Appendix I Developing Countries Covered in This Study
Afghanistan
Algeria
Argentina
Bahrain
Bangladesh
Barbados
Benin
Bolivia
Botswana
Brazil
Burma
Burundi
Cameroon
Central African Republic
Chad
Chile
Colombia
Comoros
Congo, People’s Republic of the
Costa Rica
Cyprus
Dominican Republic
Ecuador
Egypt
El Salvador
Ethiopia
Fiji
Gabon
Gambia, The
Ghana
Greece
Guatemala
Guinea
Guyana
Haiti
Honduras
India
Indonesia
Iran
Iraq
Israel
Ivory Coast
Jamaica
Jordan
Kenya
Korea
Lebanon
Lesotho
Liberia
Madagascar
Malawi
Malaysia
Mali
Malta
Mauritania
Mauritius
Mexico
Morocco
Nepal
Nicaragua
Niger
Nigeria
Oman
Pakistan
Panama
Papua New Guinea
Paraguay
Peru
Philippines
Portugal
Rwanda
Senegal
Sierra Leone
Singapore
Somalia
Sri Lanka
Sudan
Swaziland
Syrian Arab Republic
Tanzania
Thailand
Togo
Trinidad and Tobago
Tunisia
Turkey
Uganda
Upper Volta
Uruguay
Venezuela
Yemen Arab Republic
Yemen, People’s Dem. Rep. of
Yugoslavia
Zaïre
Zambia
Appendix II Inflation and Debt Service
Inflation erodes the real value of debt, except debt that is indexed. This decline can be thought of as an inflation-induced transfer, accruing to either the creditor or the debtor. The general mechanism for this transfer is the nominal interest rate. To focus on this mechanism, this discussion abstracts from changes in relative prices, the terms of trade, or the real exchange rate and is confined to a situation of identical expected and actual inflation rates. Thus, the redistribution of wealth and income that occurs with unanticipated inflation is not a factor in the following analysis, although it could easily be incorporated without materially influencing the conclusions. Only floating interest rate loans are considered, since under these loans changes in inflation that may occur prior to the maturity of a loan can be accommodated.
The standard presentation of the link between a nominal interest rate and anticipated inflation may be formally presented as i = r +
The fact that the discounted stream of repayments is unaltered does not imply that the time path of payments on the loan (i.e., the debt service burden) at a given point is unchanged. Inflation erodes the real value of the consol and thus transforms the consol into something akin to a bond that is amortized in real terms. Moreover, the inflation adjustment of the interest rate maintains the real value of the interest payments, while also transferring to the creditor, in the form of interest, the equivalent to the inflation-induced decline in the value of the outstanding loan. This decline of the outstanding loan in any period (
The equivalence of the inflation-induced transfer payments, which offset the declining real value of the loan, and amortization payments is demonstrated in Table 19. A bond with face value L0 is assumed to mature at time T with amortization payments (A) distributed evenly and discretely during this period, while the real interest rate and real growth of GDP are assumed to be zero; however, this does not change the qualitative results. In the absence of inflation, interest payments are zero and the sum of debt service payments is equal to the value of the initial loan. In the inflation case (assumed to be 10 per cent), the interest rate is 10 per cent and “interest” payments are equivalent to the inflation-induced decline in the outstanding real loan. The sum of debt service payments is equal to the real value of the initial loan, as in the no-inflation case (compare the sum of DS/GDP in both examples, which implies that the total real burden, or cost, of the loan is unchanged by inflation).27 In each case, debt service payments merely return to the creditor the real principal lent, even though in the inflationary environment “interest” payments represent a greater share of debt service.28 In inflationary circumstances, a portion of the real amortization of a loan is transferred to what is classified as “interest” payments.29
Effect of Inflation on Real Value of a Loan 1
The loan is assumed to be equal to 1,000. Maturity is in five periods with equal amortization payments. The real interest rate and real GDP growth are assumed to be zero, and the nominal interest rate equals the constant inflation rate.
Or indexed bond case.
A five-year loan may be considered as five separate loans for different periods; hence, the average period is the sum of these loans weighted by the period during which each is outstanding, that is, (.2)(1) + (.2)(2) + (.2)(3) + (.2)(4) + (.2)(5) = 3.
The method in footnote 3 applied to this case would yield (.2727)(1) + (.2314)(2) + (.1954)(3) + (.1639)(4) + (.1366) (5) = 2.66.
Effect of Inflation on Real Value of a Loan 1
Time Periods | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
1 | 2 | 3 | 4 | 5 | ||
No inflation 2 | ||||||
Loan outstanding at beginning of period | 1,000 | 800 | 600 | 400 | 200 | |
Amortization schedule | 200 | 200 | 200 | 200 | 200 | |
Interest payments (I) | — | — | — | — | — | |
Debt service (DS) | 200 | 200 | 200 | 200 | 200 | |
Real GDP | 1,000 | 1,000 | 1,000 | 1,000 | 1,000 | |
I/GDP (in per cent) | — | — | — | — | — | |
DS/GDP (in per cent) | 20.0 | 20.0 | 20.0 | 20.0 | 20.0 | |
Average period real loan is outstanding—3 periods 3 | ||||||
Inflation (10 per cent) | ||||||
Loan outstanding at beginning of period | 1,000 | 800 | 600 | 400 | 200 | |
Amortization schedule | 200 | 200 | 200 | 200 | 200 | |
“Interest” payments due to erosion of outstanding principal ( |
100 | 80 | 60 | 40 | 20 | |
Debt service (DS) | 300 | 280 | 260 | 240 | 220 | |
Nominal GDP | 1,100 | 1,210 | 1,331 | 1,464 | 1,611 | |
I/GDP (in per cent) | 9.09 | 6.61 | 4.51 | 2.73 | 1.24 | |
DS/GDP (in per cent) | 27.27 | 23.14 | 19.54 | 16.39 | 13.66 | |
Average period real loan is outstanding—2.66 periods 4 |
The loan is assumed to be equal to 1,000. Maturity is in five periods with equal amortization payments. The real interest rate and real GDP growth are assumed to be zero, and the nominal interest rate equals the constant inflation rate.
Or indexed bond case.
A five-year loan may be considered as five separate loans for different periods; hence, the average period is the sum of these loans weighted by the period during which each is outstanding, that is, (.2)(1) + (.2)(2) + (.2)(3) + (.2)(4) + (.2)(5) = 3.
The method in footnote 3 applied to this case would yield (.2727)(1) + (.2314)(2) + (.1954)(3) + (.1639)(4) + (.1366) (5) = 2.66.
Effect of Inflation on Real Value of a Loan 1
Time Periods | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
1 | 2 | 3 | 4 | 5 | ||
No inflation 2 | ||||||
Loan outstanding at beginning of period | 1,000 | 800 | 600 | 400 | 200 | |
Amortization schedule | 200 | 200 | 200 | 200 | 200 | |
Interest payments (I) | — | — | — | — | — | |
Debt service (DS) | 200 | 200 | 200 | 200 | 200 | |
Real GDP | 1,000 | 1,000 | 1,000 | 1,000 | 1,000 | |
I/GDP (in per cent) | — | — | — | — | — | |
DS/GDP (in per cent) | 20.0 | 20.0 | 20.0 | 20.0 | 20.0 | |
Average period real loan is outstanding—3 periods 3 | ||||||
Inflation (10 per cent) | ||||||
Loan outstanding at beginning of period | 1,000 | 800 | 600 | 400 | 200 | |
Amortization schedule | 200 | 200 | 200 | 200 | 200 | |
“Interest” payments due to erosion of outstanding principal ( |
100 | 80 | 60 | 40 | 20 | |
Debt service (DS) | 300 | 280 | 260 | 240 | 220 | |
Nominal GDP | 1,100 | 1,210 | 1,331 | 1,464 | 1,611 | |
I/GDP (in per cent) | 9.09 | 6.61 | 4.51 | 2.73 | 1.24 | |
DS/GDP (in per cent) | 27.27 | 23.14 | 19.54 | 16.39 | 13.66 | |
Average period real loan is outstanding—2.66 periods 4 |
The loan is assumed to be equal to 1,000. Maturity is in five periods with equal amortization payments. The real interest rate and real GDP growth are assumed to be zero, and the nominal interest rate equals the constant inflation rate.
Or indexed bond case.
A five-year loan may be considered as five separate loans for different periods; hence, the average period is the sum of these loans weighted by the period during which each is outstanding, that is, (.2)(1) + (.2)(2) + (.2)(3) + (.2)(4) + (.2)(5) = 3.
The method in footnote 3 applied to this case would yield (.2727)(1) + (.2314)(2) + (.1954)(3) + (.1639)(4) + (.1366) (5) = 2.66.
A higher nominal interest rate assures that the real value of the loan is repaid when inflation is present but, nevertheless, inflation is not neutral in its impact upon the terms of the loan. Inflation causes the real value of the loan to be amortized at a faster rate. This is shown by the higher debt service to GDP ratio for the early periods of the loan. Correspondingly, the average period that the real loan is outstanding is shortened from 3 periods with no inflation to 2.66 periods with inflation. Inflation thus induces a more rapid amortization of the real value of the loan or reduces the average time that the real loan is outstanding. The extent to which the average maturity is diminished varies directly with the inflation rate and the calendar maturity of the loan.
The effect of different inflation rates on real debt service payments of loans with varying maturities is illustrated in Charts 2, 3, and 4. For a given maturity, say 20 years as in Chart 2, higher inflation rates produce progressively greater real debt servicing obligations in the near term, with corresponding reductions in the future. The average period that the real loan is outstanding declines from 10.5 years with no inflation to 7.5 years with 5 per cent inflation and is shortened to 4.6 years if the inflation rate is 15 per cent. This more rapid effective amortization of the real loan accounts for the increase in the debt service in the short run, which for a 20-year bond jumps initially to 23 per cent from 10 per cent as inflation moves from zero to 15 per cent. The higher the inflation rate, the more rapid the amortization of the real loan. The extent to which, for a given inflation rate, repayment of the real loan is brought forward depends on the calendar maturity of the nominal loan, as can be seen by comparing Charts 2, 3, and 4. While a shorter calendar maturity for a loan of equivalent value naturally increases the debt servicing obligation in any period, the additional debt servicing obligations in the near term created by inflation are less with a loan of a shorter maturity, since there are fewer future time periods to reflect the effects of inflation. An increase in inflation from zero to 15 per cent more than doubles the initial debt servicing obligation for a 20-year loan, but there is only about a 42 per cent increase for a 5-year loan.
Two inferences can be drawn from a more rapid amortization of the real value of loans: first, a country would require larger gross borrowing in the near term to maintain the same real net resource transfer (i.e., loan disbursements less debt service payments); second, debt indicators such as the interest payments/GDP ratio or country risk measures such as the current account deficit/GDP ratio are biased upward by inflation. A comparison of the interest payments/GDP ratio across time may reflect only different inflation rates rather than provide information concerning real factors, while similar comparisons across countries may reflect only a different average maturity of outstanding loans. This implies that comparisons of current account deficits, which are the same in all components except interest payments, could differ for the reasons cited above. Thus, in an inflationary world the current account/GDP ratio is distorted by the transferring of some amortization payments from the capital account to the current account via interest payments.
Higher inflation rates do not change any of the basic parameters underlying the debt accumulation process except for the debt service ratio, which will be greater. The difference between the rate of growth of nominal (real) GDP and the nominal (real) interest rate is constant, as is the savings gap; therefore, debt capacity in the long run is unaltered. Thus, the long-run position and associated risks are unchanged, but the short-run position has been affected.30 Certain commonly used measures of a country’s external debt position, such as the current account deficit of the balance of payments/GDP or interest payments/GDP ratios, are biased upward by inflation and thus may result in a misleading inference of a deterioration in the debtor’s economic situation.
Even though the long-run viability of the debt accumulation process and, therefore, the associated long-term risk is unaffected by higher inflation, the near-term prospects are altered. Debt service ratios are higher in the near term after an increase in the inflation, reflecting the faster real amortization of debt. A shorter average maturity for outstanding real debt (i.e., higher effective real amortization payments) increases a debtor’s dependence on rollover financing, raises its vulnerability to disruptions in capital markets or short-run fluctuations in exports, and makes the maintenance of creditor confidence more important.
External debt is composed of fixed interest rates and variable interest rate loans, and actual and anticipated inflation rates are not always equal. The presence of an inflation-recognition lag may result in movement in the nominal interest rate trailing inflation developments. As a consequence, higher inflation is not fully reflected in higher interest rates and, therefore, debt service ratios would not rise by as much as if inflation were fully anticipated and may even fall. Debt service ratios on fixed interest rate loans decline with an increase in inflation. Thus, combining these factors, a possible path for debt service ratios after an increase in inflation is at first a decline followed by an increase.
Appendix III Debt Ratios and Analysis of Debt Situations
General Considerations
Concern over the rise in the external debt of developing countries has focused attention on quantifiable indicators of debt and debt capacity. Such indicators are used as an analytical tool to evaluate external debt situations and by commercial lenders in determining country creditworthiness and assessing country risk. The increase in debt servicing problems in a number of countries in the late 1970s has led regulatory officials to monitor more closely commercial banks’ country lending exposure; for example, in the United States, bank examiners draw the attention of commercial banks to exposure levels that exceed certain guidelines while, in other countries, mandatory capital requirements are related to portfolio risk, with country loans assigned different levels of risk. In these ways, debt indicators have been a factor in the supply of external funds.31
A broad indicator of a country’s dependence on foreign capital inflows is the ratio of the current account deficit of the balance of payments to GNP.32 The recent increase in this ratio for non-oil developing countries as a group suggests that their dependence on foreign capital inflows has increased, thus raising their vulnerability to external financial developments. This ratio by itself is of limited usefulness as a tool for analysis of debt situations because it does not capture the differences in the composition of a country’s capital inflows. The relative importance of direct investment and loan capital in total capital flows has a major influence on external debt indicators as generally defined. Although remittances of profits and dividends on direct investment also absorb foreign exchange resources, these generally do not have a predetermined schedule of payments. For this reason, the indicators discussed in this section focus on those arising from external loan indebtedness and do not touch on issues of direct investment versus foreign borrowing or sustain-ability of the current account deficit of the balance of payments.
Descriptive Function
As a descriptive measure, external debt indicators reflect the evolution of the terms, structure, and scale of past borrowing. These indicators may be used in cross-country and intertemporal analyses to gauge debt capacity and to assess the development of external debt situations.
Intercountry analysis employing the most commonly utilized indicators 33 suffers from some general conceptual difficulties. In the long run, and under certain conditions (discussed below), these indicators should reach a constant level, but this theoretical level may vary from country to country depending on underlying economic conditions, including the initial savings gap, productivity of investment, marginal and average savings rates, and loan terms. Comparisons of countries’ external debt situations based on debt ratios require adjustments for differences in these parameters. As developing countries generally have not reached this long-run position, cross-country comparisons also need to be adjusted for the length of time during which external debt has been accumulating, since debtors at different stages of the process have different ratios. A country that has been borrowing for a longer period would have higher debt ratios, and these higher ratios may signify only that fact.
A further complication is introduced by the effect of past changes in the global inflation rate. Inflation, by itself, will alter the commonly used ratios, and the extent to which they are changed is dependent on the proportion of variable interest rate loans in total outstanding external debt, the average maturity for both fixed and variable interest rate loans, and the average interest rate on fixed interest rate loans.
The use of debt indicators for intertemporal analysis also has certain drawbacks. The indicators generally rise in the initial stages of investment and external debt accumulation, with the rate of increase depending on the underlying economic situation. Under stable conditions, however, debt ratios would reach a maximum, which implies that their rate of increase declines, but the rate of deceleration varies from country to country. The proper use of the indicators thus requires knowledge of the debt accumulation path for a country, including the stage the country has reached along that path.
Changing economic conditions, such as changes in the terms of trade or the inflation rate, will alter the external debt accumulation process, thereby affecting both the level of the debt indicators as well as their future path. For example, a deterioration in the current account of the balance of payments, aside from producing higher long-term levels for certain indicators (e.g., external debt to GDP, debt service to export earnings), would result in a more rapid near-term rise in these indicators. The reason for this is that, in its impact on the debt situation, such a change is equivalent to adding new debt flows to the ongoing debt accumulation process.
The conceptual ambiguities cited make intertemporal and intercountry comparisons, utilizing external debt indicators, difficult to interpret. These uncertainties may be reduced by careful study of the individual economic situations. In an appraisal of a country’s current external debt position based on a wide range of economic data and analysis, debt indicators would have important descriptive meaning. Without this comprehensive review, however, it would be difficult to disentangle the various factors influencing an economy and its debt indicators.
Predictive Function
The theoretical difficulties in defining a high value for an indicator also affects the predictive value of these indicators. Moreover, past values of these indicators, particularly debt service, may not accurately reflect future values for a variety of reasons, such as bunching of maturities or changes in market interest rates. Notwithstanding these limitations, external debt indicators have frequently been used to determine whether a country is approaching a possible debt servicing problem. Often, simple criteria, or rules of thumb, for various debt indicators have been used. In addition, sophisticated statistical techniques employing a wide range of indicators have been utilized to predict the probability of debt servicing problems. Even with the refinement of such techniques, however, countries were often misclassified; countries that did not experience default were classified as having done so, and countries that did renegotiate their external debt were not so classified.34 This points out the need to temper assessments based on indicators with judgments gained from a comprehensive study of the economy; and such an evaluation can most appropriately be made in medium-term projections of the entire balance of payments and likely conditions in foreign capital markets.
Data Considerations
The usefulness of external debt indicators is diminished by certain statistical difficulties, including coverage and definitional problems (these shortcomings are discussed in Section II, above, pages 3–4). Data on debt service payments are subject to the same statistical qualifications as external debt data. In addition, debt service payments, as reported by the World Bank and the OECD, represent actual payments rather than scheduled payments; actual payments may be less than scheduled payments (e.g., because of accumulation of arrears related to debt service). In such cases, the cost to the economy of servicing the debt is measured by the actual debt service payments, but the real magnitude of the external debt problem may be understated; in some cases this has been by as much as one third. An external debt problem can also be overstated if a country makes early voluntary repayment of loans. An improved balance of payments position and increased access to international capital markets on relatively favorable terms may enable a country to refinance a portion of its outstanding external debt. This may produce a substantial jump in debt service.
Data limitations also affect the usefulness of debt indicators in their predictive function. Even if detailed statistical information on the terms of individual loans were available, estimating future debt ratios is complicated by the need to predict, possibly over several years, the future course of interest rates in international capital markets, exchange rates, export earnings, or GDP, as well as the level, composition, and terms of future borrowing. This is especially true for predicting debt service ratios, because debtors, in an effort to reduce debt service costs, have borrowed in a variety of currencies and at various interest rates,35 which further compounds the problem.
Commonly Used Debt Ratios
The various debt indicators that have been developed are generally scaled by GDP or export earnings from goods and services to take account of the size of an economy and to measure debt burden. Often, it is argued that scaling by export earnings is preferable to scaling by GDP, because export earnings represent foreign exchange resources that can be utilized to service external debt obligations whereas GDP includes sources of income that cannot be thus employed. This view, which is based on a liquidity concept, has greater validity in the short term than in the medium term, but even in the near term it does not take into account the extent to which export earnings are needed to finance current nondebt payments. For example, two countries with the same debt service to export earnings ratio, but with different import payments, would have different external debt positions. This argues for scaling, by some combined measure, of the size of the traded goods sector. However, in the longer run, even this sort of scaling factor may be inappropriate. Since the foreign exchange constraint may also be lessened by growth in the nontraded goods sector. An expansion in nontraded goods production, given relative price flexibility and the absence of widespread impediments to factor mobility, would result in some of the increased supply of nontraded goods being used to satisfy a part of aggregate demand that would otherwise be directed toward the traded goods sector. The supply of exportable goods would rise, while the demand for imports would decline. The magnitude of this shift is dependent on the substitutability of traded and nontraded goods. This shift results in a strengthening of the current account of the balance of payments and frees external resources to service debt. Thus, given the ability of productive factors to adjust to changes in relative prices, including exchange rates, the more appropriate long-run scalor would be GDP while, in the short run, if used in conjunction with other information, export earnings of goods and services captures the liquidity problems associated with external debt.
One major statistical issue associated with the use of GDP as a scaling factor for debt ratios is whether the annual average nominal exchange rate is the appropriate means of converting domestic currency GDP into GDP expressed in the currency (or currencies) of the external debt. An overvalued currency would result in a misleadingly low ratio, while an undervalued currency would produce an overly high ratio. The appropriateness of the nominal exchange rate can be judged only after a review of overall economic developments. This problem is avoided in the case of export earnings data.
Debt Service Ratio
This ratio is defined as debt service payments—interest and principal—divided by GDP or export earnings of goods and services. Private transfers, such as workers’ remittances, should also be included, since these receipts are an important source of foreign exchange in some countries. The ratio to export earnings is more frequently used and, consequently, the discussion focuses on it. The debt service ratio can be interpreted as indicating the proportion of a country’s annual exports of goods and services that would be absorbed by debt service payments and thus is a measure of the debt burden. The indicator also provides a liquidity measure analogous to cash flow indicators for a firm. According to this interpretation, a debtor’s ability to cover debt servicing obligations declines as the ratio increases.
A country rarely must service its external debt obligations wholly from current export earnings; rather, in normal circumstances, when creditor confidence is maintained, a large part of scheduled principal payments is “rolled over” by new gross foreign borrowing. The principal value of this indicator is as an index of short-run rigidity in a country’s balance of payments; the higher the ratio, the greater the external adjustment required to compensate for adverse balance of payments developments. A rule of thumb in use is that a debt service ratio below 10 per cent is acceptable whereas a ratio above 20 per cent is potentially dangerous. Generally, it is cautioned that this ratio must be analyzed in conjunction with other factors, such as growth and composition of exports and imports; otherwise, the results may be misleading. The crucial importance of this caveat is apparent when one notes that many countries have had ratios of between 20 per cent and 70 per cent at various times without encountering serious debt servicing problems, while other countries had ratios well below 20 per cent when they had to renegotiate their external debt.
To make meaningful judgments about a country’s debt position, additional data must be considered: (1) the extent to which a country obtains its export earnings from a few commodities or small number of sources; (2) the historical and prospective trends of export prices and volumes; (3) the variability in export prices and volumes around their trends, which is related to (1); (4) the level of international reserves and secondary reserves in relation to imports; and (5) the degree to which demand management can, in the short run, adjust the balance of payments without unacceptable effects on the domestic economy, which is, inter alia, related to the degree to which nonessential imports can be compressed.
Ratio of Amortization Payments to Disbursements
The ratio of amortization payments to loan disbursements provides a measure of the extent to which a country’s external debt is “rolled over.” 36 Under normal circumstances, the amortization component of debt service payments may be expected to be largely refinanced or rolled over from year to year and thus does not represent an immediate burden on the economy of the debtor country.37 A value of unity for the ratio implies that disbursements are just covering amortization payments and outstanding external debt is not growing. As external debt accumulates, this ratio is less than one and is generally smallest in the initial stages of borrowing. It rises to a constant value, which is less than one, as the long-run ratio of external debt to GDP is reached 38 and, like the debt service ratio, varies from country to country, since the underlying economic parameters differ and also can change for a given debtor over time. As a consequence, comparisons utilizing this measure are difficult. While this ratio is expected to rise over time, sharp increases may indicate either bunching of maturities or a less favorable access to international capital markets.
Ratio of Interest Payments to GDP or Export Earnings
The ratio of annual interest payments to GDP (or export earnings) can be a useful index of the relative magnitude of the burden of external debt. In theory, a high level or rapid increase in this measure would indicate the emergence of excessive consumption and/or problems with the productivity or efficiency of investment. Foreign resources may have been directed to consumption rather than investment, and/or the contribution to expanded GDP and exports of a country’s investment program may be low relative to the cost of foreign financing. However, such a conclusion cannot be drawn without additional information concerning the stage of growth and characteristics of the growth path of a country, since the external debt accumulation process predicts that this ratio will rise. The speed at which it rises and its ultimate level varies from country to country, depending on the proportion of foreign financing of investment, the incremental output/ capital ratio, the cost of foreign financing, and the extent to which the marginal savings rate exceeds the average savings rate in the debtor country. Inflation can compound the difficulties of evaluation, when floating interest rate loans are part of the external debt portfolio, by effectively assimilating some amortization payments in interest payments and distorting the statistical measure of interest payments. The extent to which the data capture this effect is dependent on the inflation rate, the proportion of floating interest rate debt, and the maturity structure. Deflating these payments by nominal GDP or export earnings does not eliminate this distortion.
Ratio of Net Resource Transfer to GDP 39
Net resource transfer, defined as loan disbursements less debt service payments, measures the additional claim on external resources acquired by the debtor country through foreign borrowing. The magnitude of net resource transfer relative to GDP 40 indicates the contribution of net foreign savings to the development process and can be usefully compared with such ratios as domestic savings to GDP and investment to GDP; the latter ratio, when combined with the incremental output to capital ratio, determines capacity growth.
A concept similar to net resource transfer, which also measures the net increase in external resources obtained from foreign borrowing, is net flow. Net flow is defined as loan disbursements less amortization of principal on outstanding debt. Net flow is consistent with national income identities of GNP, national savings, and the current account balance of goods and services, whereas net resource transfer is consistent with GDP, domestic savings, and the current account of goods and nonfactor services. Each of these flow identities can be used to analyze income growth and external debt accumulation but from slightly different perspectives. For GNP to expand, while external debt accumulates, the productivity of investment must be greater than the interest rate charged on foreign loans. If the productivity of investment is less than the interest rate charged on foreign loans, the growth rate of GNP would lag behind the growth rate of GDP.
Definitions based on GDP draw attention to the expansion of the debtor’s economy and the net resource transfer required to maintain its growth rate. However, as pointed out below, for the interest payments/GDP ratio to reach a constant level, the growth rate of GDP (i.e., the productivity of investment) must be greater than the interest rate on the loan.
Both of these conceptual frameworks are consistent and have the same condition for a stable growth of external debt relative to GDP.41 However, the appropriate framework depends on the issue. The impact of inflation on the measurement of amortization and interest payments would affect the use of net flow, whereas this would not occur if net resource transfer were utilized.
Ratio of Outstanding External Debt to GDP or Export Earnings
The preceding ratios were all measures of flows related to the external borrowing (i.e., amortization payments, interest payments, and disbursements) and income flows such as GDP or export earnings. A scaled measure of the stock position is obtained by dividing foreign indebtedness by either GDP or export earnings. This indicator has also been used as part of the measure of foreign presence in an economy, because external debt outstanding represents past reliance on contractual foreign capital inflows. A high ratio indicates that a country has had high inflows in the past but may or may not reflect a dependence on the continuation of such inflows or potential servicing difficulties. Depending on the terms of borrowing, a high external debt ratio may or may not imply a high debt service ratio.
As already outlined, the process of external debt accumulation foresees, in its initial stages, a rise in outstanding external debt relative to GDP (or to export earnings, assuming that they are a constant share of GDP) and that this ratio will reach a constant level.42 This long-run proportion will vary from debtor to debtor based on the terms of external indebtedness, the growth of GDP, and the extent of the recourse to foreign savings. Generally, however, non-oil developing countries have not been involved in the borrowing process long enough, mutatis mutandis, for this long-run relationship to apply. In the shorter term, the external debt to GDP ratio is expected to rise but at a decelerating rate; the pace at which this deceleration occurs also varies from debtor to debtor. Consequently, neither the ultimate ratio nor the rate of change of this ratio by itself is useful in making comparisons among countries.
Ratio of Net External Debt to GDP or Export Earnings
The ratio of net external debt to export earnings or GDP is one useful variant of the outstanding external debt ratio.43 Net external debt is defined as outstanding external debt less international reserves plus a level of international reserves required to meet foreign transactions.44 These working balances are assumed to be equivalent to two months’ imports of goods and services.45 This indicator makes the linkage between external debt management policy and international reserve policy more explicit, since foreign borrowing may also provide an alternative to international reserve losses. In some cases, net international reserves may also serve as indirect collateral for certain foreign loans.
Debt Capacity
One function of external borrowing, commonly utilized by developing countries, is to supplement national savings to reach a desired level of investment and GNP growth. To focus on this major purpose of foreign borrowing, other functions (e.g., maintenance of international reserves) have been omitted, as have other forms of foreign savings—direct investment—which stimulate economic development. As a result of these constraints, the difference between investment and domestic savings—the current account deficit of the balance of payments—is financed by borrowing. Over time, and with GNP growth, larger absolute amounts of foreign savings are required to support development efforts. The ability to service this expanding external debt depends on the growth of GNP and exports of goods and services, which also determines, along with other factors such as the interest rate and changes in the terms of trade, the equilibrium level and sustainable rate of growth of external debt. Eventually, with sufficient GNP growth, the gap between national savings and investment may close, and the level of external debt could decline.
The analytics of debt capacity can be described by utilizing a simple model.46 In this model, all external debt is assumed to finance the gap between investment and domestic savings, with GDP growth progressing at a rate determined by investment and the fixed incremental capital/ output ratio.47 The external debt acquired is a bond with a fixed maturity and interest rate. If inflation exists it is constant and correctly anticipated and, thus, fully incorporated in the nominal interest rate. Relative prices, the terms of trade, and the real exchange rate are assumed fixed, but inflation is permitted. Consequently, the rate of debt accumulation is determined by the savings gap, interest charges on the expanding debt, and GDP growth.
Formally, the model consists of the following equations:
where
I = investment
S = domestic savings
k = fixed incremental capital/output ratio
s = domestic savings/GDP
g = growth rate of real or nominal GDP
D = external debt
i = real or nominal interest rate on debt
The ratio of external debt to GDP will reach an upper limit in the future if the interest rate on external debt is less than the growth rate of output. Mathematically, this condition is
Thus, the external debt/GDP ratio rises to an asymptotic limit, given a constant savings gap relative to GDP and a growth rate of GDP that exceeds the cost of foreign borrowing. The growth of the external debt/GDP ratio decelerates over time (Chart 5). If the external debt/ GDP ratio reaches a long-run constant, then the debt service/GDP ratio will also reach a constant, but lower, level.48 The difference between these two ratios is determined by the terms of the loans. Interest payments are a constant fraction of outstanding debt and, thus, developments in the interest payments/GDP ratio mirror, but at a lower level, those of the outstanding debt/GDP ratio. However, the ratio of amortization payments to GDP follows a more complex path. In the initial stages of debt accumulation, amortization payments are below their long-run value, since external debt grows more rapidly than amortization payments because of the grace period, even if that period is only one year. After the first loan has matured, the unpaid balances of past loans represent a stable structure much like the age structure of a population growing at a constant rate. As a result, in the short run, the amortization payments/outstanding external debt ratio rises while, simultaneously, the outstanding external debt/GDP ratio is increasing and, thus, the amortization payments/GDP ratio must at first rise at a faster rate than the external debt/GDP ratio. After the first loan has matured and a stable structure of outstanding external debt is established, the debt service and external debt ratios will rise at the same rate (see Chart 5). In the long run, the rate of growth of external debt, debt service payments, and GDP will all be equal.49
If this long-run solution were disturbed by a once-for-all deterioration in the terms of trade so that the savings gap was expanded, a new round of external debt accumulation would be launched. However, as long as the rate of GDP growth exceeds the interest rate on external debt, the process is still stable but at a new, higher external debt/GDP ratio. A shortening of the loan maturity would gradually increase the debt service ratio because of the weight of previously made longer-term loans. Only as these longer-term loans mature and are replaced will the debt service ratio begin to approach its new, higher level. A shorter average maturity structure of outstanding loans causes a debtor to seek refinancing sooner but does not change the underlying parameters of the model or, thus, the long-run external debt/GDP ratio. This is not true if the real interest rate increases, since this would reduce the sustainable external debt/GDP ratio. An increase in the nominal interest rate, assuming no change in relative prices, would be matched by a corresponding greater growth rate of nominal GDP, leaving the long-run situation unchanged. Whether the short-run situation is altered depends on whether fixed interest rate or variable interest rate bonds are assumed.50
The above has assumed that the marginal savings rate is equal to the average savings rate, and thus the domestic savings/GDP ratio remained constant even though the economy experienced greater real income. When the marginal savings rate is greater than the average savings rate,51 national savings rise and the current account/GNP ratio declines. With a large enough marginal savings ratio, external debt will decline and the debtor will become a net creditor.
The principal implication of the foregoing is that, to avoid debt difficulties in the longer term, the productivity of borrowed resources must at least equal the interest charges associated with that debt when interest cost excludes the amortization effect discussed in Appendix II, above. Investing the proceeds from foreign borrowing at less than their opportunity cost leads to an erosion of the debtor’s resource base, because relatively more income is absorbed by debt service payments.
The present value of a constant future stream of payments or, alternatively, receipts is equivalent to that stream multiplied by the reciprocal of the interest rate. Since this is a floating interest rate consol, the interest payments on the bond are directly proportional to the interest rate, leaving the present value unchanged as illustrated in the following equation: present
Real GDP is constant, so that, effectively, this is merely deflating by the price index.
If the real interest rate were positive, then aggregate debt service would be larger because of the real interest payments on the real value of the loan.
If financial instruments were indexed to the price level, instead of having the nominal interest rate float, real interest payments and real amortization payments would be unaffected by inflation. “Interest” payments would be substantively less than the “interest” payments of a floating interest rate bond, even though the same real interest rate and the same real value of the loan were involved.
This long-run proposition remains valid only if the inflation was not induced or accompanied by a continuous deterioration in the terms of trade for the borrower. In that case, the savings gap (cum current account deficit) would be larger. The long-run debt capacity thus could be less and the long-run risks of lending greater.
The role of prudential constraints in commercial bank lending was examined in International Monetary Fund, International Capital Markets: Recent Developments and Short-Term Prospects, IMF Occasional Paper, No. 1 (September 1980).
Or the analytically equivalent concept of the ratio of the balance of goods and nonfactor services to GDP.
As a ratio to GNP (or GDP) or to exports of goods and services, these include the following: debt service payments, interest payments, outstanding external debt, and net external debt.
The in-sample errors are generally less when advanced econometric techniques are employed, compared with rule-of-thumb criteria. However, out-of-sample evidence may not be so encouraging.
Variable interest rate loans were a major form of lending in the 1970s, and the share of this lending in currencies other than U.S. dollars has increased. Whether this strategy of borrowing in a variety of currencies in an attempt to lower debt service costs is successful or not is dependent on how closely actual developments in the above-mentioned variables correspond to earlier expectations. A debtor cannot hedge against future developments in foreign exchange or bond markets, because future markets do not exist for the entire loan period and, therefore, the debtor must assume what is known as an open or exposed position.
A high ratio may also indicate the existence of a potential roll-over problem and a heightened susceptibility to changing conditions in international credit markets. This can be thought of as a capital account analog to the debt service ratio.
This, of course, assumes that new disbursements are not tied to imports or that, if they are tied, these imports are readily substitutable for existing imports, thereby freeing foreign exchange resources.
This ratio would be larger than one, when the debtor enters the capital market as a supplier of funds.
A related indicator is the ratio of debt service payments to disbursements, both scaled by GDP.
Net resource transfer can also be scaled by imports to obtain a measure of the expansion in import capacity resulting from an inward net transfer.
It should be noted that, even if the productivity of investment and the interest rate are the same, a country can gain by foreign borrowing as long as domestic resources are employed more productively than they would be otherwise.
The failure to reach this limit implies either that investment productivity was less than associated foreign interest charges or that the dependence on foreign savings has increased.
Another version of this indicator is external debt/international reserves.
The formula is [External Debt—International Reserves + (1/6) Imports of goods and services]/Exports of goods and services or GDP.
Two months’ imports of goods and services is the traditional rule of thumb. However, like all such rules, its appropriateness for a particular country must be tempered by such considerations as the concentration of imports in terms of sources and commodities, the share of tied or project-related imports in total imports, and the extent to which trade is conducted by the private sector employing its own resources.
See Evsey D. Domar, “The Effect of Foreign Investment on the Balance of Payments,” American Economic Review, Vol. 40 (December 1950), pp. 805–26; Dragoslav Avramovic, and others, Economic Growth and External Debt, International Bank for Reconstruction and Development (Johns Hopkins University Press, 1964); Robert Soloman, “A Quantitative Perspective on the Debt of Developing Countries,” in Developing Country Debt, ed. by Lawrence J. Franco and Marilyn J. Seiber (New York, 1979), pp. 17–41; and George Feder, “Economic Growth, Foreign Loans, and Debt Servicing Capacity of Developing Countries,” World Bank, Staff Working Paper No. 274 (Washington, 1978).
This model, as is standard, is presented in terms of gross domestic product. It may be couched in terms of gross national product (i.e., GDP less foreign interest payments) and similar conclusions obtained.
Assuming that export earnings are a constant share of GDP, then the debt service/export earnings ratio would have a path similar to that of the debt service/GDP ratio, but the debt service/export earnings ratio would be higher at all times.
The stability of the external debt accumulation process is predicated on the condition that the growth rate of nominal GDP exceeds the nominal interest rate charged on foreign indebtedness, with a given current account deficit/GDP ratio. A crude empirical estimate of this stability criterion for public external debt can be obtained by comparing a proxy of future interest rates with a proxy for future nominal GDP growth. Taking the average interest rate on outstanding public external debt in 1979 (6.0 per cent) and comparing it with the average annual increase of nominal GDP during 1972–79 (17.0 per cent) it appears that, in the aggregate for non-oil developing countries, a precondition for stable growth in external debt exists.
See Appendix II, above.
Assuming that consumption and savings decisions are made on the basis of GNP (GDP less foreign interest payments).