo W. de Aguiar and Eric Charles Drysdale (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1963).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Furtado, Celso, “Post-National Capitalism,” in Latin American Research Unit, Studies, Vol. 2, No. 2 (February 1978).

  • Gaddis, John Lewis, Strategies of Containment: A Critical Appraisal of Postwar American National Security Policy (New York: Oxford University Press, 1982).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gardner, Richard N., Sterling-Dollar Diplomacy: The Origins and the Prospects of Our International Economic Order (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1969).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • German Council of Economic Experts, Toward a New Basis for International Monetary Policy, Princeton Essays in International Finance No. 31 (Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press, 1972).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ghosh, Jayati, “Foreign Debt and Economic Development: The Case of Zaire,” Development and Change, Vol. 17 (1986).

  • Giavazzi, Francesco, and Alberto Giovannini, “The Role of the Exchange-Rate Regime in a Disinflation: Empirical Evidence on the European Monetary System,” in The European Monetary System, ed. by Francesco Giavazzi, Stefano Micossi, and Marcus Miller (Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press, 1988).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Giersch, Herbert, Karl-Heinz Paqué, and Holger Schmieding, The Fading Miracle: Four Decades of Market Economy in Germany (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1992).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gilbert, Milton, Quest for World Monetary Order: The Gold-Dollar System and Its Aftermath (New York: John Wiley & Sons, 1980).

  • Gilpin, Robert, and Jean Gilpin, The Political Economy of International Relations (Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press, 1987).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gimbel, John, The Origins of the Marshall Plan (Stanford, California: Stanford University Press, 1976).

  • Giscard d’Estaing, Valéry, “La politique monétaire internationale de la France,” Problèmes Economiques, No. 898, March 16, 1965.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gold, Joseph, “Some Notes on the Creation of Reserve Assets” (unpublished, 1965).

  • Gold, Joseph, The Stand-By Arrangements of the International Monetary Fund: A Commentary on Their Formal, Legal, and Financial Aspects (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1970).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gold, Joseph, Membership and Nonmembership in the International Monetary Fund: A Study in International Law and Organization (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1974).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gold, Joseph, Legal and Institutional Aspects of the International Monetary System: Selected Essays, Vol. 1 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1979).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gold, Joseph, “Law and Reform of the International Monetary System,” in Gold, Legal and Institutional Aspects of the International Monetary System: Selected Essays, Vol. 1 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1979).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gold, Joseph, “Uniformity as a Legal Principle of the Fund,” in Gold, Legal and Institutional Aspects of the International Monetary System: Selected Essays, Vol. 1 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1979).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gold, Joseph, The Rule of Law in the International Monetary Fund, IMF Pamphlet Series, No. 32 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1980).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gold, Joseph, Legal and Institutional Aspects of the International Monetary System: Selected Essays, Vol. 2 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1984).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gold, Joseph, “A New Universal and a New Regional Monetary Asset: SDR and ECU,” in Gold, Legal and Institutional Aspects of the International Monetary System: Selected Essays, Vol. 2 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1984).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gold, Joseph, “Developments in the International Monetary System, the International Monetary Fund, and International Monetary Law Since 1971,” in Gold, Legal and Institutional Aspects of the International Monetary System: Selected Essays, Vol. 2 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1984).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Goldstein, Morris, The Global Effects of Fund-Supported Adjustment Programs, IMF Occasional Paper No. 42 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1986).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Goldstein, Morris, David Folkerts-Landau, Mohamed El-Erian, Steven Fries, and Liliana Rojas-Suarez, International Capital Markets: Developments, Prospects, and Policy Issues, World Economic and Financial Surveys (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1992).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Goldstein, Morris, David Folkerts-Landau, Peter Garber, Liliana Rojas-Suarez, and Michael Spencer, International Capital Markets, Part I, Exchange Rate Management and International Capital Flows, World Economic and Financial Surveys (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1993).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Goldstein, Morris, and others, International Capital Markets, Part II, Systemic Issues in International Finance, World Economic and Financial Surveys (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1993).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Goodhart, Charles A.E., “Monetary Policy in the United Kingdom,” in Monetary Policy in Twelve Industrial Countries, ed. by Karel Holbik (Boston: Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, 1973).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Goodhart, Charles A.E., “The Conduct of Monetary Policy,” Economic Journal, Vol. 99 (June 1989).

  • Goodman, John B., Monetary Sovereignty: The Politics of Central Banking in Western Europe (Ithaca, New York: Cornell University Press, 1992).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gorbachev, Mikhail, Gipfelgespräche: Geheime Protokolle aus meiner Amtszeit (Berlin: Rowohlt, 1993).

  • Gowa, Joanne, Closing the Gold Window: Domestic Politics and the End of Bretton Woods (Ithaca, New York: Cornell University Press, 1983).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Graham, Edward M., and Paul R. Krugman, “The Surge in Foreign Direct Investment in the 1980s,” in Foreign Direct Investment, ed. by Kenneth A. Froot (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1993).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Granatstein, J.L., The Ottawa Men: The Civil Service Mandarins, 1935–1957 (Toronto: Oxford University Press, 1982).

  • Granirer, Daniel, “A Modern Great Power Concert: New York, Tokyo, and the Political Economy of International Financial Regulatory Cooperation,” Princeton University, doctoral dissertation, 1994.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Greider, William, Secrets of the Temple: How the Federal Reserve Runs the Country (New York: Simon and Schuster, 1987).

  • Gross, Jan T., “Poland: From Civil Society to Political Nation,” in Eastern Europe in Revolution, ed. by Ivo Banac (Ithaca, New York: Cornell University Press, 1992).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Guindey, Guillaume, The International Monetary Tangle: Myths and Realities, translated by Michael L. Hoffman (White Plains, New York: M.E. Sharpe, 1977; French original, 1973).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Guisinger, Stephen, “Foreign Direct Investment Flows in East and Southeast Asia: Policy Issues,” ASEAN Economic Bulletin, Vol. 8, No. 1 (July 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Guitián, Manuel, Fund Conditionality: Evolution of Principles and Practices, IMF Pamphlet Series, No. 38 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1981).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Guitián, Manuel, Rules and Discretion in International Economic Policy, IMF Occasional Paper No. 97 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1992).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Guitián, Manuel, “The Issue of Capital Account Convertibility: A Gap Between Norms and Reality,” paper presented at a seminar on currency convertibility, Marrakech, Morocco, December 16–18, 1993.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Guth, Wilfried, “Summary and Conclusions—Economic Policy Objectives and Policymaking in the Major Industrial Countries,” in Guth, ed., Economic Policy Coordination (Washington: International Monetary Fund and HWWA-Institut für Wirtschaftsforschung-Hamburg, 1988).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Guttentag, Jack M., and Herring, Richard J., Disaster Myopia in International Banking, Essays in International Finance No. 164 (Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press, 1986).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gwin, Catherine, “Financing India’s Adjustment: The Role of the Fund,” in IMF Conditionality, ed. by John Williamson (Washington: Institute for International Economics, 1983).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Gwynne, S.C., Selling Money (New York: Weidenfeld & Nicolson, 1986).

  • Haberler, Gottfried, “Review of Harrod, ‘Are these Hardships Necessary?’” Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 30 (May 1948).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Haberler, Gottfried, “Terms of Trade and Economic Development,” in Economic Development for Latin America: Proceedings of a Conference Held by the International Economic Association, ed. by Howard S. Ellis (New York: St. Martin’s Press, 1961).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Haberler, Gottfried, “How Important Is Control over International Reserves?” (1977), in Selected Essays of Gottfried Haberler, ed. by Anthony Y.C. Koo (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press, 1985).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hadley, Eleanor M., “The Diffusion of Keynesian Ideas in Japan,” in The Political Power of Economic Ideas: Keynesianism Across Nations, ed. by Peter A. Hall (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Haggard, Stephan, Richard N. Cooper, and Chung-in Moon, “Policy Reform in Korea,” in Political and Economic Interactions in Economic Policy Reform: Evidence from Eight Countries, ed. by Robert H. Bates and Anne O. Krueger (Oxford: Basil Blackwell, 1993).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Haldeman, H.R., The Haldeman Diaries: Inside the Nixon White House, ed. by Stephen E. Ambrose (New York: G.P. Putnam’s Sons, 1994).

  • Hall, John Whitney, ed., The Cambridge History of Japan, Vol. 4, Early Modern Japan (Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press, 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hansen, Alvin H., America’s Role in the World Economy (New York: W.W. Norton, 1945).

  • Hardy, Chandra S., Rescheduling Developing-Country Debts, 1956–1981: Lessons and Recommendations (Washington: Overseas Development Council, 1982).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Harrod, Roy F., Are these Hardships Necessary? (London: Rupert Hart-Davis, 1947).

  • Harrod, Roy F., The Life of John Maynard Keynes (Harmondsworth, England: Penguin, 1972).

  • Healey, Denis, The Time of My Life (London: Michael Joseph, 1989).

  • Helleiner, Gerald K., “An Unofficial View,” in Policies for African Development: From the 1980s to the 1990s, ed. by I.G. Patel (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1992).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Higgott, Richard A., Andrew F. Cooper, and Jenelle Bonnor, “Asia-Pacific Economic Cooperation: An Evolving Case-Study in Leadership and Co-operation Building,” International Journal, Vol. 19 (Autumn 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Higonnet, René P., “Eurobanks, Eurodollars and International Debt,” in Eurodollars and International Banking, ed. by Paolo Savona and George Sutija (New York: St. Martin’s Press, 1985).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Hilgerdt, Folke, Industrialization and Foreign Trade (Geneva: League of Nations, 1945).

  • Hirsch, Fred, The Pound Sterling: A Polemic (London: Victor Gollancz, 1965).

  • Hirschman, Albert O., National Power and the Structure of Foreign Trade (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1945).

  • Hoffmeyer, Erik, Dollar Shortage and the Structure of U.S. Foreign Trade (Copenhagen: Ejnar Munksgaard, 1958).

  • Hoffmeyer, Erik, The International Monetary System: An Essay in Interpretation (Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1992).

  • Hogan, Michael J., The Marshall Plan: America, Britain, and the Reconstruction of Western Europe, 1947–52 (Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press, 1987).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Holtham, Gerald, “German Macroeconomic Policy and the 1978 Bonn Summit,” in Richard N. Cooper and others, Can Nations Agree? Issues in International Economic Cooperation (Washington: Brookings Institution, 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Horne, Alistair, Macmillan, Vol. 2, 1957–1986 (London: Macmillan, 1989).

  • Horsefield, J. Keith, The International Monetary Fund 1945–1965: Twenty Years of International Monetary Cooperation, Vols. 1–3 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1969).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Houthakker, Hendrik S., “The Breakdown of Bretton Woods,” in Economic Advice and Executive Policy: Recommendations from Past Members of the Council of Economic Advisers, ed. by Werner Sichel (New York: Praeger, 1978).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Howard, Anthony, ed., The Crossman Diaries: Selections from the Diaries of a Cabinet Minister 1964–1970 (London: Hamish Hamilton, 1979).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Howell, Kristin, “The Role of the Bank for International Settlements in Central Bank Cooperation,” Journal of European Economic History, Vol. 22, No. 2 (Fall 1993).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Huang, Po-Wen, Jr., The Asian Development Bank: Diplomacy and Development in Asia (New York: Vantage Press, 1975).

  • Ikenberry, G. John, “A World Economy Restored: Expert Consensus and the Anglo-American Postwar Settlement,” International Organization, Vol. 46, No. 1 (Winter 1992).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Economic Policy Association, The United States Balance of Payments: From Crisis to Controversy (Washington: International Economic Policy Association, 1972).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Finance Corporation, Emerging Stock Markets Factbook, 1993 (Washington: International Finance Corporation, 1993).

  • International Finance Corporation, The Role of the SDR in the International Monetary System, IMF Occasional Paper No. 51 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1987).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Finance Corporation, Common Issues and Interrepublic Relations in the Former U.S.S.R., IMF Economic Review (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1992).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Finance Corporation, Selected Decisions and Selected Documents of the IMF, Nineteenth Issue (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1994).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, Annual Report of the Executive Board for the Financial Year Ended April 30 (Washington: International Monetary Fund), various issues.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, International Financial Statistics and International Financial Statistics Yearbook (Washington: International Monetary Fund), various issues.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, Summary Proceedings of the, … Annual Meeting of the Board of Governors (Washington: International Monetary Fund), various issues.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, World Economic Outlook: A Survey by the Staff of the International Monetary Fund (Washington: International Monetary Fund), various issues.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • International Monetary Fund, World Bank, Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, and European Bank for Reconstruction and Development, A Study of the Soviet Economy, Vols. 1 and 2 (Paris: International Monetary Fund, World Bank, Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, and European Bank for Reconstruction and Development, 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Issing, Otmar, Internationale Währungsordnung (Tübingen: J.C.B. Mohr, 1991).

  • Jacobson, Harold K., and Michel Oksenberg, China’s Participation in the IMF, the World Bank, and GATT: Toward a Global Economic Order (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Jacobsson, Erin E., A Life for Sound Money: Per jacobsson, His Biography (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1979).

  • James, Harold, The Reichsbank and Public Finance in Germany 1924–1933: A Study of the Politics of Economics During the Great Depression (Frankfurt: Fritz Knapp, 1985).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Jánossy, Ferenc, The End of the Economic Miracle: Appearance and Reality in Economic Development, translated by Hedy D. Jellinek (White Plains, New York: International Arts and Sciences Press, 1971; Hungarian original, 1966).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Jaruzelski, Wojciech, Stan Wojenny Dlaczego (Warsaw: Polska Oficyna Wydawnicza BGW, 1992).

  • Jeanneney, Jean-Noël, Leçon d’histoire pour une gauche au pouvoir: La faillite du Cartel 1924–1926 (Paris: Editions Seuil, 1977).

  • Jenkins, Peter, Mrs. Thatcher’s Revolution: The Ending of the Socialist Era (London: Jonathan Cape, 1987).

  • Jenkins, Roy, A Life at the Centre (London: Macmillan, 1991).

  • Johnson, Chalmers, MITI and the Japanese Miracle: The Growth of Industrial Policy 1925–1975 (Stanford, California: Stanford University Press, 1982).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Johnson, H. Clark, “The Gold Deflation, France, and the Coming of the Depression 1919–1932” (Yale University, doctoral dissertation, 1994).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Johnson, Harry G., Economic Policies Toward Developing Countries (Washington: Brookings Institution, 1967).

  • Johnson, Harry G., “The Bretton Woods System, Key Currencies, and the ‘Dollar Crisis’ of 1971,” Three Banks Review, No. 94 (June 1972).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Jones, Joseph M., Tariff Retaliation: Repercussions of the Hawley-Smoot Bill (Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press, 1934).

  • Jones, Randall S., “Japanese Direct Investment in the United States,” Asian Affairs: An American Review, Vol. 18, No. 3 (Fall 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kafka, Alexandre, “The Theoretical Interpretation of Latin American Development,” in Economic Development for Latin America: Proceedings of a Conference Held by the International Economic Association, ed. by Howard S. Ellis (New York: St. Martin’s Press, 1961).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kaiser, David E., Economic Diplomacy and the Origins of the Second World War: Germany, Britain, France, and Eastern Europe 1930–1939 (Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press, 1980).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kamiński, Barłomiej, The Collapse of State Socialism: The Case of Poland (Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press, 1991).

  • Kaplan, Jacob J., and Günther Schleiminger, The European Payments Union: Financial Diplomacy in the 1950s (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Katzenstein, Peter J., Small States in World Markets: Industrial Policy in Europe (Ithaca, New York: Cornell University Press, 1985).

  • Kaufman, Michael, Jamaica Under Manley: Dilemmas of Socialism and Democracy (London: Zed Books, 1985).

  • Kelly, Margaret, Naheed Kirmani, Miranda Xafa, Clemens Boonekamp, and Peter Winglee, Issues and Developments in International Trade Policy, IMF Occasional Paper No. 63 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1988).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kelly, Margaret, and others, Issues and Developments in International Trade Policy, World Economic and Financial Surveys (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1992).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kenen, Peter B., Financing, Adjustment and the International Monetary Fund (Washington: Brookings Institution, 1986).

  • Kenen, Peter B., Managing Exchange Rates (London: Routledge, 1988).

  • Kenen, Peter B., “The Coordination of Macroeconomic Policies,” in International Policy Coordination and Exchange Rate Fluctuations, ed. by William H. Branson, Jacob A. Frenkel, and Morris Goldstein (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kenen, Peter B., “Organizing Debt Relief: The Need for a New Institution,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 4 (Winter 1990).

  • Kenen, Peter B., EMU After Maastricht (Washington: Group of Thirty, 1992).

  • Kenen, Peter B., “Capital Controls, the EMS and EMU,” Economic Journal, Vol. 105 (January 1995).

  • Kennan, George F., Memoirs 1925–1950 (Boston: Little Brown, 1967).

  • Kennedy, Paul, Preparing for the Twenty-First Century (London: HarperCollins, 1993).

  • Keynes, John Maynard, The Economic Consequences of the Peace (New York: Harcourt, Brace and Howe, 1920).

  • Keynes, John Maynard, A Treatise on Money, Vol. 2 (New York: Harcourt, Brace and Co., 1930).

  • Keynes, John Maynard, The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes, Vol. 24, Activities 1944–1946: The Transition to Peace, ed. by Donald Moggridge (London: Macmillan, 1979).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Keynes, John Maynard, The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes, Vol. 25, Activities 1940–1944: Shaping the Post-War World, The Clearing Union, ed. by Donald Moggridge (London: Macmillan, 1980).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Keynes, John Maynard, The Collected Writings of John Maynard Keynes, Vol. 26, Activities 1941–1946: Shaping the Post-War World, Bretton Woods and Reparations, ed. by Donald Moggridge (London: Macmillan, 1980).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Khan, Mohsin S., and Malcom D. Knight, Fund-Supported Adjustment Programs and Economic Growth, IMF Occasional Paper No. 41 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1985).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Killick, Tony, “Kenya, the IMF, and the Unsuccessful Quest for Stabilization,” in IMF Conditionality, ed. by John Williamson (Washington: Institute for International Economics, 1983).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Killick, Tony, ed., The Quest for Economic Stabilization: The IMF and the Third World (New York: St. Martin’s Press, 1984).

  • Kindleberger, Charles P., “International Monetary Stabilization,” in Postwar Economic Problems, ed. by S.E. Harris (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1943).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kindleberger, Charles P., The Dollar Shortage (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press, 1950).

  • Kindleberger, Charles P., “The Price of Gold and the N-l Problem,” in Kindleberger, International Money: A Collection of Essays (London: Allen & Unwin, 1981).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kindleberger, Charles P., The World in Depression 1929–1939 (London: Allen Lane, 1973; Berkeley: University of California Press, 1986).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kindleberger, Charles P., A Financial History of Western Europe (New York: Oxford University Press, 1993).

  • Kissinger, Henry, “International Economics and World Order” (September 24, 1984) in Observations: Selected Speeches and Essays 1982–1984 (Boston: Little Brown, 1985).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Klaus, Václav, “Price Liberalization and Currency Convertibility: Twenty Days After,” in Currency Convertibility in Eastern Europe, ed. by John Williamson (Washington: Institute for International Economics, 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Koo, Anthony Y.C., Selected Essays of Gottfried Haberler (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press, 1985).

  • Kopper, Hilmar, “The Battle Plans of Hilmar Kopper,” Euromoney, January 1994.

  • Kraft, Joseph, The Mexican Rescue (New York: Group of Thirty, 1984).

  • Krueger, Anne O., Liberalization Attempts and Consequences (New York: Ballinger for National Bureau of Economic Research, 1978).

  • Krueger, Anne O., Political Economy of Policy Reform in Developing Countries (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press, 1993).

  • Krueger, Anne O., and Ilter Turan, “The Politics and Economics of Turkish Policy Reforms in the 1980s,” in Political and Economic Interactions in Economic Policy Reform: Evidence from Eight Countries, ed. by Robert H. Bates and Anne O. Krueger (Oxford: Basil Blackwell, 1993).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kunz, Diane B., The Economic Diplomacy of the Suez Crisis (Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 1991).

  • Kunz, Diane B., “Cold War Dollar Diplomacy: The Other Side of Containment,” in The Diplomacy of the Crucial Decade: American Foreign Relations During the 1960s, ed. by Diane B. Kunz (New York: Columbia University Press, 1994).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Kuznets, Simon, “Two Centuries of Economic Growth: Reflections on U.S. Experience,” American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, Vol. 67 (February 1977).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lacouture, Jean, De Gaulle: The Ruler 1945–1970 (New York: Norton, 1992).

  • Lal, Deepak, The Poverty of “Development Economics (London: Institute for Economic Affairs, 1983).

  • Lary, Hal B., and others, The United States in the World Economy: The International Transactions of the United States During the Interwar Period (Washington: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1943).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lawson, Nigel, The View from No. 11: Memoirs of a Tory Radical (London: Bantam, 1992).

  • Leith, J. Clark, and Michael F. Lofchie, “The Political Economy of Structural Adjustment in Ghana,” in Political and Economic Interactions in Economic Policy Reform: Evidence from Eight Countries, ed. by Robert H. Bates and Anne O. Krueger (Oxford: Basil Blackwell, 1993).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Letwin, Oliver, Privatising the World: A Study of International Privatisation in Theory and Practice (London: Cassel, 1988).

  • Lever, Harold, and Christopher Huhne, Debt and Danger: The World Financial Crisis (Harmondsworth, England: Penguin, 1985).

  • Levi, Darrell E., Michael Manley: The Making of a Leader (London: Andre Deutsch, 1989).

  • Lewis, W. Arthur, Economic Survey 1919–1939 (London: Allen & Unwin, 1949; reprint 1953).

  • Lewis, W. Arthur, Growth and Fluctuations 1870–1913 (London: Allen & Unwin, 1978).

  • The Limits to Growth: A Report for the Club of Rome’s Project on the Predicament of Mankind (New York: Universe Books, 1972).

  • Lincoln, Edward J., Japan: Facing Economic Maturity (Washington: Brookings Institution, 1988).

  • Lipschitz, Leslie, and Donogh McDonald, eds., German Unification: Economic Issues, IMF Occasional Paper No. 75 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lissakers, Karin, Banks, Borrowers, and the Establishment: A Revisionist Account of the International Debt Crisis (New York: Basic Books, 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Little, Jane Sneddon, “Comment,” in Eurodollars and International Banking, ed. by Paolo Savona and George Sutija (New York: St. Martin’s Press, 1985).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lomax, David F., The Developing Country Debt Crisis (New York: St. Martin’s Press, 1986).

  • Low, Patrick, Trading Free: The GATT and U.S. Trade Policy (New York: Twentieth Century Fund, 1993).

  • Ludlow, Peter, The Making of the European Monetary System: A Case Study of the Politics of the European Community (London: Butterworth Scientific, 1982).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Lustig, Nora, Mexico, The Remaking of an Economy (Washington: Brookings Institution, 1992).

  • MacDonald, Oliver, ed., The Polish August: Documents from the Beginnings of the Polish Workers’ Rebellion, Gdansk, August 1980 (San Francisco: Ztangi Press, 1981).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Machlup, Fritz, Plans for Reform of the International Monetary System, Special Papers on International Economics, No. 3 (Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press, revised, 1964).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Machlup, Fritz, “The Magicians and Their Rabbits,” Morgan Guaranty Survey, Morgan Guaranty Trust Company, May 1971.

  • Maddison, Angus, Phases of Capitalist Development (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1982).

  • Madrid, Raul L., Overexposed: U.S. Banks Confront the Third World Debt Crisis (Washington: Investor Responsibility Research Center, 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Marglin, Stephen A., and Juliet B. Schor, eds., The Golden Age of Capitalism: Reinterpreting the Postwar Experience (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Marris, Stephen, Deficits and the Dollar: The World Economy at Risk (Washington: Institute for International Economics, 1985; rev. ed., 1987).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Marsh, David, The Bundesbank: The Bank that Rules Europe (London: Heinemann, 1992).

  • Martin, Matthew, The Crumbling Façade of African Debt Negotiations: No Winners (London: Macmillan, 1991).

  • Mason, Edward S., and Robert E. Asher, The World Bank Since Bretton Woods (Washington: Brookings Institution, 1973).

  • McKinnon, Ronald I., Money and Capital in Economic Development (Washington: Brookings Institution, 1973).

  • McKinnon, Ronald I., An International Standard for Monetary Stabilization (Washington: Institute for International Economics, 1984).

  • McKinnon, Ronald I., “Taxation, Money and Credit in a Liberalizing Socialist Economy,” in The Emergence of Market Economies in Eastern Europe, ed. by Christopher Clague and Gordon C. Rasser (Cambridge, Massachusetts: Basil Blackwell, 1992).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • McKinnon, Ronald I., “The Rules of the Game: International Money in Historical Perspective,” Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 31 (March 1993).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Meier, Gerald M., Problems of a World Monetary Order (New York: Oxford University Press, 1982).

  • Melitz, Jacques, “Monetary Discipline and Cooperation in the European Monetary System: A Synthesis,” in The European Monetary System, ed. by Francesco Giavazzi, Stefano Micossi, and Marcus Miller (Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press, 1988).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Meltzer, Allan H., “A Way to Defuse the World Debt Bomb,” Fortune, November 28, 1983.

  • Mihaljek, Dubravko, “Intergovernmental Fiscal Relations in Yugoslavia 1972–90,” in Transition to Market: Studies in Fiscal Reform, ed. by Vito Tanzi (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1993).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mikesell, Raymond F., “Appraising IMF Conditionality: Too Loose, Too Tight, or Just Right,” in IMF Conditionality, ed. by John Williamson (Washington: Institute for International Economics, 1983).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mikesell, Raymond F., The Bretton Woods Debates: A Memoir, Essays in International Finance No. 192 (Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press, 1994).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Milward, Alan S., “The Reichsmark Bloc and the International Economy,” in Der “Führerstaat”: Mythos und Realität: Studien zur Struktur und Politik des Dritten Reiches, ed. by Gerhard Hirschfeld and Lothar Kettenacker (Stuttgart: Klett-Cotta, 1981).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Milward, Alan S., The Reconstruction of Western Europe 1945–51 (London: Methuen, 1984; Berkeley: University of California Press, 1984).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Milward, Alan S., (with George Brennan and Federico Romero,) The European Rescue of the Nation-State (London: Routledge, 1992).

  • Mistry, Percy S., “Africa’s Adjustment and the External Debt Problem,” in Policies for African Development: From the 1980s to the 1990s, ed. by I.G. Patel (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1992).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Moggridge, Donald, Maynard Keynes: An Economist’s Biography (London: Routledge, 1992).

  • Morgan, Austen, Harold Wilson (London: Pluto Press, 1992).

  • Morgenthau, Henry III, Mostly Morgenthaus: A Family History (New York: Ticknor & Fields, 1991).

  • Morgenthau, Henry, Jr., “Address by the Honorable Henry Morgenthau, Jr. at the Inaugural Plenary Session July 1, 1944,” in United Nations Monetary and Financial Conference, Bretton Woods, New Hampshire, July I to July 22, 1944: Final Act and Related Documents (Washington: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1944).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mozhin, Alexei V., “Russia’s Negotiations with the IMF,” in Changing the Economic System in Russia, ed. by Anders Åslund and Richard Layard (London: Pinter Publishers, 1993).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mulford, David C, “The View of the Reagan Administration: Toward Stronger World Growth,” in Latin America’s Debt Crisis: Adjusting to the Past or Planning for the Future? ed. by Robert A. Pastor (Boulder, Colorado: Lynne Rienner, 1987).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mundell, Robert A., “A Theory of Optimum Currency Areas,” American Economic Review, Vol. 51 (September 1961).

  • Mundell, Bretron A., “The Appropriate Use of Monetary and Fiscal Policy for Internal and External Stability,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 9 (March 1962).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Mussa, Michael, “Nominal Exchange Rate Regimes and the Behavior of Real Exchange Rates: Evidence and Implications,” Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, Vol. 25 (1986).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Nafziger, E. Wayne, The Debt Crisis in Africa (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1993).

  • Narasimham, M., Bretton Woods—Forty Years On (Bombay: Forum of Free Enterprise, 1984).

  • Narasimham, M., World Economic Environment and Prospects for India (New Delhi: Sterling Publishers, 1988).

  • Nau, Henry R., The Myth of America s Decline: Leading the World Economy into the 1990s (New York: Oxford University Press, 1990).

  • Ncube, P.D., M. Sakala, and M. Ndulo, “The International Monetary Fund and the Zambian Economy: A Case,” in The IMF and the World Bank in Africa: Conditionality, Impact and Alternatives, ed. by Kjell J. Havnevik (Uppsala: Scandinavian Institute of African Studies, 1987).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Neal, Larry, “The Economics and Finance of Bilateral Clearing Agreements: Germany 1934–8,” Economic History Review, Vol. 32 (August 1979).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Neal, Larry, The Rise of Financial Capitalism: International Capital Markets in the Age of Reason (Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press, 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Nelson, Joan M., “Poverty, Equity, and the Politics of Adjustment,” in The Politics of Economic Adjustment: International Constraints, Distributive Conflicts, and the State, ed. by Stephan Haggard and Robert R. Kaufman (Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press, 1992).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Nicolson, Harold, Diplomacy (London: Thornton Butterworth, 1939).

  • Nixon, Richard, R. N.: The Memoirs of Richard Nixon (New York: Grosset & Dunlap, 1978).

  • Nölling, Wilhelm, Unser Geld: Der Kampf um die Stabilität der Währungen in Europa (Berlin: Ullstein, 1993).

  • North-South, a Programme for Survival: Report of the Independent Commission on International Development Issues (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press, 1980).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Norton, Joseph Jude, “Capital Adequacy Standards: A Legitimate Regulatory Concern for Prudential Supervision of Banking Activities?” Ohio State Law Journal, Vol. 49 (1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Nurkse, Ragnar, International Currency Experience: Lessons from the Inter-War Period (Geneva: League of Nations, 1944).

  • Nyerere, Julius, “An Address,” Development and Change, Vol. 17, 1986.

  • Nyirabu, CM., “A View from Africa: 2,” in Africa and the International Monetary Fund, ed. by Gerald K. Helleiner (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1986).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Obstfeld, Maurice, “International Capital Mobility in the 1990s,” in Understanding Interdependence: The Macroeconomics of the Open Economy, ed. by Peter B. Kenen (Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press, 1995).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Odell, John S., U.S. International Monetary Policy: Markets, Power, and Ideas as Sources of Change (Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press, 1982).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ohkawa, Kazushi, “Japan’s Development: A Model for Less-Developed Countries?” Asian Development Review, Vol. 1, No. 2 (1983).

  • Okun, Arthur M., The Political Economy of Prosperity (Washington: Brookings Institution, 1970).

  • Oliver, Robert W., Early Plans for a World Bank, Princeton Studies in International Finance No. 29 (Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press, 1971).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Olson, Mancur, The Logic of Collective Action (Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press, 1965).

  • Olson, Mancur, The Rise and Decline of Nations: Economic Growth, Stagflation, and Social Rigidities (New Haven, Connecticut: Yale University Press, 1982).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Onimode, Bade, “IMF and World Bank Programmes in Africa,” in Onimode, ed., The IMF, the World Bank and the African Debt, Vol. 1, The Economic Impact (London: Institute for African Alternatives and Zed Books, 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, OECD Economic Outlook, No. 37 (June 1985).

  • Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, Why Economic Policies Change Course: Eleven Case Studies (Paris: Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, 1988).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Organization for European Economic Cooperation, Statistical Bulletin of Foreign Trade, various issues.

  • Ota, Fusae, Hiroya Tanigawa, and Tasuke Otani, “Russia’s Economic Reform and Japan’s Industrial Policy,” Ministry of International Trade and Industry, Working Paper, Tokyo, 1992.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Othman, Haroub, and Ernest Maganya, “Tanzania: The Pitfalls of the Structural Adjustment Programme,” in The IMF, the World Bank and the African Debt, Vol. 1, The Economic Impact, ed. by Bade Onimode (London: Institute for African Alternatives and Zed Books, 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ouattara, Alassane D., “Design, Implementation, and Adequacy of Fund Programs in Africa,” in Africa and the International Monetary Fund, ed. by Gerald K. Helleiner (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1986).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Padoa-Schioppa, Tommaso, “The European Monetary System: A Long-Term View,” in The European Monetary System, ed. by Francesco Giavazzi, Stefano Micossi, and Marcus Miller (Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press, 1988).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Palyi, Melchior, Managed Money at the Crossroads: The European Experience (Notre Dame, Indiana: University of Notre Dame Press, 1958).

  • Palyi, Melchior, The Twilight of Gold 1914–1936: Myths and Realities (Chicago: Henry Regnery, 1972).

  • Papageorgiou, Demetrios, Armeane M. Choksi, and Michael Michaely, Liberalizing Foreign Trade in Developing Countries: The Lessons of Experience (Washington: World Bank, 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Patat, Jean-Pierre, and Michel Lutfalla, Histoire Monétaire de la France au XXe siècle (Paris: Economica, 1986).

  • Patel, I.G., The Link Between the Creation of International Liquidity and the Provision of Development Finance (Geneva: United Nations Conference on Trade and Development, 1967).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Pauls, B. Dianne, “U.S. Exchange Rate Policy: Bretton Woods to Present,” Federal Reserve Bulletin, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Vol. 76, No. 11 (November 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Penrose, Edith, “The Development of Crisis,” in The Oil Crisis, ed. by Raymond Vernon (New York: W.W. Norton, 1976).

  • Pierre-Brossolette, Claude, “Les relations monétaires extérieures de 1958 à 1964,” in De Gaulle en son siècle, Vol. 3, Moderniser la France (Paris: Plon, 1992).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Piganiol, André, Histoire de Rome (Paris: Presses Universitaires de France, 1939; 5th ed., 1962).

  • Plumptre, A.F.W., Three Decades of Decision: Canada and the World Monetary System, 1944–75 (Toronto: McClelland and Stewart, 1977).

  • Pöhl, Karl Otto, “You Can’t Robotize Policymaking,” The International Economy, October/November 1987.

  • Polak, Jacques J., “Monetary Analysis of Income Formation and Payments Problems,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 6 (November 1957).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Polak, Jacques J., The World Bank and the International Monetary Fund: A Changing Relationship (Washington: Brookings Institution, 1994).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Polak, Jacques J., and W.H. White, “The Effect of Income Expansion on the Quantity of Money,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 4 (August 1955).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Polak, Jacques J., and Victor Argy, “Credit Policy and the Balance of Payments,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 18 (March 1971).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Polk, Judd, Sterling: Its Meaning in World Finance (New York: Harper, 1956).

  • Prate, Alain, Les batailles économiques du general de Gaulle (Paris: Plon, 1978).

  • Prebisch, Raúl, “Commercial Policy in Underdeveloped Countries,” American Economic Review: Papers and Proceedings, Vol. 49 (May 1959).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Pressnell, L.S., External Economic Policy Since the War, Vol. 1, The Post-War Financial Settlement (London: H.M. Stationary Office, 1986).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Proceedings and Documents of the United Nations Monetary and Financial Conference, Bretton Woods, New Hampshire, July 1–22, 1944, Vol. 1 (Washington: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1948).

  • The Public Papers and Addresses of Franklin D. Roosevelt, Vol. 2, The Year of Crisis 1933 (New York: Random House, 1938).

  • Putnam, Robert D., and Nicholas Bayne, Hanging Together: The Seven-Power Summits (Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press, 1984).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Putnam, Robert D., and C. Randall Henning, “The Bonn Summit of 1978: A Case Study in Coordination,” in Richard N. Cooper and others, Can Nations Agree? Issues in International Economic Cooperation (Washington: Brookings Institution, 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Rajski, Z., “Produkt krajowy brutto,” in Gospodarka polska w latach 1990–1992, ed. by L. Zienkowski (Warsaw, 1992).

  • Rasminsky, Louis, “Canadian Views,” in Bretton Woods Revisited, ed. by A.L.K. Acheson, J.F. Chant, and M.F.J. Prachowny (Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 1972).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Rees, David, Harry Dexter White: A Study in Paradox (New York: Coward, McCann & Geoghegan, 1973).

  • Regan, Donald T., “The Versailles Summit and the World Economy,” Wall Street Journal, June 15, 1982.

  • Regan, Donald T., For the Record: From Wall Street to Washington (New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, 1988).

  • Report to the Council and Commission of the Realization by Stages of Economic and Monetary Union in the Community (Luxembourg, 1970).

  • Republic of China, Executive Yuan, Directorate-General of Budget, Accounting and Statistics, Statistical Yearbook of the Republic of China, various issues.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Reston, James Jr., The Lone Star: The Life of John Connally (New York: Harper & Row, 1989).

  • Rhomberg, Rudolf R., “Failings of the SDR: Lessons from Three Decades,” in International Financial Policy: Essays in Honor of Jacques J. Polak, ed. by Jacob A. Frenkel and Morris Goldstein (Washington: International Monetary Fund and De Nederlandsche Bank, 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Rieffel, Alexis, The Role of the Paris Club in Managing Debt Problems, Essays in International Finance No. 161 (Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press, 1985).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Rieke, Wolfgang, “The Development of the Deutschemark as a Reserve Currency,” in Reserve Currencies in Transition (New York: Group of Thirty, 1982).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Rojo, Luís Angel, “Panorama Económico,” España Perspectiva, 1969, reprinted in Trece economistas españoles ante la economía española, ed. by Jacinto Ros Hombravella (Barcelona: Oikos-tau, 1975).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Roll, Eric, “Behind Bretton Woods: The Climate Then and Today,” in International Capital Movements, Debt and Monetary System, ed. by Wolfram Engels, Armin Gutowski, and Henry C. Wallich (Mainz: v. Hase & Koehler, 1984).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Rooth, Ivar, Riksbankschef 1929–1948: En autobiografi, Intalad för och utskriven av Gösta Rooth (Oslo: private printing, Gosta Rooth, 1988).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Rostow, W.W., The Stages of Economic Growth: A Non-Communist Manifesto (Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press, 1971; original edition, 1960).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Rueff, Jaques, Combats pour l’ordre financier: Mémoires et documents pour servir à l’Histoire du dernier demi-siècie (Paris: Plon, 1972).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Sachs, Jeffrey D., “The Current Account and Macroeconomic Adjustment in the 1970s,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Brookings Institution, 1981(1).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Sachs, Jeffrey D., “Efficient Debt Reduction,” in Dealing with the Debt Crisis, ed. by Ishrat Husain and Ishac Diwan (Washington: World Bank, 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Sachs, Jeffrey D., “Introduction” in Sachs, ed., Developing Country Debt and the World Economy (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Sachs, Jeffrey D., “My Plan for Poland,” The International Economy, December 1989/January 1990.

  • Sachs, Jeffrey D., Poland’s Jump to the Market Economy (Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press, 1993).

  • Sachs, Jeffrey D., and Charles Wyplosz, “The Economic Consequences of President Mitterrand,” Economic Policy, Vol. 2 (April 1986).

  • Salant, Walter S., and others, The United States Balance of Payments in 1968 (Washington: Brookings Institution, 1963).

  • Sandbrook, Richard, The Politics of Africa’s Economic Recovery (Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press, 1993).

  • Sayers, R.S., The Bank of England 1891–1944, Vol. 1 (Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press, 1976).

  • Schadler, Susan, Franek Rozwadowski, Siddharth Tiwari, and David O. Robinson, Economic Adjustment in Low-Income Countries: Experience Under the Enhanced Structural Adjustment Facility, IMF Occasional Paper No. 106 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1993).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Schatz, Sayre P., “Pirate Capitalism and the Inert Economy of Nigeria,” Journal of Modern African Studies, Vol. 22, No. 1 (1984).

  • Schlesinger, Arthur M., Jr., A Thousand Days: John F. Kennedy in the White House (New York: Fawcett Premier, 1965).

  • Schmidt, Helmut, Menschen und Mächte (Berlin: Siedler Verlag, 1987).

  • Schroder, Gerhard, and others, “Vorlage für das Politbüro des Zentralkommittee der SED,” reproduced in “‘Schock mit Schlimmen Folgen,’” Der Spiegel, 46/44, 1992.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Schröder, Klaus, “Die Verschuldung Polens im Westen,” in Krise in Polen, ed. by Hermann Volle and Wolfgang Wagner (Bonn: Verlag für Internationale Politik, 1982).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Schubert, Aurel, The Credit-Anstalt Crisis of 1931 (Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press, 1991).

  • Sengupta, Arjun, “Allocation of SDRs Linked to Reserve Needs,” Finance & Development, Vol. 23 (September 1986).

  • Servan-Schreiber, J.-J., The American Challenge, translated by Ronald Steel (New York: Atheneum, 1968; French version: Le défi américain, 1967).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Shinohara, Miyohei, “Trends and Dynamics of East and Southeast Asian Economies,” Asian Development Review, Vol. 3, No. 1 (1985).

  • Shulian, Zhou, Wu Jinglian, and Wang Haibo, Lirun fanchou he shehui-zhuyi de jiye guanli (The Profit Category and Socialist Business Management), Beijing, 1979 (translated in Chinese Economic Studies, Vol. 14, No. 2–3 (Winter-Spring 1980–81).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Shultz, George, Turmoil and Triumph: My Years as Secretary of State (New York: Scribner’s, 1993).

  • Silva Herzog, Jesús, “The Costs for Latin America’s Development,” in Latin America’s Debt Crisis: Adjusting to the Past or Planning for the Future? ed. by Robert A. Pastor (Boulder, Colorado: Lynne Rienner, 1987).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Simonsen, Mario Henrique, “The Developing-Country Debt Problem,” in International Debt and the Developing Countries, ed. by Gordon W. Smith and John T. Cuddington (Washington: World Bank, 1985).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Singer, Hans W., “Economic Progress in Under-Developed Countries,” Social Research, Vol. 16 (March 1949).

  • Sivard, Ruth Léger, World Military and Social Expenditures 1987–88 (Washington: World Priorities Inc., 1987).

  • Skidelsky, Robert, John Maynard Keynes: The Economist as Saviour (London: Macmillan, 1992).

  • Slay, Ben, The Polish Economy: Crisis, Reform, and Transformation (Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press, 1994).

  • Solomon, Robert, The International Monetary System, 1945–1976: An Insider’s View (New York: Harper & Row, 1977).

  • Solomon, Robert, “International Monetary Reform: The Future Is Not What It Used To Be!” in The Future of the International Monetary System: Change, Coordination or Instability, ed. by Omar F. Hamouda, Robin Rowley, and Bernard M. Wolf (Armonk, New York: M.E. Sharpe, 1989).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Spaventa, Luigi, “Two Letters of Intent: External Crises and Stabilization Policy, Italy 1973–77,” in IMF Conditionality, ed. by John Williamson (Washington: Institute for International Economics, 1983).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Spero, Joan Edelman, The Failure of the Franklin National Bank: Challenge to the International Banking System (New York: Columbia University Press, 1980).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Stallings, Barbara, “International Influence on Economic Policy: Debt, Stabilization, and Structural Reform,” in The Politics of Economic Adjustment, ed. by Stephan Haggard and Robert R. Kaufman (Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press, 1992).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Stanislaw, Joseph, and Daniel Yergin, “Oil: Reopening the Door,” Foreign Affairs, Vol. 72, No. 4 (September/October 1993).

  • Stockman, David A., The Triumph of Politics: How the Revolution Failed (New York: Harper & Row, 1986).

  • Story, Jonathan, “The Launching of the EMS: An Analysis of Change in Foreign Economic Policy,” Political Studies, Vol. 36 (1988).

  • Strange, Susan, Sterling and British Policy: A Political Study of an International Currency in Decline (London: Oxford University Press, 1971).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Suzuki, Yoshio, Japan’s Economic Performance and International Role (Tokyo: University of Tokyo Press, 1989).

  • Swoboda, Alexander K., The Euro-Dollar Market: An Interpretation, Essays in International Finance No. 64 (Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press, 1968).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Swoboda, Alexander K., Credit Creation in the Euromarket: Alternative Theories and Implications for Control (New York: Group of Thirty, 1980).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Sweezy, Paul M., “Peaceful Transition from Socialism to Capitalism?” Monthly Review, Vol. 15, No. 11 (March 1964).

  • Szasz, André, Monétaire Diplomatie: Nederlands Internationale Monétaire Politiek (Leiden: H.E. Stenfort Krose, 1988).

  • Szymczak, Philippe, “International Trade and Investment Liberalization: Mexico’s Experience and Prospects,” in Mexico: The Strategy to Achieve Sustained Economic Growth, ed. by Claudio Loser and Eliot Kalter, IMF Occasional Paper No. 99 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1992).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Tadao, Ishikawa, “Asia and Japan,” in Asia and Japan: The Search for Modernization and Identity, ed. by Andrew J.L. Armour (London: Athlone Press, 1985).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Tavlas, George S., On the International Use of Currencies: The Case of the Deutsche Mark, Essays in International Finance No. 181 (Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press, 1991).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Tavlas, George S., and Yuzuru Ozeki, The Internationalization of Currencies: An Appraisal of the Japanese Yen, IMF Occasional Paper No. 90 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1992).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Thatcher, Margaret, The Downing Street Years (London: HarperCollins, 1993).

  • Thurow, Lester, Head to Head: The Coming Economic Battle Among Japan, Europe, and America (New York: William Morrow, 1992).

  • Tignor, Robert, The Struggle for the Private Sector: Egypt, Nigeria, and Kenya in the Age of Decolonization (forthcoming).

  • Tinbergen, Jan, Reshaping the International Order: A Report to the Club of Rome (New York: E.P. Dutton, 1976).

  • Trebilcock, Clive, The Industrialization of the Continental Powers 1780–1914 (London: Methuen, 1981).

  • Triffin, Robert, Europe and the Money Muddle: From Bilateralism to Near-Convertibility 1947–1956 (New Haven, Connecticut: Yale University Press, 1957).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Triffin, Robert, “The Return to Convertibility: 1926–1931 and 1958-? or Convertibility and the Morning After,” Quarterly Review, Banca Nazionale del Lavoro, No. 48 (March 1959).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Triffin, Robert, “Tomorrow’s Convertibility: Aims and Means of International Monetary Policy,” Quarterly Review, Banca Nazionale del Lavoro, No. 49 (June 1959).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Triffin, Robert, Gold and the Dollar Crisis: The Future of Convertibility (New Haven, Connecticut: Yale University Press, 1960).

  • Triffin, Robert, “Summary and Conclusions,” in The European Monetary System: Origins, Operation and Outlook, by Jacques van Ypersele with Jean-Claude Koeune (Luxembourg: Office for Official Publications of the European Communities, 1984).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Triffin, Robert, “The European Monetary System: Tombstone or Cornerstone?” in Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, The International Monetary System: Forty Years After Bretton Woods, Conference Series, No. 28 (Boston: Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, 1984).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Tsantis, Andreas C., and Roy Pepper, Romania: The Industrialization of an Agrarian Economy under Socialist Planning (Washington: World Bank, 1979).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ullastres, Alberto, “Plan de Estabilización: Discurso del Ministro de Comercio a las Cortes,” (July 28, 1959), Información Comercial Española, Boletín Semanal, No. 643, July 30, 1959.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ullman, Richard H., Securing Europe (Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press, 1991).

  • Umemura, Mataji, and Toshiyoki Mizoguchi, eds., Quantitative Studies on Economic History of Japan Empire 1890–1940 (Tokyo: Hitotsubashi University Press, 1981).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Ungerer, Horst, Jouko J. Hauvonen, Augusto Lopez-Claros, and Thomas Mayer, The European Monetary System: Developments and Perspectives, IMF Occasional Paper No. 73 (Washington: International Monetary Fund, 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • United Nations, Yearbook of International Trade Statistics, various issues.

  • United Nations Economic Commission for Latin America, The Economic Development of Latin America and Its Principal Problems (Lake Success, 1950).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • United States, Department of the Treasury, United States Participation in the Multilateral Development Banks in the 1980s (Washington: U.S. Government Printing Office, February 1982).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • U.S. Congress, Senate, Hearings Before the Committee on Foreign Relations, on S.833, A Bill to Amend the Economic Cooperation Act of 1948, February 16, 1949, 81st Cong., 1st Sess. (Washington: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1949).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • U.S. Congress, Joint Economic Committee, Report of the Subcommittee on International Exchange and Payments, Action Now to Strengthen the U.S. Dollar, 92nd Cong., 1st Sess. (Washington: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1971).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • “U.S. Proposals on International Debt Crisis,” Hearing Before the Committee on Banking, Finance and Urban Affairs, House of Representatives, 99th Cong., 1st Sess., October 22, 1985, Serial No. 99–39 (Washington: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1986).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Van der Wee, Herman, Prosperity and Upheaval: The World Economy 1945–1980, translated by Robin Hogg and Max R. Hall (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1986).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Van Dormael, Armand, Bretton Woods: Birth of a Monetary System (New York: Holmes and Meier, 1978).

  • Van Houtven, Leo, “Half a Century After Bretton Woods: The Role of the IMF in the International Monetary System,” in Monetary Stability Through International Cooperation: Essays in Honour of André Szász, ed. by Age Bakker, Henk Boot, Olaf Sleijpen, and Wim Vanthoor (Amsterdam: De Nederlandsche Bank, 1994).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • van Meerhaeghe, M.A.G., International Economic Institutions (London: Longman, 1971).

  • Varela, Manuel, “El Plan de Estabilización como yo lo recuerdo,” Información Comercial Española, Nos. 676–77, December 1989–January 1990.

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Viner, Jacob, “Power Versus Plenty as Objectives of Foreign Policy in the Seventeenth and Eighteenth Centuries,” World Politics, Vol. 1 (October 1948).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Viner, Jacob, International Economics (Glencoe, Illinois: Free Press, 1951).

  • Volcker, Paul A., and Toyoo Gyohten, Changing Fortunes: The World’s Money and the Threat to American Leadership (New York: Times Books, 1992).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Von Laue, Theodore H., Sergei Witte and the Industrialisation of Russia (New York: Columbia University Press, 1963).

  • Wade, Robert, Governing the Market: Economic Theory and the Role of Government in East Asian Industrialization (Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press, 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Wai, U Tun, “The Relation Between Inflation and Economic Development: A Statistical Inductive Study,” Staff Papers, International Monetary Fund, Vol. 7 (October 1959).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Walters, Alan, “Money on a Roller-Coaster,” The Independent, July 14, 1988.

  • Walters, Alan, “The Radcliffe Report—Ten Years After: A Survey of Empirical Evidence,” in Money in Britain 1959–1969, ed. by David R. Croóme and Harry G. Johnson (London: Oxford University Press, 1970).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Walters, Alan, Sterling in Danger: The Economic Consequences of Pegged Exchange Rates (London: Fontana, 1990).

  • Wandel, Eckhard, Hans Schäffer: Steuermann in wirtschaftlichen und politischen Krisen (Stuttgart: Deutsche Verlags-Anstalt, 1974).

  • Waterbury, John, “The Political Context of Public Sector Reform and Privatization in Egypt, India, Mexico, and Turkey” in The Political Economy of Public Sector Reform and Privatization, ed. by Ezra N. Suleiman and John Waterbury (Boulder, Colorado: Westview Press, 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Wheeler, Mortimer, “Roman Contact with India, Pakistan and Afghanistan,” in Aspects of Archaeology in Britain and Beyond, ed. by Francis William Grimes (London: H.W. Edwards, 1951).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Wilcox, Clair, A Charter for World Trade (New York: Macmillan, 1949).

  • Wilkie, James W., ed., Statistical Abstract of Latin America, Vol. 29, Part 1 (Los Angeles: UCLA Latin American Center Publications, University of California, 1992).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Williams, David, “The Evolution of the Sterling System,” in Essays in Money and Banking in Honour of R.S. Sayers, ed. by C.R. Whittlesey and J.S.G. Wilson (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1968).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Williams, John H., Postwar Monetary Plans, and Other Essays (New York: A.A. Knopf, 1947).

  • Williamson, John, The Crawling Peg, Essays in International Finance No. 50 (Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press, 1965).

  • Williamson, John, The Failure of World Monetary Reform 1971–74 (New York: New York University Press, 1977).

  • Williamson, John, “Keynes and the International Economic Order,” in Keynes and the Modern World: Proceedings of the Keynes Centenary Conference, King’s College, Cambridge, ed. by David Worswick and James Trevithick (Cambridge, England: Cambridge University Press, 1983).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Williamson, John, “On Judging the Success of IMF Policy Advice,” in Williamson, ed., IMF Conditionality (Washington: Institute for International Economics, 1983).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Williamson, John, The Exchange Rate System (Washington: Institute for International Economics, 1983; 2nd ed., 1985).

  • Williamson, John, and Marcus H. Miller, Targets and Indicators: A Blueprint for the International Coordination of Economic Policy (Washington: Institute for International Economics, 1987).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Wilson, Harold, The Labour Government 1964–1970: A Personal Record (London: Weidenfeld and Nicolson, 1971).

  • Wonnacott, Paul, The Floating Canadian Dollar: Exchange Flexibility and Monetary Independence (Washington: American Enterprise Institute, 1972).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Woods, Randall Bennett, A Changing of the Guard: Anglo-American Relations, 1941–1946 (Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 1990).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • World Bank, The International Bank for Reconstruction and Development, 1946–1953 (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Press, 1954).

  • World Bank, Accelerated Development in Sub-Saharan Africa: An Agenda for Action (Washington: World Bank, 1982).

  • World Bank, Country Economics Department, Adjustment Lending: An Evaluation of Ten Years of Experience (Washington: World Bank, 1988).

  • World Bank, Sub-Saharan Africa: From Crisis to Sustainable Growth: A Long-Term Perspective Study (Washington: World Bank, 1989).

  • World Bank, The East Asian Miracle: Economic Growth and Public Policy (New York: Oxford University Press, 1993).

  • World Bank, Trends in Developing Economies: Extracts, Vol. 1, Eastern Europe and Central Asia (Washington: World Bank, 1993).

  • World Bank, Adjustment in Africa: Reform, Results, and the Road Ahead (New York: Oxford University Press, 1994).

  • World Bank, World Debt Tables, various issues.

  • World Bank, World Development Report (New York: Oxford University Press), various issues.

  • Woytinsky, W.S., and E.S. Woytinsky, World Commerce and Governments: Trends and Outlook (New York: Twentieth Century Fund, 1955).

  • Yamazawa, Ippei, Koji Taniguchi, and Akira Hirata, “Trade and Industrial Adjustment in Pacific Asian Countries,” The Developing Economies, Vol. 21 (1983).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Yasuba, Yasukichi, “Imported Inflation and the Upward Revaluation of the Yen,” in Breadth and Depth in Economics: Fritz Machlup—The Man and His Ideas, ed. by Jacob S. Dreyer (Lexington, Massachusetts: Lexington Books, 1978).

    • Search Google Scholar
    • Export Citation
  • Yergin, Daniel, The Prize: The Epic Quest for Oil, Money, and Power (New York: Simon & Schuster, 1991).